You are on page 1of 15

No.

508 January 15, 2004

Compulsory Licensing vs. the Three


“Golden Oldies”
Property Rights, Contracts, and Markets
by Robert P. Merges

Executive Summary

From its inception in the U.S. in the early 20th ers to locate, negotiate with, and pay individual sell-
century, compulsory licensing has been seen as a ers. Compulsory licensing supposedly addresses the
means of making intellectual works available by “market failure” of high transaction costs.
reducing some of the transaction costs associated But markets for digitized works do not suffer
with obtaining permission to use copyrighted from market failures. Furthermore, the Internet
material. There are now increasing calls for com- has reduced the transaction costs that once served
pulsory licensing for digitized works on the as a key rationale for compulsory licensing. Recent
Internet, particularly music. developments suggest that fears of excessive con-
Conceptually, a compulsory license falls mid- trol of digital content are overblown. Without
way between granting full copyright, which gives enhancing compulsory licensing, the digital land-
owners broad control, and denying copyright pro- scape is diverse, as the case of music demonstrates.
tection altogether. There is free music, temporarily free music, and
Rather than allowing musicians, artists, and low-cost music online. Offline, music companies
other copyright owners to negotiate licensing are lowering the prices of CDs.
terms for use of their works, a compulsory license The influence costs associated with compul-
forces copyright owners to allow use of their sory licensing schemes make them a more expen-
works under legislatively set prices and restric- sive mechanism for setting prices. Private negoti-
tions on use. ations are much cheaper and more flexible over
When warring groups sound the alarm over the long term.
excessive control via copyright on the one hand and In the digital realm, we have not yet aban-
insufficient incentives to create on the other, com- doned the basic building blocks of all creative
pulsory licensing seems a reasonable compromise. endeavors—property rights, contracts, and vol-
Compulsory licensing seems to pay off big in the untary markets—and we therefore retain the pre-
short term by reducing the need for individual buy- conditions for future growth and diversification.

_____________________________________________________________________________________________________
Robert P. Merges is a professor at the University of California—Berkeley School of Law and the University of
California—Davis School of Law.
We have not yet Introduction and markets—and have therefore retained the
abandoned the conditions for future growth and diversifica-
Near the beginning of the Internet revolu- tion. There will still be times when the expe-
basic building tion, I called for patience in intellectual prop- dient of market circumvention, such as com-
blocks of erty (IP) policy, despite the controversy gener- pulsory licenses, may sound appealing, but
ated by the ease of sharing copied digital con- we would be wise to avoid it.
our creative tent, such as music, movies, and electronic
industries— books.1 As is well known, the Internet not only
property rights, provided everyone a printing press, but file- Where We Are Now
sharing applications like Napster and Kazaa
contracts, and have made content like music and movies Let’s examine music, since so much of the
markets. freely available and, therefore, have made pro- fuss is centered on the downloading of copy-
ducers of such content reluctant to fully righted music. Some observers have suggest-
embrace the Web as a distribution channel. ed compulsory licensing as a means of mak-
Intellectual property rights were indeed ing music widely available for download.
going to cause bottlenecks in the commercial Rather than allowing musicians, artists, and
distribution of digital content of all kinds. other copyright owners to negotiate licensing
But, based on historical examples, any terms for use of their works with content dis-
attempt to circumvent the sometimes slow tributors and consumers, a compulsory
process of market formation via the mecha- licensing regime would impose a mandatory
nism of property rights would likely leave licensing system to force copyright owners to
society worse off. In other situations seem- allow use of their works under legislatively set
ingly intractable bottlenecks had been eased prices and restrictions on use. The making of
by the formation of cooperative organiza- cover songs provides a familiar non-Internet
tions made up of the holders of multiple and example: if the White Stripes wanted to cover
disparate property rights, such as ASCAP “Lawyers, Guns and Money” by the late
(the American Society of Composers, Artists Warren Zevon, they would pay the statutory
and Publishers), formed to clear copyrights fee and the copyright owner would have to
in the early days of radio. I sang the praises of allow them to use the song.
these voluntary, private organizations, espe- But expanded compulsory licensing for
cially compared to legislative compulsory online media would be ill advised. While
licensing schemes designed to do an end-run there have been years of reluctance by media
around private bargaining. companies, today anyone can legally down-
Despite mounting cries for compulsory load music from all five of the “major” record
licensing to facilitate the distribution of digi- labels for as little as 49 cents per song.
tal entertainment and information, I have Depending on the service, one can listen to a
not changed my tune. Indeed, the Promised song once, capture it for multiple plays in a
Land of widespread digital distribution is set period of time, or “burn” it onto a cus-
upon us in many areas, and very nearly so in tomized, personal CD.2 Consumers can also
others. There is still a dearth of legitimate listen to a “live stream” of music selected by
music, television, and blockbuster movies an Internet DJ, with royalties paid to the
offered online by their creators. But we will songwriters.3 Of course, anyone can still go to
be judged wise for avoiding abrupt changes a record store and buy a CD.
in our IP system that replace voluntarism In addition, consumers can legally down-
and trade with forced sharing, such as load generous amounts of free music. Many
expanded compulsory licensing of content. talented musicians make their work avail-
In the digital realm, we have not yet aban- able, cost-free, over the Internet. Some offer a
doned the basic building blocks of our cre- portion of their work for free, hoping to gen-
ative industries—property rights, contracts, erate enough buzz about their music that lis-

