You are on page 1of 90

THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO

ACCOUNTING FRAUD: BOOMS, BUSTS, AND INCENTIVES TO PERFORM

A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED TO
THE FACULTY OF THE UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO
BOOTH SCHOOL OF BUSINESS
IN CANDIDACY FOR THE DEGREE OF
DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY

BY
ROBERT HENRY DAVIDSON

CHICAGO, ILLINOIS
JUNE 2011

UMI Number: 3460166

All rights reserved


INFORMATION TO ALL USERS
The quality of this reproduction is dependent on the quality of the copy submitted.
In the unlikely event that the author did not send a complete manuscript
and there are missing pages, these will be noted. Also, if material had to be removed,
a note will indicate the deletion.

UMI 3460166
Copyright 2011 by ProQuest LLC.
All rights reserved. This edition of the work is protected against
unauthorized copying under Title 17, United States Code.

ProQuest LLC.
789 East Eisenhower Parkway
P.O. Box 1346
Ann Arbor, MI 48106 - 1346

Copyright Robert Henry Davidson 2011

DEDICATION

I dedicate this dissertation to my father,

Daniel Robert Davidson

TABLE OF CONTENTS

List of Tables

List of Figures

vii

Acknowledgements

viii

Abstract

ix

Introduction

Literature

Hypothesis Development

Data: AAERs

19

Tests and Results

25

Robustness Checks

58

Conclusion

65

References

66

Appendix 1

70

iv

LIST OF TABLES

Table 1: Descriptive Statistics: Fraud Sample

22

Table 2: Time-Series Regressions

30

Table 3: Correlation Matrix

33

Table 4: Descriptive Statistics

35

Table 5A: Hazard Analysis

37

Table 5B: Hazard Analysis: Compensation Sub-Sample

39

Table 6A: Hazard Analysis: Market Incentive Proxies

43

Table 6B: Hazard Analysis: Compensation Sub-Sample

46

Table 7: Logistic Regressions: Interactions

52

Table 8: Hazard Analysis: Fraud Type

56

Table 9: Chi Squared Tests

57

Appendix Table 1: Variable Definitions

70

Appendix Table 2: Descriptive Statistics

71

Appendix Table 3: Hazard Analysis: SEC Chair Fixed Effects

72

Appendix Table 4: Hazard Analysis: Industry Level

73

Appendix Table 5: Hazard Analysis: Firm-Level Variables

74

Appendix Table 6: Hazard Analysis: Market Incentive Proxies

75

Appendix Table 7: Hazard Analysis: Industry Level

76

Appendix Table 8: Logistic Regressions: Interactions

79

Appendix Table 9: Hazard Analysis: Fraud Type ERC

80

vi

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1: Accounting Fraud by Year

28

Figure 2: Percentage of Accounting Fraud by Year

29

vii

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I am grateful for many helpful comments from my dissertation committee: Abbie Smith (chair),
Ray Ball, Ryan Ball, and Christian Leuz. I would also like to thank Phil Berger, Aiyesha Dey,
Merle Erickson, Joseph Gerakos, Andrei Kovrijnykh, Michael Minnis, Valeri Nikolaev, ZoeVonna Palmrose, Haresh Sapra, Oren Yoeli, Shimeng Yu, and Sarah Zechman as well as
participants in seminars at the University of Chicago Booth School of Business, Georgetown
University, The University of Texas at Dallas, The University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign,
and Purdue University.

viii

ABSTRACT

In this thesis, I examine whether macroeconomic conditions influence the propensity to commit
accounting fraud. I find that the incidence of observed accounting fraud is increasing in GDP
and is at its highest in the periods leading up to an economic peak. In addition, the incidence of
observed accounting fraud is decreasing in the average correlation between firm and market
returns and the average magnitude of analyst forecast errors; the relation is increasing in
market price-earnings ratios. When examining the relation between macroeconomic conditions
and firm-level fraud determinants I find that the association between CEO compensation
incentives and the propensity to observe accounting fraud is generally negative, but is positive
and significant during periods of high price sensitivity to earnings news. I also find that
although the association between the firms need for external financing and the propensity to
observe accounting fraud is positive, it is only significant during periods of high price
sensitivity to earnings news. Analyzing accounting fraud by type reveals that revenue fraud is
increasing in price sensitivity to revenue news; this relation does not exist for expense or
balance sheet fraud. Balance sheet fraud is increasing in the default risk premium. These
results are consistent with the hypothesis that market-wide incentives for managers to
manipulate earnings influence the decision to commit accounting fraud above and beyond firmlevel determinants.

ix

1. Introduction

Over the last 100 years, recessions have been routinely accompanied by revelations of
scandalous reporting failures at many firms. Fraudulent reporting was exposed after the Great
Crash in 1929, after the Savings & Loans scandal in the 1980s, and after the dot-com bubble of
the late 1990s/early 2000s1. Sweeping changes in regulation often followed these scandals; for
example, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act was drafted to reduce the incidence of fraudulent reporting
after the dot-com crash. Additionally, Baker and Wurgler [2007] note the dramatic decrease in
stock prices that occurs during these periods. Reduced firm value, reduced investor confidence,
increased bankruptcies, increased unemployment, and increased regulation all contribute to the
total welfare cost from widespread accounting fraud.

Prior research finds that managers commit accounting fraud partly in response to strong
financial incentives2. These incentives include avoiding, among other things, termination, a
decline in the value of their stocks and options, a downgrade of the companys debt, debt
covenant violations, and corporate bankruptcy. The strength of these financial incentives varies
over time. Moreover, the strength of these incentives varies cross-sectionally as well.

Theoretical research predicts that the level of accounting fraud in the economy is not
constant over time; neither is the strength of the managers financial incentives created by the
1

Galbraith [1961] discusses the scandals that followed the Great Crash. Ball [2009] discusses the wave of scandals
that came to light after the dot-com bubble burst.
2

Dechow et al [1996] find that managers commit fraud to access the capital markets on favorable terms. Johnson
et al [2009] find that managers commit fraud due to financial incentives from their compensation packages.
Graham et al [2005] find survey evidence that managers manipulate earnings to keep their firms share price high.

capital and labor markets. Research on firm-level determinants of accounting fraud often yields
contradictory results and does not consider, first, how the strength of incentives varies over
time and, second, differential effects across these incentives. Do changes in the macro economy
influence managers reporting decisions above and beyond firm-level accounting fraud
determinants? Are certain firm-level accounting fraud determinants only important under
certain environmental conditions? Does the type of accounting fraud managers commit depend
on the source of their incentives?

To answer these questions I gather data on a comprehensive sample of instances of


accounting fraud that occurred in the United States between 1980 and 2005. Over 800 cases of
accounting fraud are revealed over the sample period, including such high profile cases as
Adelphia, Enron, Sunbeam, Tyco, and WorldCom.

Having identified the period the violation began, I use survival analysis to test whether
observed accounting fraud is related to macroeconomic performance and whether we observe
more managers reporting fraudulently after a long boom period. I then construct three
macroeconomic proxies measuring the relative strength of incentives the capital and labor
markets create and test whether these proxies explain the increase in fraudulent reporting
observed during certain periods. I interact hypothesized firm-level accounting fraud
determinants with a market measure of price sensitivity to short-term news to see whether firmlevel determinants affect managers more strongly in certain environments. Finally, I split
accounting fraud into three groups revenue fraud, expense fraud, and balance sheet fraud to
test for differential effects across incentives to commit accounting fraud.
2

In survival analysis including both fraud firms and a random sample of non-fraud firms,
I find more observed cases of accounting fraud start in periods of strong aggregate performance
and in the two years leading up to an economic peak. This finding is robust to the inclusion of
potential firm-level determinants of accounting fraud. Moreover, I find that more managers
start committing accounting fraud in periods wherein firm returns are less correlated with the
market return, in periods wherein predicting earnings is easier, and in periods wherein priceearnings ratios are high.

In logistic analysis testing the relation between accounting fraud and firm-level fraud
determinants interacted with price sensitivity to news, I find that the delta of the CEOs stock
holdings is positive and significantly related to accounting fraud only in periods of high price
sensitivity to short-term news. I also find that while the relation between raising capital and
accounting fraud is generally positive, it is statistically significant only in periods of high price
sensitivity to news.

In survival analysis of accounting fraud by type, I find more observed cases of revenue
fraud in periods of high price sensitivity to revenue news; expense fraud is similarly related to
price sensitivity to earnings news, rather than revenue news. I also find that balance sheet
fraud is positively related to the default risk premium; no significant relation exists between
revenue or expense fraud and the default risk premium. Overall, these findings are consistent
both with the environment playing a role in managers financial reporting decisions and with
managers responding to external market driven incentives by committing accounting fraud in
periods when those incentives are strongest.
3

This paper contributes to the literature in several ways. First, by demonstrating that a
given managers decision to commit accounting fraud is related to macroeconomic conditions, it
provides support for the hypothesis that market wide incentives influence managers reporting
decisions incremental to firm-level effects. Second, as logistic results suggest, the macro
environment affects the strength of the financial incentives from CEO incentive compensation
or the firms need for external financing; managers reporting decisions are only influenced by
these incentives when they are at their strongest. Third, this paper documents a differential
effect across incentives to commit accounting fraud. For example, managers are more likely to
commit revenue fraud when the demand for top-line growth is high and are more likely to
commit balance sheet fraud when the risk of default is high. Finally, it provides a novel
explanation for the contradictory results reported in the literature and the lack of consensus
regarding the relation between accounting fraud and firm-level determinants thereof.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows: section 2 reviews the relevant
literature; section 3 develops testable hypotheses; section 4 describes the data; section 5
describes my empirical tests and presents my results; section 6 discusses my tests for robustness
and section 7 concludes.

2. Literature

Most research on the relation between accounting fraud and the environment in which it
occurs is theoretical. Though each of these models assumptions and mechanisms are different,

they all predict that more managers start to commit accounting fraud in periods of strong
aggregate performance.

Povel, Singh, and Winton [2007] present a model of collective accounting fraud wherein
a given manager is motivated to obtain funding for a project; investors choose either to rely on a
public signal from the manager or to invest in costly but unbiased private monitoring before
deciding whether to invest. Depending on investors beliefs about the state of the world, a
manager with a bad project can increase his chances of obtaining funding by overstating the
projects value. Povel et al [2007] find that the relation between accounting fraud, actual
performance, and expected performance is non-monotonic. Specifically, fraud peaks in good
but not great states of the world. The primary determinant of their findings is the level of
monitoring effort investors exert, which is influenced by the macro economy.

Hertzberg [2005] develops a model wherein variation in the managers short-term and
long-term incentives in turn creates variation in the incentives to commit accounting fraud.
Managers are more likely to commit accounting fraud when their short-term incentives are
strong. Hertzberg, however, does not model which forces alter the composition of the
managers incentives. Short-term incentives could be increased by various changes within the
firm, by capital and labor market activity, or by other forces in the environment.

Rajgopal, Shivakumar, and Simpson [2007] develop and test a catering theory of
earnings management. In their model, the manager is concerned with obtaining the highest
possible price for his firms shares. They find that earnings management increases in periods of
5

high investor optimism, which they define as periods wherein positive earnings surprises
receive a larger price reaction.

Though Rajgopal et al [2007] do not model or directly test the link between earnings
optimism and actual macro performance, they allude to as much and cite some macroeconomic
theories (Lavington [1922] and Collard [1996]) that suggest that periods of earnings optimism
tend to coincide with periods of high real growth. This model is in slight contrast to the one
presented by Povel et al [2007], who argue that when actual performance and expected
performance are both high, managers have less incentive to commit fraud because the true
performance of their firms is high. This difference, however, may derive from the papers
different focuses. Whereas Povel et al [2007] model the decision to commit accounting fraud, a
high risk decision that can lead to large fines and jail time, Rajgopal et al [2007] appear to model
cases of within GAAP earnings management which is a low-risk decision, relatively speaking.

Several recent empirical papers study the relation between accounting fraud and the
environment in which it occurs. Kedia, Koh, and Rajgopal [2010] find that fraudulent reporting
has a contagion effect. Specifically, they find that managers are more likely to commit
accounting fraud after another firm in their industry is revealed to have misreported. They find
this effect only in the absence of SEC litigation of the initial misconduct. While it is not clear
whether this effect is due to managers perceiving a lax regulatory environment (i.e., a reduced
cost to misconduct) or a change in social norms (i.e., that misconduct is condoned), it does
appear to be driven by environmental, as opposed to firm-level, forces.

Fernandes and Guedes [2009] examine the relation between accounting fraud and
expected and actual macro performance. They find a positive relation between the occurrence
of accounting fraud and expected performance and a negative relation between accounting
fraud and actual performance. I, on the other hand, after controlling for the difference between
actual and expected output find a positive relation between accounting fraud and aggregate
output. Several measurement issues related to Fernandes and Guedes [2009] calculation of
accounting fraud could account for our different results. For example, they average Foreign
Corrupt Practices Act violations over a three year period, which makes it impossible to identify
which conditions were present when the manager decided to start committing accounting
fraud. Such averaging can create a mechanical bias that leads to either overstating or
understating the true number of fraud firms present in a given year. A second measurement
issue arises from the years to which they attribute violations. Over their time period, fraudulent
reporting lasts, on average, just under three years. Over the same time period, government
litigation releases tend to occur about three years after the fraud is detected. This means that a
release in 2005 is likely to address accounting fraud that began around 2000. Fernandes and
Guedes [2009] average this release over the period 2003-2005.

Gerety and Lehn [1997] test internal and external forces that can influence the decision to
commit accounting fraud. They find that fraud is more likely in markets wherein it is more
difficult to value assets. Though their tests are done in the cross-section, comparing accounts
such as research and development to property, plant, and equipment, it is possible that there is
also a temporal effect. If assets in general are more difficult to value in certain periods, then this
7

could lead to either increased cases of fraud or decreased detection of fraud. An additional
implication is that fraud should be more prevalent in industries with assets that are more
difficult to value.

Cunningham [2005] also presents a theory of fraud that is related to valuation


difficulties. He argues that the growing prominence of the fair-value movement and the
elevation of cash flows give managers more discretion over reported numbers, which now lack
verifiability, and has led to an increase in fraudulent reporting. This could explain a general
increase in accounting fraud over this time period (starting in the early 1970s), but is less likely
to explain variation in the level of accounting fraud over the business cycle.