2
teners are willing to pay for more later (for a nies like yourself. Tell us more about
concert ticket or a CD). This online distribu- why you think they should license
tion model increasingly constrains the price music to Grokster.
of the “legitimate” downloading services Rosso: It’s not so much that they should
referred to above, particularly as mainstream license to Grokster, it’s more a call for
artists embrace it as an alternative to tradi- blanket compulsory licensing of some
tional recording companies. kind. At the moment content licensing
negotiations are a one-way street. And
what has happened is that record com-
The Curious Appeal of panies have used their content to slow
Compulsory Licensing the growth of ecommerce and the
Internet until they can figure out how
Now, with such ample content available, to co-opt the technology. Simply put,
one would think things are working fairly they want to own or control the tech-
well, growing pains aside. Visionary business- nology themselves.
man Steve Jobs evidently thinks so: he recent-
ly guided Apple Computer—a hardware com- Let us consider Lessig’s proposals for a
pany—into the vibrant and competitive mar- moment. Lessig calls for a new look at com-
One of the last
ket for music downloading.4 pulsory licensing as a compromise that allows things one might
Compared to the hue and cry of only a few media companies to secure “compensation expect is a call for
years ago, when the record labels were widely without control.”8 He argues that, in the past,
criticized for “not getting” the Internet, the Congress and the courts often balanced the a radical overhaul
outlook today seems promising. One of the interests of technological innovators against and government
last things one might expect is a call for a rad- established content owners by creating com-
ical overhaul and government involvement in pulsory licensing schemes. Examples include
involvement in
the distribution mechanisms of music and the early player piano industry (the occasion the distribution
other digital content. Yet that is exactly what for the first compulsory license) and the satel- mechanisms of
we are hearing, most prominently from well- lite television industry, which grew by
respected legal scholar Lawrence Lessig.5 In rebroadcasting the signals from established music and other
his recent book, The Future of Ideas, Lessig out- broadcast TV stations. Lessig argues that digital content.
lines a plan for compulsory licensing of copy- Congress has so far largely overlooked com-
righted works, a strategy that would require pulsory licensing in the Internet arena, which
movie and music companies to allow anyone he suggests is a bad thing.
to download and use digital works, as long as Lessig’s concern for balance with respect
they made payments to copyright holders to rights in the creation of intellectual prop-
under a federal statute.6 erty and its use by others is right on the mark.
Wayne Rosso, president of Grokster, a Ideas and other intellectual property should
peer-to-peer (P2P) file-sharing company, not be locked up in perpetuity. His idea of
exemplifies a similar viewpoint, but from the creators making voluntary contributions of
perspective of an impatient vendor. Consider intellectual works to a low-restriction “cre-
this exchange between Rosso and an inter- ative commons,”9 for example, is a creative
viewer:7 and novel response to the risk of over-appro-
priation of intellectual property, which he
Interviewer: A lot was made in the and others worry about. Under the creative
media about your speech at the commons approach, the creators of digital
Financial Times new media conference work (e.g., photo, story, or drawing) can offer
recently. You used the opportunity to their work to others for copying and reuse,
attack the recording industry for not but can also limit others’ uses in any of a
licensing their music to P2P compa- number of ways, such as for noncommercial

3
exploitation only. Lessig apparently sees as this statutory license is now called. Under
compulsory licensing as a similarly flexible it, any recording artist can record a new ver-
and beneficial policy for making intellectual sion (often called a “cover”) of an existing
works widely available. But compulsory song composition as long as he or she pays a
licensing, although often regarded as a rea- statutory compulsory license fee to the
sonable compromise, is not a policy that will owner of the composition.11 In this way, a
bring about balance between creation, use, statute created long ago to address an indus-
and profit in the long run. Markets will tend try now long dead continues to undergird
to be superior in their beneficial impact on transactions in an important modern indus-
the creative process and output. Compulsory try. As described later in this paper, the statu-
licenses, being creatures of federal statute, tory royalty rate for covers was well below
tend to be less flexible and more susceptible what many believed the market rate would
to political manipulation than market-based have been, which is precisely the sort of leg-
transactions. The costs that are saved by a islative lock-in that occurs when market par-
compulsory license in the short run are usu- ticipants are channeled into statutory licens-
ally more than offset by the inefficiencies ing instead of voluntary, arm’s-length deals
that it causes over time. negotiated to fit the dynamics of individual
Despite the difficulties it can cause, Lessig buyers and sellers.
and Rosso are certainly not alone in advocat- The second reason compulsory licensing
ing compulsory licensing. Since its inception is attractive is that it pays off big in the short
in the United States in the early 20th century, term. It reduces initial transaction costs by
compulsory licensing has been appealing for eliminating the need for individual buyers to
two reasons. First, as Lessig notes, compulso- locate, negotiate with, and pay individual
ry licensing does separate “compensation sellers. This “market failure” rationale is
from control.” Conceptually, it falls midway most plausible where markets are unlikely to
between granting full copyright, which like form because sellers deem it not worthwhile
all property rights gives owners very broad to spend the resources necessary to reach a
powers, and denying copyright protection certain group of buyers. At least under the
altogether. Whenever warring groups sound market conditions prevailing when it was
the alarm over, on the one hand, domination passed, the compulsory license for isolated,
via copyright, and, on the other, insufficient remote satellite TV viewers might have fit
incentives to create works in the first place, such a description. But obviously most mar-
compulsory licensing seems a reasonable kets for copyrighted works are not nearly so
compromise policy. “thin”—so this justification for compulsory
That policy, however, is less reasonable licensing would rarely arise. And it certainly
than it first appears. As noted, the first com- does not apply to Internet-based markets,
The costs that pulsory license statute in the U.S. was enact- since this medium represents one of the
are saved by a ed to prevent a single large firm from domi- most powerful transaction cost-reducing
compulsory nating the market for player piano rolls.10 forces ever seen in the music, publishing,
Piano rolls were used to create music in play- and related industries.
license in the er pianos. When piano rolls were held to be Nonetheless, calls for compulsory licens-
short run are copyrightable by the Supreme Court, ing for music are creating considerable chaos
Congress legislated a compulsory license in with respect to the licensing and pricing of
usually more than accord with the wishes of piano roll compa- streamed and downloaded music over the
offset by the nies worried that the dominant firm in the Internet. There is a good argument that a
inefficiencies that industry would lock up the rights to all pop- sweeping move toward compulsory licensing
ular music as embodied in piano rolls. Even would lower some of the transaction costs
it causes over today, the legacy of the piano roll wars lives associated with the distribution of digital
time. on in the “mechanical” compulsory license, works—in the short term. The time and trou-