Ebert and Gagne [2007] develop a monopoly model of fraud in which managers choose
to commit fraud because of their ability to shift the costs onto the company. The managers
ability to shift costs is related to his power and ability to subvert internal controls. In this
model, the costs of accounting fraud increase at a slower rate for the manager than for the firm.
If the power of the average CEO has increased over the last 30 years, then this model provides
an explanation for the increase in the magnitude of the average fraud case over the last 30 years.
As accounting frauds become larger, the CEO takes on a decreasing fraction of the costs.

Miller [2006] investigates the role of the press as a watchdog for accounting fraud. If the
press incentives to investigate possible fraud firms vary over time, this could lead to variation
in the number of perpetrated or detected cases of accounting fraud. Miller [2006] finds that in
the cross section, firms with a richer information environment are more likely to be cited in the
8

press. He also finds that the type of fraud matters; insider trading sells for example. There is
no evidence of a temporal shift in the efforts of the press to uncover and report accounting
fraud.

Dechow, Ge, Larson, and Sloan [2010] use many hypothesized firm-level symptoms and
determinants of accounting fraud to develop a predictive model of fraud. They develop an
audit tool, the F-Score, which has the ability to identify fraud firms ex post. Though their
research question is different from mine, our papers have several similarities. First, to build
their sample of accounting fraud, Dechow et al [2010] hand collect, as I do, a large sample (i.e.,
2190) of SEC Accounting and Auditing Enforcement Releases; theirs is also one of the few
papers to analyze several hundred fraud firms. The difference between our reported sample
sizes is that while Dechow et al [2010] include in their analysis all fraud years for a given firm, I
include only the first year of fraudulent reporting. Second, both Dechow et al [2010] and I test
market-related motives for accounting fraud. Specifically, we both report a positive association
between accounting fraud and both the propensity to raise capital and lagged abnormal returns.

3. Hypothesis Development

Becker [1968] presents a rational theory of crime that reduces the decision to commit a
crime to a weighing of the benefits against the associated costs. A given managers decision to
report truthfully or to commit accounting fraud can be analyzed in this context. The costs to the
manager, if his crime is detected, are substantial and include fines, jail time, and loss of
reputation. Therefore, the perceived costs of reporting truthfully or, conversely, the perceived
9

benefits of reporting fraudulently - must also be substantial before a manager would choose to
commit accounting fraud.

Analytical research supports the claim that the level of accounting fraud in the economy
is not constant over time. That accounting scandals come in waves is supported by anecdotal
evidence. Thus, the forces that greatly influence the perceived costs of truthfully reporting
poor performance do not appear to be constant over time. These forces can arise from within
the firm, but can also arise from the environment the firm operates in.

Survey evidence from Graham, Harvey, and Rajgopal [2005] indicates that executives
manipulate earnings to maintain or increase their firms share price. Baker, Ruback, and
Wurgler [2007] suggest that managers manipulate earnings to cater to market demands.
Following this evidence, I assume that a given manager will be motivated to keep the price of
his firms shares high and, when faced with reporting performance below ex ante expectation,
will base his decision of whether to report truthfully on the presence of environmental factors
that affect the net benefits of accounting fraud. A given managers market driven incentives are
not constant over time, so we should observe an increase in fraudulent reporting in periods
wherein those incentives are strongest.

3.1 Time Variance

Recent literature predicts that the relation between accounting fraud and
macroeconomic performance is positive, though not necessarily monotonic3. Proposed

Povel et al [2007], Hertzberg [2005], and Strobl [2008] all develop analytical models that find this result.

10

hypotheses for this relation include the belief that monitors, such as external auditors, debt
holders, and shareholders reduce their effort during periods of strong aggregate performance
and the belief that investors are more likely to believe what firms report during periods of
strong aggregate performance. These specific hypotheses, however, are difficult to test
empirically because of difficulties in measuring monitors effort or how willing investors are to
believe financial statements.

These hypotheses seem to implicitly assume that the opportunities managers have to
commit accounting fraud are the key determinant of fraud because they do not address the
managers motivations to commit fraud. A more comprehensive argument considers both. I
argue that managers care about their firms performance measured against both their firms
expected performance and performance relative to peers and that performing poorly across
either dimension can increase a managers incentives to commit accounting fraud. Myers,
Myers, and Skinner [2006] document the importance to managers of consistently exceeding
expectation. They find that firms with long strings of positive earnings surprises have higher
share prices than do firms with similar long run performance but without the consecutive
strings of positive surprises. Martin and McConnell [1991] find that takeover targets perform
better than the market but worse than their peer groups. Antle and Smith [1986] and Gibbons
and Murphy [1992] both find that relative performance is sometimes explicitly written into
compensation contracts. Share price, job retention, and CEO compensation are all influenced by
the firms performance, relative to both its own expected performance and to that of its peers.

11

Ball [2009] argues that high growth is built into performance expectations during a
boom period and that managers therefore come under peer and financial pressures to deliver
strong earnings growth and share market performance4. When, inevitably, some firms
experience declining performance relative to their own expectations and/or their peers, the
managers of these firms find themselves unable to meet their heightened expectations. Such
managers know the consequences of poor performance and have particularly strong incentives
to meet expectation.

Building on research related to investor sentiment, Baker and Wurgler [2007] argue that
during the boom phase of the late 1990s extraordinary investor sentiment pushed the prices of
many stocks to unfathomable heights that could not be justified by the facts at hand. They
further note that risks and limits to arbitrage made it too difficult for contrarian arbitrageurs
to bring prices back down to appropriate levels. This extremely high optimism was built into
the markets expectation of firm performance. Baker and Wurgler [2006] find that investor
sentiment has a greater effect on firms with higher growth prospects; on average, firms have
higher growth prospects when the aggregate economy is experiencing a high growth boom.
The prior literature leads me to my first hypothesis:

H1A: The relation between macroeconomic performance and accounting fraud is positive.

Given that the costs associated with reporting truthfully increase dramatically for
managers when their firm is performing poorly relative to benchmarks, I expect to find that

Galbraith [1961] makes a similar case for the events leading up to the 1929 market crash.

12

periods characterized by high benchmarks and a reasonable number of firms starting to


perform below expectation have higher levels of observed cases of accounting fraud. These
characteristics describe the years leading up to an economic peak. Such periods are generally
characterized by years of sustained growth that does not continue far into the future. Many
firms experience high growth in the years leading up to the peak, and their current forecasts are
formulated, in part, on this prior growth. Ex post we know that a number of firms experience a
decrease in performance right before the economy peaks and starts to decline.

H1B: The relation between observed accounting fraud and the years before an economic peak is
positive.

A related area of research looks at the progression a firm and manager make to get to
the point where a given manager commits accounting fraud. Schrand and Zechman [2008]
argue that there is a slippery slope to accounting fraud wherein managers start off looking to
plug small gaps in performance and may have no intention of committing accounting fraud. If
the firms performance does not improve in subsequent periods, a manager may continue to
plug the small gaps; over time, however, the amount of manipulated earnings can grow
egregious and the manager will then face either reporting truthfully and reversing his past
entries, or continuing down the path towards accounting fraud. Empirical and anecdotal
evidence support the slippery slope theory; this evidence does not change the predictions I
make in this paper. I posit that market driven incentives and the firms environment influence
managers in the same way regardless of whether a given manager has shown a willingness to
slightly manipulate earnings in the past or would have to reverse his past entries if he chose to
13

report truthfully. While a manager who has previously manipulated earnings may be more
willing to commit accounting fraud, environmental factors likely influence all managers in the
same direction, even if by varying degree.