4
ble that go into assembling large blocks of son market resolution of disputes over distri- Clearly, absolute
digital content would be saved—for now. And bution must be allowed to play out. Put sim- control over
users would be free to “rip, mix, and burn” to ply, the participants in the media revolution
their hearts’ content, secure in the knowledge disagree over the optimal property rights intellectual
that it was legal as long as they paid whatev- regime, and there is no way to instantly sort property is
er fee was required under the statute. This out settlements and contracts that will prop-
instantaneous “market making” of the com- erly evolve over time. Maintaining the tradi-
almost
pulsory licensing process would no doubt be tional legal pairing of property rights and unthinkable.
a boon to users in the short term. Music fans, contracts, which usually leads to market for-
for instance, have had to wait almost 10 years mation, seems like a safer course than man-
since the advent of the popular, commercial dates or new market intervention to correct
Internet for the rollout of cheap, simple for past market intervention.
music downloading sites such as Listen.com It is true that property rights confer a
and Applemusic.com.12 This seems to be measure of control—they would not be much
quite a long wait for large record labels to use if they didn’t. But the specter of total,
finally recognize the potential of Internet omnipresent control is what has the critics
music distribution and for a single entity worried. These fears may well be unjustified,
such as Apple to negotiate with all the labels however. Even the strongest digital rights
for access rights to their content. But the management system one might contemplate
instant market making of a compulsory falls far short of total control over the infor-
license will be detrimental to long-run intel- mation it protects from unwanted copying.15
lectual property markets. Putting aside the ever-present threat that a
copy management system will be “hacked” or
“cracked,” there are many manifestations of
Overblown Fears about digital content that cannot be effectively con-
“Content Control” Drive trolled by a rightholder. For example, if I
download a movie about a great wizard who
Compulsory Licensing is shipwrecked on a remote island, the movie
Demands distributor can control my use in many ways.
I may be permitted to watch it only once, or
Much of the hand-wringing over copy- may have to pay royalties for subsequent
rights in digital content centers on the uses. My copy of the file may become inoper-
notion of control. Some content owners and ative after a period of time. I may not be able
sellers express grave concerns that the to capture and extract still images from the
Internet undermines the control that they movie and copy them to my own computer,
can exercise over their works and derivations and so on.
of them. Peer-to-peer file sharing, the clearest But as law professor Polk Wagner of the
example of loss of control over distribution University of Pennsylvania argues, it would
and pricing, has led to progressive escalation be prohibitively expensive for the movie’s
of penalties for copyright infringement.13 owner to prevent me from referring to the
Copyright critics, by contrast, bemoan the movie in conversations with my friends, or
tightening of copyright owners’ control rep- speaking about the movie as I teach a class-
resented by the Digital Millennium room full of students, or even borrowing
Copyright Act of 1998 and other recent legis- broad themes from the movie in writing a
lation.14 Note the paradox here: Content short story.16 The digital record of the work
owners think the Net takes away control, can be controlled, but it is much more diffi-
while Lessig and others believe digitization is cult to police the lingering thoughts about
cementing owners’ control over content. In the movie or my expression of them, in
fact, both are partly correct, which is one rea- reviews, critiques, and conversations. Of

5
course, the content owner could assign a pri- ry license is necessary, it is argued, to offset
vate investigator to each viewer of the movie, this growing power.18 It certainly is true that
to make sure none of these activities crossed some firms have pursued a strategy of aggre-
the “infringement” line, but that would be gating content, with the idea that large
expensive indeed. libraries create “synergies” of various kinds.
Clearly, absolute control over intellectual (The AOL/Time Warner merger was justified
property is almost unthinkable. A key ques- on that basis, although even it has since been
tion is whether a right-holder exerting more plagued by a range of problems.) Compul-
control over a protected work might (per- sory licensing proposals based on this con-
haps counterintuitively) increase the total cern aim to strip property right holders of
output of creative works. In a regime where their power to control the use of content
tight digital control over downloaded movies while preserving their right to compensation.
is possible, the copyright owner may feel In the main, current conditions suggest
comfortable distributing it more widely than that underlying fears of concentration and
he does in today’s environment of easy copy- control are perhaps overblown. The digital
ing. This may spark more indirect—and landscape is wildly diverse, as the case of
hence perfectly legal—derivative creations. music makes amply clear. There is free music,
If digital diversity For example, someone may be inspired by the temporarily free music, and low-cost music
is the goal, the general themes in the movie to write a novel online. Music companies are lowering the
current system or short story. Or a controversial copyrighted prices of CDs. There is fully secured and pro-
photograph may spark debate over its con- tected music, available for downloading only
seems not to be tent, or about free speech in general.17 with serious restrictions on use, copying, and
doing too badly. Wagner’s argument is that the total volume distribution. There is partially secured music,
of cultural discourse—very broadly defined— available for a fee for downloading and then
may rise under a regime of greater control. useable without restriction. There is even rel-
Such potential gains could be undermined atively cheap downloading of an entire album
by a compulsory licensing regime, however. If directly from the recording artist, without
content owners decide not to distribute some record label, distributor, or retail store.
works digitally, or never to produce them at This digital smorgasbord has evolved
all because of a perceived loss of control or within the confines of strong intellectual
unfair statutory fee, we will be worse off. A property rights, whatever one may feel about
rigid compulsory license will often under- the appropriateness of that regime as it cur-
reward creators or constrain novel distribu- rently exists. Of course one might argue that
tion strategies. regime is undermined by the ease of copying
itself. Nonetheless, if digital diversity is the
goal, the current system seems not to be
Growing Diversity—Without doing too badly. Would a sweeping reform
Compulsory Licensing really help?

The Lessig agenda—“compensation with-


out control”—seems to spring at least partly Why Compulsory Licensing
from an overriding concern that society not Is No Solution
permit the same concentration of economic
power (and therefore cultural influence) in Diversity already springs from the
the Internet arena as some perceive in con- “Golden Oldies” of property rights, contracts
ventional media such as television. The “con- and markets. But there are other reasons to
trol” argument is based on Lessig’s view that oppose compulsory licensing as a path to
content is increasingly concentrated in the greater diversity. These stem from the way
hands of big media companies. A compulso- compulsory licensing works in practice as

6
opposed to theory. In particular, compulsory testimony from both owners and users
licensing mechanisms suffer from two inher- before setting a price.
ent weaknesses: (1) overcomplexity and inef- Once they are set up—which is usually
ficiencies generated by bureaucratic price-fix- where the proponents of compulsory licenses
ing and influence-seeking (the “too many begin their analysis—the price schedule type
moving parts” phenomenon), and (2) inflexi- of compulsory licenses can work quite
bility, or the problem of legislative lock-in. smoothly for a time. The problem is that set-
ting up the schedule may be very costly. Lessig’s
Problem 1: Too Many Moving Parts call for “compensation without control”
In our legal system, creative works are gen- sounds appealing, but the process of deter-
erally protected by intellectual property mining fair compensation is expensive and
rights.19 That means that potential users of time consuming. And there is the additional
information must obtain permission from problem that a schedule set up to meet
the rightholder before copying, performing, today’s conditions may quickly become out-
or otherwise using it.20 If a user fails to do so, dated—and yet, because of the vagaries of the
the rightholder can halt the unauthorized legislative process, be very hard to change.
use and recoup royalties or damages. In Even at the outset, compulsory license nego-
terms of legal theory, this remedy against tiations involve an additional cost not pre-
unauthorized use is the essence of a property sent in everyday market transactions. In the
right, whether tangible or intangible. case of legislated price schedules, members of
Our system also permits another arrange- Congress must be educated about details of
ment, the compulsory license, whereby the the industry. Parties with an economic inter-
rightholder does not have the right to pre- est in the outcome of the schedule-setting
vent unauthorized use. Under this arrange- obviously have a major stake in this educa-
ment, the user can “infringe” the right all he tion process. In fact, they have an incentive to
wants; he is however required to pay a gov- skew the “education process” in their favor
ernment-specified fee to the rightholder. and are therefore willing to expend signifi-
In practical terms, the underlying, crucial cant sums of money on lobbying. All inter-
difference between the two arrangements is ested parties are aware of this, of course,
who gets to set the price of the information.21 In the which leads them to expend significant sums
first regime, much like a typical property right, on the process. Economists who study these
the creator/owner of the information gets to sorts of processes even have a term for such
set the price or not sell. The user must obtain expenditures: they call them influence costs.22
permission from the owner. This permission A key difference between market negotia-
will be granted only when the user is willing to tion and legislative wrangling over price is
pay what the owner thinks fair in exchange for the level of influence costs involved in each. A schedule set up
the legal right to use the information. In general, parties to a private bargain are
In the second arrangement, the govern- willing to expend some resources to enhance
to meet today’s
ment plays a role in setting the price. This their bargaining position, but there are lim- conditions may
determination can take one of several forms. its. It would make no sense to try to persuade quickly become
Congress may simply legislate a fixed price a seasoned record company executive to
for certain types of intellectual works, as it agree to a deal that falls far outside of indus- outdated—and
has done for users of musical compositions try norms, for example. The same is not true, yet, because of
who want to record a new version of the com- however, in the legislative context. Members
position. This may be thought of as a “price of Congress do not know the details of con-
the vagaries of
schedule” license. Or a more complex proce- tent industry operations. They do not know the legislative
dure may be mandated. For example, for cer- industry “rules of thumb.” Also, the setting process, be very
tain types of copyrighted works Congress has of a rate schedule will affect many future
set up a royalty arbitration panel that hears transactions, which means that both parties hard to change.

7
Compulsory may well find it desirable to escalate the webcasters could instead pay a percentage of
licensing influence game well beyond anything nor- their revenue as royalties. Negotiations
mally seen in a private bargain. A royalty between one group of small webcasters and
schemes involve schedule, in other words, is like a very big and the Recording Industry Association of
significant almost permanent “contract,” and so will jus- America set that rate at between 8 percent
tify far more negotiation expenditures than a and 12 percent of stations’ revenue.26
influence costs typical negotiation for a specific purpose, to The webcaster arbitration was conducted
that make them last a limited time, between two private par- under the Copyright Act’s Copyright Arbitra-
more expensive as ties. Finally, a rate schedule is a “one shot” tion Royalty Panel procedure. The goal of the
transaction; thus, there is no opportunity to webcasting CARP was to establish prices that
a mechanism for “even up” bargaining over a series of transac- Internet webcasters would pay to record
setting prices. tions, a process that would encourage the labels and other owners of sound recording
parties to stop fighting today in expectation copyrights.27 The webcasting CARP stretched
of making up ground in future deals. over several years and cost millions of dollars.
Influence costs are also significant in But the CARP’s proposal was deemed unac-
compulsory licenses that set up a process ceptable by some parties, who appealed the
rather than a one-time rate schedule. The panel’s decision. The upshot? According to
recently concluded (though still contested) one copyright system expert:
copyright arbitration involving Internet
“webcasters” is a case in point. Webcasters, A decision was rendered by the
unlike traditional broadcasters, must pay Librarian in the webcasting rate pro-
royalties for the public performance of sound ceeding—the ‘‘CARP of the century so
recordings—that is, recorded versions of far’’ (to quote from the Register of
songs, such as a track from a CD.23 Tradi- Copyrights). The Office rejected the
tional broadcasters do not pay such a royalty, CARP’s decision, and the Librarian
under a longstanding rule that record labels issued a modified ruling. No one was
and other sound recording producers have happy. All the parties appealed to the
lived with for many years. Because webcast- D.C. Circuit. Several parties approach-
ing, unlike traditional broadcasting, can ed Congress and a statute was enacted
make it easy to record music, the music further modifying at least part of the
industry pushed for the right to receive roy- Librarian’s decision. Total costs for
alties on webcasts. This was implemented in this CARP, including attorneys fees
the Digital Performance Right in Sound and witness costs, were in the millions
Recordings Act of 1995.24 Substantial revi- of dollars (some estimates as high as
sions appeared in the Digital Millennium $25 million).28
Copyright Act of 1998,25 but implementation
of the royalty was delayed several years to let The ongoing complexity and cost of this
copyright owners and webcasters negotiate. CARP led several of the parties to back pro-
During this period, thousands of small posals to replace the CARP process with a
webcasters operating on shoestring budgets new and better procedure for establishing
sprang up. Under applicable law, the licensing fees. These new proposals reveal
Librarian of Congress (via a procedure defects in the current system that shed inter-
described in the next paragraph) finally set esting light on the problems of compulsory
royalty rates, asking webcasters to pay 0.07 of licenses in general. For example, one idea is to
a cent per song played. Many small webcast- replace the three-member CARP tribunal
ers protested, saying that it would put them with a single “copyright judge.”29 However,
out of business. In response, Congress passed opponents of this proposal expressed anxiety
the Small Web-casters Settlement Act in about lodging so much power in a single
2002, which created a new plan under which individual who could not be removed from