3.2 Market Based Incentives

Knowing in which environments managers are more likely to commit accounting fraud
is a helpful starting point for developing hypotheses about which market forces create such
strong incentives that managers respond to them by committing accounting fraud. If more
managers report fraudulently in good times, then the focus can shift to stimulants that are
particularly strong in these periods. Market wide incentives affect all firms in the economy at
the same time and to a highly correlated degree. Therefore, looking at changes in these
incentives over time is required to test the theory that market driven incentives influence a
managers reporting decisions.

Many areas of research document that markets create significant incentives for
managers to perform5. Benmelech, Kandal, and Veronesi [2010] show that while incentivebased compensation induces managers to exert costly effort, it also induces them to conceal bad
news about future growth options and to choose sub-optimal investment policies. They argue
that in periods with strong market incentives, or periods wherein price is highly sensitive to
short term news, incentive compensation should be reduced. Though accounting fraud is not
the focus of their paper, Benmelech et al [2010] nevertheless mention that fraudulent reporting
5

For examples of the effects of market incentives, see Gray, Meek, and Roberts [1995], and Cao and Laksmana
[2010].

14

is one possible response a manager can have to poor performance in periods wherein price
sensitivity to news is high. Such a manager has incentives to keep his firms share price high
because this affects both his compensation and the probability of job retention. Disappointing
investors by performing poorly reduces the price of the firms shares, reduces the value of a
managers incentive based compensation, and increases the likelihood of the manager being
replaced.

H2: The relation between observed accounting fraud and market driven incentives is positive.

Empirically separating capital market from labor market incentives is difficult. Poor
performance reduces share price, increases the cost of capital, increases pressure from investors,
and increases the likelihood of replacement. My main argument is that the incentives to commit
accounting fraud originate in the labor market, but normally include equity sensitive
compensation. If managers are ultimately concerned with their net worth, then we can assume
that meeting the expectations of both the capital and labor markets is important to them.
Hypothesis 3 attempts to isolate the effects on accounting fraud of the value of the managers
incentive plans and net worth and on his firms need to access the capital markets.

3.3 Relation between market-based incentives and firm-level accounting fraud determinants

Research on firm-level determinants of accounting fraud often produces inconsistent


and in some cases contradictory results. Common issues in this area of research are small

15

sample sizes6 and samples collected over short periods7. These issues could mean that the
differences in results have nothing to do with econometric or measurement issues, but are
driven by fluctuations in the strength of market wide incentives that influence both the decision
to commit accounting fraud and managers operating, financing, and reporting decisions.
Essentially, prior research may have overlooked an important factor when modeling firm-level
accounting fraud determinants. For example, research on the link between incentive
compensation and accounting fraud has yielded mixed results. While Benmelech et al [2010]
show that incentive compensation induces the manager to exert costly effort, the extent to
which it also gives the manager incentives to commit accounting fraud remains unclear.
Johnson et al. [2009] find a positive relation between CEO unrestricted stock holdings and
accounting fraud while Armstrong et al. [2009] find a negative relation between incentive
compensation and accounting fraud. Benmelech et al. [2010] argue that the effect of incentive
compensation is not constant and is, rather, influenced by market behavior. In periods wherein
the sensitivity of price to short-term news is high, managers have increased incentives to
conceal bad news.

H3A: The relation between observed accounting fraud and price sensitivity of the CEOs net
worth is positive and more pronounced in periods wherein stock price is highly sensitive to shortterm news.

Beneish [1997] analyzes 49 fraud firms drawn from AAERs. Erickson et al [2004] analyze the amount of tax 27
fraud firms pay on fraudulent inflated earnings.
7

Kedia and Philippon [2007] study violations between 1996 and 2001.

16

While Dechow et al. [1996] find that accounting fraud is often motivated by concerns
about the cost of external financing, Beneish [1999] finds no support for this claim. The effect of
firm performance on the cost of external financing is not constant. It is possible that the
incentives arising from a need to access the capital markets are strong enough to influence the
managers reporting decisions only in periods wherein the fraudulently inflated earnings will
have the greatest effect on the value of securities.

H3B: The relation between observed accounting fraud and the decision to raise capital is positive
and more pronounced in periods wherein price is highly sensitive to short-term news.

3.4 Differential effects across type of accounting fraud committed

Financial statements report the aggregation of many individual transactions and entries.
Managers can commit accounting fraud by intentionally misrepresenting any combination of
these individual transactions. For example, a manager can increase net income by overstating
revenue, understating expenses, or by manipulating both. This choice is likely strategic and
reflects specific expectations the manager wishes to meet. Revenue, expense, and balance sheet
information is used by numerous agents for numerous purposes. A manager can have strong
incentives to improve along one of these dimensions while having not nearly as strong of
incentives to improve along the others. If market driven incentives are an important
determinant of accounting fraud, then we should observe managers committing certain types of
accounting fraud when the incentives for improvement along that dimension are particularly
strong. Ghosh, Gu, and Jain [2005] find the that two components of earnings are differentially
17

informative, suggesting that the interpretation of a positive earnings surprise is in part


determined by whether that surprise is driven by increased revenues, or decreased expenses.
Further, Ertimur, Livnat, and Martikainen [2003] find that revenue surprises are more
important for growth firms and during high growth periods. The market demand for revenue
growth varies independently from that of earnings growth. When the demand for top line
growth is high we should observe an increase in revenue fraud but, ceteris paribus, have no
reason to expect an increase in expense or balance sheet fraud.

H4A: The relation between revenue fraud and sensitivity of price to revenue news is positive and
incremental to any relation to sensitivity of price to earnings news, and is related to a stronger
degree than is expense or balance sheet fraud.

In addition to revenue and expense information having differential interpretations, the


income statement and balance sheet are often used by different agents for different purposes.
For example, Watts *2003+ notes the prevalence of the balance sheets use in contracting when
discussing conservatism in accounting. Common covenants written into debt contracts include
restrictions against issuing more debt, requiring a minimum level of working capital, and
placing limits on certain ratios such as interest coverage and debt-to-equity. When analyzing
developments in credit risk management, Altman and Saunders [1998] cite the extensive use of
the balance sheet in credit risk assessment. They also note that an important goal of the last 10
years has been to properly analyze the balance sheet in light of the rise of many forms of offbalance sheet debt. Bernanke and Gertler [1989] develop a model of the business cycle where
higher net assets reduce the agency costs of financing real capital investments. In their model,
18

the balance sheet is more important in periods of high financial distress. Many of the incentives
for a strong balance sheet relate to credit risk or bankruptcy risk and the strength of these
incentives varies through time.

H4B: The relation between balance sheet fraud and the default risk premium is positive and is
related to a stronger degree than is revenue or expense fraud.

4. Data: AAERs

I use SEC Accounting and Auditing Enforcement Releases (AAERs) as a proxy for
accounting fraud. These releases summarize investigations the SEC brings against the agents of
firms for violations of SEC and Federal rules. AAERs clearly state whether a violation is for
accounting fraud or some other infraction (e.g., securities law violations). To collect my sample,
I read through AAERs 1 3148 which were released between May 17, 1982 and June 29, 2010.
After limiting my sample to violations for accounting fraud wherein the fraud has a
determinable start date and then removing redundant cases, I am left with 824 firms.