8
office for seven years under the terms of the Simplicity is desirable, but legislating is an
bill.30 Indeed, the proposal to establish such a ugly process. Judging by recent history, legis-
copyright “czar” shows how far a compulsory lation produces ugly results in copyright
licensing regime strays from a true market matters as well. A prime example is the
system. Another concern was “appealability,” Digital Millennium Copyright Act of 1998.
an obvious issue in light of the multiple This legislation was the result of interest
appeals to different political arenas that fol- group deal-making so Byzantine that it bog-
lowed the webcasting CARP decision. Finally, gles the mind of even David Nimmer, author
and most ironically, the parties expressed a of the most comprehensive and widely used
strong desire to establish a system that copyright law treatise, who has decried the
reduced the costs of compulsory licensing “absurdly complex”32 effects of this
proceedings and promoted private party set- “fiendishly complicated”33 piece of legisla-
tlement prior to the completion of full-blown tion. You might recall that this is the legisla-
arbitration proceedings.31 The irony here is tion that was originally designed to clarify
that there is an alternative to CARP tribunals and update the copyright law in light of the
that very effectively promotes private party Internet. It wound up being a hugely com-
negotiation of price schedules without expen- plex piece of lawmaking that created broad
sive and cumbersome government-mandated new areas of copyright liability for those who
Compulsory
tribunals: private property rights. produce and distribute technologies capable licensing has
To summarize: compulsory licensing of breaking copy protection schemes. The act led to price
schemes invariably involve significant influ- legislated in detail in areas such as Internet
ence costs that make them generally more service provider (ISP) liability for infringing stagnation.
expensive as a mechanism for setting prices. content supplied by subscribers. The patch-
Private party negotiations are more flexible work of industry-specific provisions that
and likely much cheaper on average over the major content providers were induced to
long term. include in exchange for agreement to the
basic structure of the act suggests the kind of
Problem 2: Legislative Lock-In complexity that would attend any compre-
Another problem with compulsory licens- hensive compulsory licensing statute cover-
es is that they can easily become outdated ing Internet content. Indeed, any bill in this
and unreflective of supply and demand. But area can be expected to quickly reopen the
unlike private contracts (which are usually same issues that vexed participants in the
more short-lived than legislation and can in DMCA process.
any case always be renegotiated), legislation is As messy as it is, legislation that does pass
exceedingly hard to get rid of or change. is likely to be very difficult to get rid of later.
Industry participants thus run the risk of This poses perhaps the greatest threat of all.
being tied to an outdated pricing structure. Legislative lock-in explains why compul-
This is the problem of legislative lock-in. sory licensing rates—such as those for record-
Advocates of compulsory licensing ed musical compositions and, in the past,
schemes envision a simple, fair system, to be jukebox performances34—periodically fall so
enacted rapidly and straightforwardly by rea- far behind market rates. For example, the
sonable, fair-minded policymakers. Their statutory rate for recorded compositions did
plea seems reasonable and straightforward to not change between the 1909 Copyright Act
them: they want Applemusic.com without and the 1976 Copyright Act, despite the mas-
the 10-year wait and without the control that sive growth in the music recording industry
property rights confer on established content during that era.35 In practice, then, compul-
distributors. But a legislative compromise sory licensing has led to price stagnation.
will likely be locked in longer than 10 years, Although it is impossible to prove that this
to the detriment of many involved. led directly to reduced output of copyrighted

9
works, it surely had some effect—if nothing fluid, functional markets—without recourse
else, by undercompensating composers for to a compulsory license.
works that consumers valued highly.
Proponents of a compulsory licensing
scheme for the Internet point to it as one way How Markets Solve the
to bypass the power of media content Licensing Dilemma through
“dinosaurs.” But if history is any guide, com-
pulsory licensing is likely to hatch as many
Voluntary Associations
dinosaurs as it bypasses. Consider webcast- As inefficient as they can be, compulsory
ing, for instance. As things stand, webcasters licenses might still be justifiable if there were
have to compete for business on the same no good alternative. But the state of digital
basis as radio stations—song selection, disk distribution is no case of “market failure” jus-
jockeys, and so forth. The dawning compul- tifying government intervention. In the intel-
sory licensing regime prevents a webcaster lectual property arena, compulsory licenses
from trying a radically new strategy. What if are in fact rarely, if ever, necessary. Private
a startup webcaster offered a premium royal- rightholders have ample incentives to get
ty rate to song composition owners who their content to a paying audience and have
wanted their music played via an interactive proven adept at getting together to form col-
service over the Internet, perhaps in exchange lective rights administration organizations
for the exclusive right to stream music in this to resolve IP transaction bottlenecks. This
medium? (Compulsory licenses by their has been true over the years in a number of
nature make all works available nonexclusive- industries, beginning with song composition
ly.) Would composers and music publishers owners—songwriters and music publishers—
give this “premium” webcasting channel a try? in the 1920s.40 Radio broadcasters found
Would consumers like it? We will probably themselves liable for copyright infringement
never find out. Because “compensation” has for the public performance of song composi-
been decoupled from “control,” we will get the tions. There was serious concern about the
same brand of competition in webcasting that costs of locating and dealing with all the indi-
we do in radio. So while webcasters could vidual holders of song copyrights. A classic
compete on format, number and type of example of the need for compulsory licensing
advertisements, and the like, they could not seemed to be in the making. And yet it was
compete on the basis of exclusive content. not: the copyright holders formed ASCAP, a
A related area of the entertainment indus- collective rights organization (CRO) that
try, the use of copyrighted songs as back- drew together all the copyright holders and
ground music in movies and TV shows, pro- offered a single “package license” to radio
vides a stark contrast to the compulsory stations. Because of the CROs, no compulso-
model. For historical reasons, there is no ry license was necessary for music composi-
compulsory license for the incorporation of a tions played over the air. Similar CROs have
song into the action and events of a movie or since emerged in other places and industries.
TV show.36 Movie and TV producers must These specialized private organizations bun-
negotiate directly with the owners of copy- dle together copyrights and distribute royal-
Private rights in music or their agents.37 Exchanges ty payments to individual members.
rightholders in this area demonstrate all the attributes of There is no reason to believe that CROs
a robust market: direct negotiations, wide will not emerge in the Internet arena. Indeed,
have ample price differentials, and above all a variety of there is evidence that some are in the making
incentives to get competitors.38 The volume of licensing in already. For example, various “clearing-
their content to a this area,39 and the variance in price and house” sites offer the works of individual
other terms, demonstrates convincingly that content creators in a “one-stop-shopping”
paying audience. copyrighted content can form the basis of format—similar in some ways to the package