Determining which types of violations to include involves a degree of subjectivity.


Ultimately, I include in my final sample only those firms for which it can be determined that
their financial statements (or notes) were materially misstated. One exception to this rule is
violations due to options backdating. Only a small number of AAERs involve options
backdating, and their inclusion marginally improves the results of some of the tests. I
nevertheless exclude these cases because most of the time, the illegal act related to forging
documents or failing to disclose the backdating to shareholders, not to overstating net earnings
19

or assets. The choice to include violations for revenue (or asset) understatement is also
subjective. As with cases of options backdating, only a small number of AAERs (i.e., 4 cases)
involve violations for revenue or asset understatement.8 This could be due to fewer managers
having strong incentives to understate revenues or to the SEC having weaker incentives to
prosecute these types of violations. Because my hypotheses relate to the incentives to overstate,
rather than understate, earnings or net assets, I exclude these cases.

Only firms under the jurisdiction of the SEC are prosecuted and included in the AAER
sample. Firms that do not issue public debt or equity in the United States are not included.
Given that I test the relation between capital and labor market incentives and accounting fraud,
collecting a sample of fraud firms from the universe of firms under SEC jurisdiction should
represent a fair proxy, relative to the alternatives. Small private firms are not included because
the owners of these firms generally do not have concerns related to labor market incentives (i.e.,
they often have a controlling interest) or to capital market incentives from public shareholders
(i.e., public shareholders are often nonexistent). Debt holders tend to be concerned about
downside risk and the cash flows required to service debt, not about whether the firm exceeds
high growth expectations.

Although a number of international firms do raise public capital in the United States and
fall under the jurisdiction of the SEC, the AAER sample contains only a handful of such firms.
Several explanations are consistent with this finding: international firms may commit

Xerox and Microsoft are two well known cases of revenue/asset understatement litigated by the SEC.

20

accounting fraud, as defined by the SEC, less frequently than domestic firms, increased costs to
prosecute agents who do not reside in the United States, or lower demand to prosecute these
agents because foreign firms have fewer U.S. shareholders. My macro variables are calculated
using U.S. centric data (e.g. U.S. GDP and surprise, and SEC budget data) and my market wide
incentives proxies are calculated using Compustat North America data. Therefore, I exclude
firms headquartered outside of the U.S. from my sample of 824 fraud firms.

Data restrictions limit the number of fraud firm observations available for firm-level
analysis. Table 1 presents the number of firms lost at each stage. The two primary reasons for
the decline in sample size are the lack of any identifying code for the firm (363 firms) and the
absence of CRSP and Compustat data before and during the period wherein the fraud began
(190 firms). The primary survival analysis includes 271 firms. While this is a large drop from
my original sample of 824 firms, it is large compared to prior research9. Of these 271 firms, only
104 have Execucomp compensation data available; I therefore conduct two sets of analysis, one
with and one without variables for CEO compensation.

AAERs offer several advantages relative to other proxies for accounting fraud. First and
foremost, it is clear whether the managers of firms in the AAER sample actually committed
accounting fraud, making the probability of type 1 errors negligible. I am specifically interested
in violations of Section 13(a) and Section 13(b)(2)(A) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934

Dechow et al [2010] is one important exception to the general trend of small sample sizes in prior research. Their
main analysis includes between 354 and 494 fraud firm years. My analysis, which includes several of the variables
they use in their most restrictive tests, is based on a sample of 271 individual fraud firms.

21

which requires issuers to make and keep books, records, and accounts, which, in reasonable
detail, accurately and fairly reflect the transactions and dispositions of assets of the issuer.
AAERs are often issued for violations of Section 13 of the Securities Exchange Act and they
clearly note which violations occurred, making them an appropriate choice to test my

Table 1
Descriptive Statistics: Fraud Sample

Sample collection period

1982-2010

Sample period of violations

1980-2005

Total AAERs

3148

AAERs not involving accounting fraud and redundant AAERs

2298

Total accounting fraud AAERs

852

Cases of options backdating

24

Cases of asset/revenue understatement

Number of fraud cases in time-series analysis

824

Firms without CRSP identifiers

329

Firms with CRSP identifiers but no data to calculate lagged returns

190

Remaining firms without Compustat identifiers/data

34

Firms available for firm-level survival analysis

271

Remaining firms without compensation data

167

Firms available for survival analysis with compensation data

104

Average Duration of Fraud

2.50 years

Median Duration of Fraud

2 years

Shortest Case

1 quarter

Longest Case

13 years

This table provides summary information about the AAER sample, including the number of fraud firms and years, and describes the
reductions in sample size due to data requirements.

22

hypotheses. This is not necessarily true for earnings restatements, which also occur because of
clerical error, change in accounting policy, or numerous other factors in addition to accounting
fraud. This is also not necessarily true for observations from the Stanford Law Database on
Shareholder Lawsuits. Though many shareholder lawsuits arise from intentional material
misstatements, many more arise for other reasons. Moreover, many shareholder lawsuits allege
intentional misstatements when there is no clear evidence to support that claim.

In the earnings management literature, some measure of abnormal accruals is often used
as a proxy for earnings management. Whether these measures have much ability to discern
earnings management in the aggregate, however, is debatable. Ball [2009] points out that much
of the academic research on earnings management establishes a rather weak burden of proof.
Ball [2009] goes on to state that one advantage of focusing on negligent or fraudulent financial
reporting is that a proven case of negligent or fraudulent financial reporting is an institutional
fact, as distinct from an error-prone academic estimate. Further, Correia *2010+ shows that
accruals models are correlated at less than 5 percent with ex post measures of accounting fraud.

Another advantage of using AAERs is that they provide a great deal of information
about the nature and timing of the violation. They generally provide clearer information about
the start and end dates of the violation than do releases of violations of the Foreign Corrupt
Practices Acts (FCPA) books and records laws. Testing the environmental conditions present at
the time a manager starts to commit accounting fraud requires as detailed and accurate
information as possible about the start date of the violation. One last important advantage of
using AAERs is that most of them provide clear information regarding which accounts or totals
23

were manipulated. AAERs denote whether the primary manipulations increased revenue,
reduced expenses, or increased net assets on the balance sheet. This information is required to
test Hypothesis 4. In many cases, information regarding the specific entries booked or illegal
agreements entered into is provided, ensuring I can accurately categorize accounting fraud into
types.

AAERs do, however, have several limitations. One drawback of using any ex post
measure of accounting fraud (i.e., AAERs, restatements, FCPA releases) is that they only
document cases that are detected a potentially important issue that is difficult to completely
address. If the SECs detection methods or litigation decisions contain any bias, then this issue
becomes particularly relevant to AAERs. That said, as Dechow et al [2010] point out, the SEC
identifies firms for review through anonymous tips, news reports, voluntary firm restatements,
and their own review practices. Several independent sources provide information regarding
potential malfeasance, which should reduce the possibility of bias in the SECs detection
methods.