10
licensing of ASCAP. Even the webcasting nization founded years ago by media compa- Policymakers
public performance rights subject to a com- nies specifically to compete with ASCAP, is a should leave
pulsory license administered by the CARP good example. There is every reason to believe
have spawned a new CRO, SoundExchange. that multiple collective rights organizations creativity to the
SoundExchange was formed by record labels may well emerge and that average prices for musicians.
and other copyright holders to receive public copyrighted works will drop if they do.
performance royalties and distribute them to Nevertheless, the threat of antitrust inves-
member organizations. While this organiza- tigations and litigation looms over every col-
tion emerged in the shadow of the compul- lective rights organization. For this reason,
sory license enacted by Congress, there is no record labels asked for and received explicit
reason to believe it would not have come into legislative exemption from the antitrust laws
being to administer strictly private property in forming SoundExchange to deal with web-
rights, just as ASCAP did in the 1920s. Such casters.44 While understandable, this step is
an organization could perform the same col- in some ways unfortunate. It does nothing to
lection and distribution functions, with one dispel the antitrust fears of other firms want-
important difference: its members, and not ing to form such collectives. Future propo-
Congress, would determine the price and nents of new organizations, for example in
other terms under which webcasters could movies, may even feel compelled to emulate
use the members’ public performance the music industry, with the perhaps unfor-
rights.41 Along with more flowering of con- tunate consequence of making congressional
tent, the added bonus would have been that approval a de facto requirement for the for-
the significant “influence costs” incurred in mation of a collective rights organization
the rate-setting process could be saved. It is and retaining Congress as a middleman.
ironic indeed that in the age of digital “disin- A better approach would be for the courts
termediation,” right holders have had to deal to make it very clear that under antitrust law,
with a formidable middleman—first Con- collective rights organizations are presump-
gress and then the webcasting CARP. tively exempt from antitrust liability.
Antitrust suits against them ought to be dis-
missed at the summary judgment stage.
Antitrust Issues Collective action across firms is simply a pre-
requisite for the formation of markets in cer-
Because collective rights organizations tain IP-intensive industries, and antitrust law
bring competitors together in an industry- ought to reflect that markets have plenty of
wide organization, the unfortunate impulse room for cooperation as well as competition.
of policymakers is to regard such entities as
effective cover for a cartel. For example, when
asked his opinion of SoundExchange, the Conclusion
recording industry’s attempt at collaboration
to collect license fees for performers, Rep. A competitive market, combined with the
James Sensenbrenner (R-WI) said it “sounds existence of property rights such as those pre-
like an antitrust violation to me.”42 The histo- vailing today, will foster a wide spectrum of
ry of ASCAP, moreover, is tightly intertwined market strategies regarding how much to pro-
with numerous antitrust investigations.43 tect intellectual creations. The widely touted
Despite these concerns, collective rights orga- advantages of a compulsory license will very
nizations are usually tightly constrained in likely materialize without putting content
function by their members. Many are also providers into a legal straightjacket that will
subject to competition, the best guarantor undercompensate some of them and lock all
against consumer harm. BMI (Broadcast of them into a rigid structure that will be dif-
Music Incorporated), a collective rights orga- ficult to change as time goes on.

11
Policymakers should leave creativity to the “How Markets Solve the Licensing Dilemma
through Voluntary Associations,” later in this
musicians. The best course here is to stick paper.
with the Golden Oldies—property rights,
contracts, and markets. These institutions 4. Laurie J. Flynn, “Apple Offers Music Downloads
have stood the test of time. They are very like- with Unique Pricing,” New York Times, April 29,
2003, p. D1.
ly the best choices in the Internet setting too.
How do we translate these general guide- 5. See Lawrence Lessig, The Future of Ideas (New
lines into specific recommendations? Given York: Vintage Books, 2001).
the analytics of compulsory licensing, and
6. Ibid., pp. 241–58.
starting where we find ourselves today, three
initial policies are in order: 7. Ciarán Tannam, “Interview with the President
of Grokster,” MP3Newswire.net, April 30, 2003,
• Repeal the digital public performance http://www.mp3newswire.net/stories/2003/
grokster. html.
right compulsory license, and let Sound-
Exchange and any competitors that may 8. Lessig, Chapter 11.
arise deal directly with webcasters.45
• Resist appeals to legislate more compul- 9. See www.creativecommons.org.
sory licenses. 10. See Merges, “Contracting into Liability Rules.”
• Continue to apply liberal antitrust rules
to collective rights organizations.46 11. 17 U.S.C. § 115 (2003).

12. See generally Saul Hansell, “E-Music Sites


With these policies in place, the three Settle on Prices. It’s a Start,” New York Times,
Golden Oldies can be expected to play well in March 3, 2003, p. C1.
this new setting, as they have so well in others.
13. See, for example, P2P Piracy Prevention Act of
2002, H.R. 107th Cong., 2d Sess. (July 25, 2002).

Notes 14. Pub. L. No. 105-304, 112 Stat. 2860 (Oct. 28,
1998), codified at scattered sections of 17 U.S.C.
1. Robert P. Merges, “Contracting into Liability For critiques of this and related legislation, see
Rules: Intellectual Property Transactions and Pamela Samuelson, “Toward a ‘New Deal’ for
Collective Rights Organizations,” California Law Copyright for an Information Age,” Michigan Law
Review 84 (1997): 1293. Review 100 (2002); and David Nimmer, “Back
from the Future: A Proleptic Review of the Digital
2. To be fair, music download services offer an Millennium Copyright Act,” Berkeley Technology
ever-changing array of options and restrictions on Law Journal 16 (2001): 855.
the downloading and “burning” of music onto
CDs. See, for example, applemusic.com; and 15. Digital rights management (DRM) refers to
“Listen.com Halves CD Burning Cost,” Internet technologies that encase content in secure elec-
News, February 13, 2003, http://www. Internetnews. tronic “envelopes,” which users can open only
com/ec-news/article.php/1583661. with permission of the content owner. This per-
mits the distribution of content on a for-profit
3. As explained later in this paper, songwriters basis over the Internet. Various automated use
whose compositions are played by online web- limitations and user rights may be encoded into
casters are paid through collective rights organi- the DRM. See http://www.law.berkeley.edu/institutes/
zations such as ASCAP, just as they are when their bclt/drm/resources.html; and Mark Stefik,
music is played on conventional radio and TV “Shifting the Possible: How Trusted Systems and
broadcasts. Some webcasters, however, are Digital Property Rights Challenge Us to Rethink
required to pay royalties to record companies in Digital Publishing,” Berkeley Technology Law
addition to songwriters, under the Digital Journal 12 (1997):137.
Performance Right in Sound Recordings Act of
1995, Pub. L. No. 104-39, November 1, 1995, 109 16. Polk Wagner, “Information Wants to Be Free:
Stat 336, codified at 17 U.S.C. sections 106(6) and Intellectual Property and the Mythologies of
114(d)-(j); and the Digital Millennium Copyright Control,” Columbia Law Review 103 ( 2003): 995.
Act, Pub. L. No. 105-304, 112 Stat 2860 (1998),
codified in scattered sections of 17 U.S.C. See 17. Ibid., p. 1009.

12
18. Lessig, pp. 118–19. Law—Congress Responds to Copyright Arbitra-
tion Royalty Panel’s Webcasting Rates—Small
19. “Creative works” loosely refers to the subject Webcaster Settlement Act of 2002, P. L. 107-321,
matter of intellectual property. Various doctrines 116 Stat. 2780 (To Be Codified at 17 U.S.C. §
in intellectual property law distinguish between 114[F]-[G]),” Harvard Law Review 116 (2003):
ideas and their embodiments. 1920.

20. A narrow exception exists where permission is 27. The CARP covered only royalties to the owners
likely to be too expensive to be worthwhile, or of sound recording copyrights, usually record
where it may be withheld because the potential labels, and not to songwriters for musical compo-
user will criticize or satirize the work. These “mar- sitions. Musical composition royalties for web-
ket failure” scenarios are thought to justify copy- casting are collected by collective rights organiza-
right’s “fair use” exception to infringement. See tions such as ASCAP and BMI, just as they are for
Wendy Gordon, “Fair Use as Market Failure: A conventional radio. ASCAP for example offers its
Structural and Economic Analysis of the Betamax own license to webcasters where companies pay
Case and Its Predecessors,” Columbia Law Review on the basis of revenue generated from advertis-
82 (1982): 1600; and Robert P. Merges, “Are You ing and site traffic, which comes out to about 1.6
Making Fun of Me? Notes on Market Failure and percent of a site’s revenues, http://www.ascap.
the Parody Defense in Copyright,” American com/ weblicense/.
Intellectual Property Law Association Quarterly
Journal 21 (1993): 305. 28. Copyright Royalty and Distribution Reform
Act of 2003: Hearing before the Subcommittee on
21. See Robert P. Merges, “Of Property Rules, Courts, The Internet, and Intellectual Property of
Coase, and Intellectual Property,” Columbia Law the Committee on the Judiciary, House of
Review 94 (1994): 2655. Representatives, 108th Cong., 1st Sess., H.R. 1417,
April 1, 2003 (Statement of Michael J. Remington,
22. On this concept, see Paul Milgrom and D. J. former staff counsel, IP Subcommit-tee, House
Roberts, “Bargaining Costs, Influence Costs, and Committee on the Judiciary), pp. 28, 31.
the Organization of Economic Activity,” in
Perspectives on Positive Political Economy, ed. James E. 29. Ibid.
Alt and Kenneth A. Shepsle (Cambridge, MA:
Cambridge University Press, 1990); Paul Milgrom 30. Ibid. (Statement of Robert A. Garrett), pp. 9, 10:
and John Roberts, Economics, Organization and
Management (Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice [T]he parties [I represent—sports leagues and
Hall, 1992), pp. 192–94. other suppliers of digital content] are unani-
mous in their support for a decisionmaking
23. Technically, Congress for the first time gave body that consists of three individuals, rather
the owners of sound recording copyrights—typi- than one copyright royalty judge. They also
cally record companies—the exclusive right to support specific measures that will help
publicly perform their sound recordings in a dig- reduce costs and promote voluntary settle-
ital audio transmission, which means primarily ments, which we believe should be another
the transmission of the work over the Internet. principal goal of the legislation.
See 17 U.S.C. 106(6). This right varies depending
on the context: for subscription services, the right 31. Ibid., at 14:
translates into a compulsory license under 17
U.S.C. § 114(d)(2); for “interactive services,” there [The Joint Sports Claimaints, or JSC, interest
is a mandatory requirement to negotiate a “vol- group, consisting of sports leagues such as
untary” license; and for Internet transmissions of Major League Baseball, the NBA, and the like]
regular, traditional “over-the-air” broadcasts, strongly believes that one of the goals of the
there is no legal liability at all. For analysis and cri- copyright royalty arbitration process should
tique of this complex structure, see David be to discourage litigation and to encourage
Nimmer, “Ignoring the Public, Part I: On the voluntary settlements among the parties to
Absurd Complexity of the Digital Audio disputes. Existing policies and procedures, by
Transmission Right,” UCLA Entertainment Law raising bars to settlements at various points in
Review 7 (2000): 189 the process, have had precisely the opposite
effect. Examples include the policies and pro-
24. P.L. 104-39, 109 Stat. 336 (995). cedures dealing with confidentiality of negoti-
ated agreements, the technical distinction
25. P.L. 105-304, 112 Stat 2860 (1998). between settlements arrived at before and after
the initiation of CARP proceedings, and the
26. See generally, “Recent Legislation Copyright Office’s practice of permitting those who fail