The SEC faces budgetary constraints and only prosecutes those cases where there is
strong evidence against the firm. Time-variance in budget constraints could influence the
composition of the sample. To control for this possibility, I include the SECs annual budget
appropriation in my models. However, analyzing my sample of AAERs provides anecdotal
evidence that budget constraints do not create much bias. Indeed, my sample includes 24 cases
in which the manipulation amounted to less than $1 million dollars, which suggests that the
SEC has the resources to prosecute cases of relatively small manipulations as long as there is
24

strong evidence of malfeasance. Further, there is no statute of limitations for litigating cases of
accounting fraud.

Another concern related to using AAERs is that lags in detection and/or AAER release
could cause the number of new fraud cases to be understated in the last few years of the sample
period. To mitigate this possibility, I include in the sample only violations that started before
2006. In the AAER sample, accounting fraud lasts on average 2.5 years and the corresponding
release is published on average 3 years after the violation is detected. Therefore, performing
tests through 2005 should greatly reduce the likelihood that the most recent years contain an
unrepresentative number of fraud cases10.

5. Tests and Results

I test Hypotheses 1A and 1B using time-series and survival analysis. While the small
number of years in my sample and concerns about correlated omitted variables limits the ability
of the time-series regressions to establish causality, these regressions still provide descriptive
evidence on when we observe more managers choosing to commit accounting fraud and on the
magnitude of the effect that changes in the macro economy has on the propensity to observe
new cases of accounting fraud. To test Hypotheses 1A and 1B, I estimate time-series regressions
of the following general form:

fraud i macro _ performance surprise .

10

(1)

Results are not sensitive to the choice of cutoff year. I also used 2003 and 2004 as end years and find that the
significance of my results remains unchanged.

25

Fraud is measured as the number of managers who start committing fraud during a
given year scaled by the number of Compustat firms in that year. Macro performance is
measured using GDP (inflation adjusted and expressed in chained 2005 100s of billions of
dollars) with the time trend removed using the Hodrick-Prescot [1997] filter1112. To test
Hypothesis 1B I include indicator variables that measure the run up before an economic peak
and the recovery after an economic trough as defined by the National Bureau of Economic
Research (NBER). Peak takes a value of 1 if the current year falls within the two years before an
NBER defined peak and 0 otherwise and Trough takes a value of 1 if the current year falls
within the two years following an NBER defined trough and 0 otherwise. I also include an
indicator variable, PTT, to measure the period between the peak and trough. Including these
indicators allows me to track accounting fraud through the business cycle and to observe how
accounting fraud rises and falls. GDP Surprise is defined as the difference between actual GDP
and expected GDP as forecasted by the Survey of Professional Forecasters, provided by the
Philadelphia FED. I include GDP Surprise because the decision to commit accounting fraud
could be related more to the performance-expectation gap than to performance per se. Because
the vast majority (over 75%) of observed cases of accounting fraud start in the fourth calendar
quarter, I measure and test macro variables contemporaneously with observed cases of
accounting fraud in both the time-series and survival analyses.

11

I also use the Baxter-King [1999] filter and find no change in my results.

12

Focusing on the consumption and investment components of GDP does not change the results. Neither does
using corporate profits.

26

Fraud is measured as a percentage to control for the possibility that the level of
accounting fraud is positively related to the number of firms in the economy. Figures 1 and 2
show the effect of deflating accounting fraud by the number of Compustat firms. Figure 1 plots
new cases of detected accounting fraud by year. There is clear evidence of a time trend in
accounting fraud. However, as shown in Figure 2, when I replace the number of cases of
accounting fraud with the percentage of accounting fraud firms there is no longer such a trend
over the sample period.

As presented in Table 2, the results from annual time-series regressions are consistent
with Hypotheses 1A and 1B. New cases of observed accounting fraud are positively related to
detrended GDP and economic peaks. All time-series standard errors are adjusted using the
Newey-West correction. Because the dependent variable is scaled by total Compustat firms,
interpreting the magnitude of the coefficients yields an increase in the percentage of fraud
firms. The 0.05 coefficient on GDP in the base model of Table 2 indicates that a one standard
deviation increase in GDP ($139 billion) increases the percentage of fraud firms by 0.07 percent.
In 1996, for example, this increase translates into 6 additional cases of accounting fraud - a result
that is both economically significant and feasible. These findings are consistent with the
theoretical literature, which predicts that managers are more likely to commit accounting fraud
in strong economic periods.

Survival analysis allows me to extend tests to the firm level and allows for both
macroeconomic and firm-level controls. To test Hypothesis 1A and 1B, I estimate a Cox

27

28

New Cases of Accounting Fraud

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

Year

Figure 1: Accounting Fraud by Year

Fraud Starts

29

New Cases of Accounting Fraud Scaled by NYSE/AMEX/Nasdaq Firms

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.2

Year

1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

Figure 2: Percentage of Accounting Fraud by Year

Fraud Starts

Table 2
Time-Series Regressions
Base
GDP

Peak

0.05 **
(2.06)

Cycle

0.04

0.04

(0.48)

(0.40)

Peak

0.75 ***
(3.18)

PTT

0.64 **
(2.55)
-0.26
(-0.88)

Trough

-0.22 **
(-2.04)

Surprise

Constant

Observations
R-Squared

0.01

0.01

0.02

(0.23)

(0.14)

(0.26)

0.68 ***

0.97 ***

1.09 ***

(7.95)

(6.17)

(6.53)

26

26

26

6.00%

25.00%

30.00%

This table presents time-series regression estimates for fraud starts at the annual level. The time range in the regressions
is 1980-2005. Standard errors are adjusted using the Newey-West [1987] procedure. ***, **, and * represent significance
at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels, respectively. T-statistics are presented in parentheses. The dependent variable is the
number of managers who start committing fraud in the current year scaled by the number of Compustat firms. GDP is
gross domestic product in chained 2005 billions of dollars, adjusted for inflation, and detrended using the Hodrick
Prescot (1980) filter. Peak is an indicator variable equal to 1 in the 2 years leading up to an economic peak as defined by
NBER. PTT is an indicator variable equal to 1 in the periods between a peak and a trough. Trough is an indicator
variable equal to 1 in the 2 years following an economic trough as defined by NBER. Surprise is GDP less forecasted
GDP as predicted by the Survey of Professional Forecasters provided by the Philadelphia FED.

proportional hazards model of the following general form:

fraud i macro _ perf j macro _ controls k firm level _ controls

(2)

Fraud is now measured with an indicator variable equal to 1 in the period during which
failure occurs (i.e., when the manager starts committing accounting fraud) and 0 otherwise. In
30

the base models I include a measure for GDP change as an additional proxy for macro
performance to see if the results appear to be driven primarily by the level or change in
detrended GDP. Macroeconomic controls include GDP surprise, stock market volatility, the
default risk premium, the SEC budget appropriation, the average time to detect new cases of
accounting fraud, and the number of IPOs in the previous three years. Stock market volatility
captures a component of the information environment; accounting fraud could be related more
to variance in performance and expectation than to actual performance per se. The default risk
premium controls for default risk and the rate at which future cash flows are discounted in the
price-earnings ratio analysis. Many AAERs report that the detection of fraud came after the
firm became insolvent and no longer had enough cash to service its debt obligations or continue
operating. The SECs budget appropriation controls for the SECs ability to detect and litigate
accounting fraud. As suggested in Dyck et al [2007] the SEC is often not the first agent to detect
accounting fraud, which means the SEC budget may not control for a large portion of the
detection environment. However, since my sample of fraud firms is collected from SEC AAERs,
the SEC budget should effectively control for the effect of litigation constraints on the sample.
The average time to detect new cases of accounting fraud controls for changes in monitor effort.
The proxy is imperfect, but it is probable that in years where cases of fraud are detected quickly
that monitors are exerting more effort to detect fraudulent reporting. The number of IPOs over
a 3 year period controls for changes in the composition of firms in the economy. Generally, the
number of IPOs increases during periods of prosperity; if a large number of fraud firms are IPO
firms, then it is possible that the observed increase in accounting fraud during strong economic
31

periods is related to concurrent increases in the number of IPOs. Though the number of IPOs is
unlikely to influence individual fraud firms, it could still explain a significant coefficient on
GDP.

I include the following firm-level determinants of accounting fraud as controls: a raising


capital indicator variable, lagged abnormal returns, and the delta of CEO option and stock
holdings. Capital takes a value of 1 if the firm issued debt or sold common shares in the current
period and 0 otherwise. Dechow [1996] argue that among the reasons managers commit
accounting fraud is that the inflated share price reduces the cost of raising capital. Dechow et al
[2010] test several different proxies of dependency on external financing and find that,
compared with other proxies, an indicator for whether the firm raised capital in the fraud year
has superior predictive power. Lagged abnormal return is defined as the value-weighted
market adjusted firm return for the previous year. Dechow et al [2010] argue that managers
whose firms have optimistic expectations built into their stock price may be more prone than
other managers to overstate their earnings for the purpose of hiding decreasing performance. A
significant coefficient on this variable supports the hypothesis that high expectations and
market driven incentives are among the reasons managers commit accounting fraud. Wealth is
measured using the delta of all options and shares held by the CEO using the Core & Guay
[2002] methodology. While the relation between accounting fraud and incentive compensation
is not clear, it is nevertheless an important consideration. All variables are defined in Appendix
Table 1.

32

33

0.579

0.455

0.426

0.079

0.062

0.005

-0.003

0.069

0.010

-0.011

0.026

-0.001

-0.028

-0.068

0.012

0.024

0.026

0.010

-0.016

0.084

Revenue

Expense

Balance Sheet

GDP

Peak

Trough

Surprise

Volatility

Risk Premium

SEC

Detect

IPO

CA

MAFE

PE

Capital

Lag Ab Return

PE - Firm Level

PR

Wealth

0.002

0.044

0.018

0.022

0.007

0.039

-0.035

-0.054

0.026

0.011

0.028

0.008

0.086

-0.037

-0.018

0.034

0.042

0.363

0.309

1.000

0.808

0.005

0.009

-0.004

0.007

0.029

0.057

0.000

0.021

0.022

0.015

0.021

0.012

0.035

-0.003

-0.006

0.012

0.007

0.547

1.000

0.304

0.619

Revenue Expense

0.017

0.000

0.004

0.012

0.026

0.001

0.022

0.012

0.025

-0.007

0.017

0.024

0.036

-0.006

-0.002

0.022

0.025

1.000

0.534

0.361

0.584

Sheet

Balance

0.047

-0.232

-0.059

0.061

-0.018

-0.375

0.617

0.215

-0.543

-0.285

0.024

0.526

0.435

-0.235

-0.022

0.664

1.000

0.038

0.014

0.054

0.056

GDP

0.039

0.096

-0.037

0.008

0.001

-0.086

0.118

-0.152

-0.116

-0.195

-0.201

0.027

-0.043

0.022

-0.193

1.000

0.729

0.045

0.028

0.052

0.054

Peak

-0.013

-0.124

-0.020

0.039

-0.012

-0.203

0.215

0.144

-0.149

-0.144

0.045

0.387

0.196

-0.001

1.000

-0.185

-0.020

-0.003

-0.008

-0.019

-0.017

Trough

-0.023

-0.343

0.025

-0.078

0.039

-0.102

0.040

-0.502

0.364

0.317

-0.541

-0.567

-0.512

1.000

-0.026

0.059

-0.247

-0.017

-0.012

-0.051

-0.038

0.056

0.058

-0.041

0.052

-0.018

0.204

0.506

0.867

-0.380

-0.061

0.297

0.618

1.000

-0.574

0.180

0.013

0.442

0.042

0.038

0.092

0.083

Surprise Volatility

Risk

0.033

0.021

-0.049

0.116

-0.051

-0.090

0.320

0.447

-0.602

-0.535

0.602

1.000

0.619

-0.598

0.385

0.093

0.534

0.028

0.010

0.006

0.007

Premium

0.021

0.519

-0.031

0.095

-0.054

0.210

-0.341

0.308

-0.263

-0.247

1.000

0.599

0.298

-0.544

0.045

-0.190

0.029

0.017

0.014

0.035

0.032

SEC

-0.024

-0.192

0.036

-0.069

0.033

0.103

0.014

-0.064

0.453

1.000

-0.234

-0.710

-0.193

0.224

-0.239

-0.055

-0.372

-0.026

0.005

-0.010

-0.021

Detect

-0.048

0.295

0.057

-0.040

0.032

0.422

-0.295

-0.452

1.000

0.392

-0.255

-0.642

-0.454

0.307

-0.184

-0.085

-0.576

0.018

0.020

0.010

0.006

IPO

0.056

0.201

-0.046

0.014

-0.014

0.180

0.194

1.000

-0.430

0.022

0.307

0.457

0.919

-0.475

0.159

-0.174

0.224

0.020

0.028

-0.029

-0.057

CA

0.014

-0.684

-0.017

0.017

0.003

-0.389

1.000

0.331

-0.548

-0.390

-0.337

0.354

0.496

-0.101

0.186

0.271

0.719

0.021

-0.003

-0.025

-0.030

MAFE

0.035

0.653

0.025

-0.008

0.007

1.000

-0.487

0.191

0.427

0.100

0.209

-0.098

0.200

-0.121

-0.207

-0.064

-0.380

0.040

0.057

0.469

0.063

PE

0.033

-0.013

0.040

-0.029

1.000

0.001

-0.004

-0.019

0.029

0.029

-0.048

-0.046

-0.025

0.033

-0.008

0.001

-0.020

0.026

0.032

0.013

0.031

Capital

This table shows univariate correlations (Spearman above the diagonal and Pearson below the diagonal). Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

1.000

Fraud

Fraud

Table 3
Correlation Matrix

0.191

0.029

0.071

1.000

-0.027

-0.009

0.018

0.014

-0.043

-0.092

0.095

0.116

0.052

-0.082

0.039

0.018

0.062

0.014

0.009

0.025

0.029

Return

0.030

-0.013

1.000

0.073

0.031

0.025

-0.043

-0.044

0.056

0.026

-0.027

-0.049

-0.048

0.014

-0.021

-0.035

-0.062

0.010

0.003

0.024

0.018

Level

Lag Ab PE - Firm

0.033

1.000

0.004

0.036

-0.012

0.775

-0.573

0.144

0.522

0.113

0.517

0.048

0.167

-0.270

-0.083

0.023

-0.257

0.001

0.025

0.076

0.067

PR

1.000

0.030

0.038

0.212

0.017

0.056

0.033

0.058

-0.046

-0.028

0.027

0.048

0.066

-0.006

-0.005

0.057

0.058

0.027

0.014

0.008

0.012

Wealth

Table 3 presents Spearman and Pearson correlations for variables I use in survival
analysis. Univariate correlations between accounting fraud, macroeconomic performance, and
the market incentive proxies are consistent with Hypotheses 1 and 2. Table 4 presents
descriptive statistics for the variables used in survival analysis. Approximately 3.5% of the
observations used in survival analysis are first year fraud firms. GDP can show negative values
because of the effect of time detrending. The value for the peak and trough indicators is the
percentage of years that meet the inclusion criteria. The firm-level variables (i.e., lagged
abnormal returns, PE firm level, and wealth) are winsorized at the 1 percent level to reduce
the influence of outliers. Appendix Table 2 presents descriptive statistics for the firm-level
variables split between fraud and non-fraud firms. Fraud firms are more likely to raise external
financing and have much higher lagged abnormal returns on average (though the median
values are similar). Fraud and non-fraud firms have similar PE ratios and the delta for fraud
firm CEOs is a little more than twice as large as it is for non-fraud firm CEOs.