13
to participate in a proceeding the opportunity “Fees for use of a single song in a motion picture
to oppose settlements by proceeding partici- range from a few thousand dollars to $50,000 or
pants and to require the initiation of new more.” See Rachlin, p. 202. The website of one of
CARP proceedings. [We] strongly support the many companies that specializes in clearing
adding provisions to the [proposed Act] to such rights provides a vivid description of how
eliminate these barriers to settlement. markets work in this area:

32. David Nimmer, “A Riff on Fair Use in the Q: Here’s the critical question—how much will
Digital Millennium Copyright Act,” University of a synchronization license [the technical name
Pennsylvania Law Review 148 (2000): 673, 675. for using copyrighted music in a movie or TV
show] cost?
33. Nimmer, “Ignoring the Public, Part I” p. 189.
A: That depends on a lot of factors, not least of
34. Jukeboxes were exempt from paying royalties which is the nature of the music you’re looking
to songwriters until the 1976 act added a com- for. If a client calls us up and blithely
pulsory license. This was originally set very low— announces that they’ve got $5,000.00 and are
$8.00 per year per jukebox. After the jukebox roy- looking for a Beatles song, we will gently advise
alty was included in the Copyright Arbitration them that those kinds of dollars simply will
Royalty Panel structure in the 1976 Copyright Act not buy a Lennon-McCartney tune. Likewise, if
(17 U.S.S. § 116) an arbitration panel increased we call up the publisher of “Pickle-for-a-Nickel-
the amount to $50 per machine. Currently, juke- with-the-Mustard-on-Top” to negotiate a one-
boxes are subject to a voluntary negotiation week usage on a radio station in the village of
backed up by the threat of a royalty arbitration Carbuncle, and they grandly declare that they
tribunal, 17 U.S.C. § 116 (2003). The emergence won’t take less than $100,000.00 for such a
of Internet-based “on-demand” jukeboxes sheds usage, we will firmly inform them that such
light on the undervaluation of musical composi- funds will not be forthcoming.
tions in the jukebox context. This new generation
of jukeboxes is not subject to the threat of a com- Available at http://www.patcoresources.com/
pulsory license. Instead, digital jukebox compa- piece-of-music.htm. For background on the high-
nies (such as Ecast of San Francisco) enter into ly competitive “music publishing” industry,
individual agreements with the owners of musical which handles deal-making for these rights (as
composition copyrights. The royalty rates in these well as others related to music), see http://www.
agreements are potentially much more flexible nmpa.org/nmpa. html.
than those subject to the one-size-fits-all statuto-
ry rate or conventional jukeboxes. And there is 39. In 2001, the Harry Fox Agency—which han-
evidence now that consumers value songs played dles many of the transactions in this area—report-
on a jukebox much more highly than was tradi- ed synchronization license revenue of $620 mil-
tionally thought. See, for example, Jon Healey, lion. See National Music Publishers Association,
“Paying for Music on Demand,” Los Angeles Times, 2001 Annual Report, www.nmpa.org/pr/NMPA_
September 18, 2003, p. C2. (“Tracks from tradi- Inter national_Survey_12th_Edition.pdf.
tional jukeboxes run 50 cents or less apiece, while
Ecast’s machines charge up to $2.50.”) 40. This section draws on Merges, “Contracting
into Liability Rules.”
35. Joseph Taubman, In Tune with the Music Business
(New York: Law-Arts, 1980). 41. Once SoundExchange had been formed, one
might suppose that the parties would simply have
36. See generally Al Kohn and Bob Kohn, Kohn on proceeded to private negotiations without waiting
Music Licensing (New York: Aspen, 2002): 778. for the CARP panel to reach its decision. It is clear,
however, that the looming presence of the CARP
37. The Harry Fox Agency of New York is the prevented almost all private negotiations. Everyone
largest “synchronization rights” agent for copy- chose to make some “influence expenditures” and
right owners, bringing together the myriad sellers wait. See Library of Congress, Copyright Office,
of these rights—typically, music publishing com- “Determination of Reasonable Rates and Terms
panies—with prospective buyers, typically produc- for the Digital Performance of Sound Recordings
ers or music coordinators for movie studios and and Ephemeral Recordings,” July 8, 2002.
television production companies. See Harvey
Rachlin, The TV and Movie Business: An Encyclopedia 42. Quoted in Drew Clark, “Sensenbrenner Takes
of Careers, Technologies, and Practices 1991 (Nevada New Approach to Recording Industry,” National
City, CA: Harmony Books, 1991), p. 203 Journal Technology Daily, March 28, 2001.

38. For example, one industry account states that 43. Noel L. Hillman, “Intractable Consent: A

14
Legislative Solution to the Problem of the Aging media companies specifically to compete with
Consent Decrees in United States v. ASCAP and ASCAP—may be helpful.
United States v. BMI,” Fordham Intellectual Property
Media and Entertainment Law Journal 8 (1998): 773. 46. Note that the Copyright Act exempts
SoundExchange and any competitor that may
44. See 17 U.S.C. § 114(e)(1). arise from antitrust liability for certain negotia-
tion and price-setting activities. See 17 U.S.C. §
45. Again, the example of BMI—formed by large 114(e) (2003).

Published by the Cato Institute, Policy Analysis is a regular series evaluating government policies and offer-
ing proposals for reform. Nothing in Policy Analysis should be construed as necessarily reflecting the views
of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before congress. Contact the
Cato Institute for reprint permission. Additional copies of Policy Analysis are $6.00 each ($3.00 each for five
or more). To order, or for a complete listing of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000
Massachusetts Ave., N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call toll free 1-800-767-1241 (noon - 9 p.m. eastern
time), fax (202) 842-3490, or visit our website at www.cato.org.

15

You might also like