Tables 5A and 5B report results supporting Hypotheses 1A and 1B. GDP, GDP Change,
and economic peaks are significant and positively related to the hazard rate. I find that more
managers start to commit accounting fraud in periods of strong aggregate performance and in
the two years leading up to an economic peak. In Table 5A, the 1.295 hazard rate on GDP
means that for a $100 billion increase in GDP there is a corresponding 29.5% increase in
accounting fraud. A one standard deviation increase in GDP leads to approximately an 80%
increase in observed accounting fraud. Over my sample period, the average year has 31 new

34

Table 4
Descriptive Statistics
Variable

Mean

Std. Dev.

25th

Median

75th

Fraud

3.54%

Revenue

2.27%

Expense

1.41%

Balance Sheet

1.24%

GDP

1.44

138.78

-120.61

-32.29

103.77

Peak

27.00%

Trough

27.00%

Surprise

36.84

18.19

24.77

38.94

47.09

Volatility

4.50%

2.00%

3.32%

4.21%

4.89%

Risk Premium

2.06%

0.47%

1.70%

1.96%

2.21%

SEC

322

115

251

318

344

Detect

2.38

0.40

2.12

2.35

2.68

IPO

1039

484

582

1075

1492

CA

24.97%

6.00%

20.33%

25.26%

28.33%

MAFE

0.10

0.03

0.08

0.10

0.13

PE

11.89

2.79

9.82

12.69

14.30

PR

1.82

0.49

1.42

1.79

2.27

ERC

0.003

0.01

0.000

0.002

0.003

RRC

0.011

0.02

0.001

0.007

0.012

Capital

53.00%

Lag Ab Ret

8.00%

0.92

-35.00%

-5.00%

26.00%

PE - Firm Level

14.81

53.46

1.47

12.33

21.39

1002.00

3909

32.00

98

443

Wealth

This table provides descriptive statistics for variables used in hazard and logistic analysis. The sample period is 1980-2005.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

35

cases of accounting fraud. This one standard deviation increase in GDP increases the number of
fraud firms in the economy from 31 to 55. In addition, I find that the SEC variable is generally
negative and significant. This finding suggests that managers are less likely to commit
accounting fraud in periods wherein the SEC has more resources at its disposal. Detect is also
negative but only significantly so in one out of six models. In practical terms, wealth is not
related to the hazard rate. The economic effect is small; a base hazard rate of 1.000 indicates
that the variable has no effect on whether fraud occurs and the hazard rate for incentive
compensation always falls between 0.999 and 1.000 (the z-stat is between -0.01 and 0.00).

The hazard rate for the risk premium is negative in all models, significantly so in four of
them. The hazard rate for IPO is positive and significant in Table 5A but is negative (though
insignificant) in Table 5B. This switch, however, is not driven by a correlation between IPO and
compensation; what causes the switch is not clear, but in an economic sense, the hazard rate of
0.995 0.998 in Table 5B is not significant. The hazard rate on the risk premium indicates a
large effect on fraud, but when placed in context is not so large. In the GDP model of Table 5A,
a 1 unit (1 percent) increase in the risk premium is associated with a 48% reduction in
accounting fraud. But, the standard deviation of the risk premium is less than 0.5%. So, a two
standard deviation change in the risk premium is needed to observe the 48% reduction in fraud.
The relation between raising capital and accounting fraud is positive, as predicted by the extant
literature, but not significant. This lack of significance could be due to the downward bias of
coefficients that attends modeling rare events in non-linear models, as documented by King and

36

Table 5 A
Hazard Analysis
GDP
GDP

Change

Peak

1.295 **
(2.20)

GDP Change

1.538 **
(2.21)

Peak

1.340 ***
(3.48)

Trough

0.681 ***
(-3.06)

Surprise

Volatility

Risk Premium

1.013 **

1.005

1.012 ***

(2.59)

(0.91)

(3.02)

1.285 ***

1.255 ***

1.252 ***

(3.51)

(2.62)

(3.46)

0.516

0.351 **

(-1.38)
SEC

(-2.20)

0.999

0.998 **

(-1.57)
Detect

(-2.38)

0.539

0.285 **

(-1.16)
IPO

Capital

Lag Ab Return

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

(-2.42)

0.750
(-0.83)
0.998 ***
(-3.04)
0.598
(-1.20)

1.001 **

1.000

1.001 *

(2.01)

(0.49)

(1.67)

1.270

1.269

1.270

(1.37)

(1.36)

(1.37)

1.084 **
(2.21)

1.088 **
(2.25)

1.085 **
(2.34)

0.12
271
2987

0.14
271
2987

0.11
271
2987

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic and firm-level conditions
present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates. Standard
errors are clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to a different way of measuring aggregate performance. Z-stats
are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
GDP is gross domestic product in chained 2005 100's of billions of dollars, adjusted for inflation and detrended using the HodrickPrescot filter. GDP Change is the change in detrended GDP in 100s of billions of dollars. Peak is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the
year is in the 2 years prior to an NBER defined economic peak. Trough is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the year is in the 2 years
following an NBER defined trough. Surprise is the difference between actual GDP and forecasted GDP. Volatility is the standard
deviation of the monthly market return. Risk premium is the long term Baa corporate bond rate less the 10 year government treasury

37

Table 5A: Continued


rate. S EC is the S EC annual budget, expressed in millions of dollars. Detect is the average time to detection in years for accounting
frauds beginning in the current year. IPO is the number of IPOs in the last 3 years. Capital is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the firm
issued debt or stock in the current period. Lag Ab Return is the lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual market return.

Zeng [2001]. In economic terms, issuing capital is associated with approximately a 27% increase
in accounting fraud. Time variance in the relation is explored in Hypothesis 3. The relation
between lagged abnormal returns and accounting fraud is positive, consistent with Dechow et
al [2010], though it is statistically significant only in Table 5A. One explanation for this finding
is that the relation is not strong enough to be detected with the smaller number of fraud firm
observations included in the tests presented in Table 5B. The results indicate that every 1%
increase in lagged abnormal returns is associated with approximately an 8.5% increase in
probability of accounting fraud.

To mitigate the potential of downward bias of coefficients that typically attends models
of rare events, I perform my analysis using a subset of non-fraud firms. King and Zeng [2001]
provide a detailed discussion of the difficulty of modeling rare events.13 Given that fraud firms
represent less than 1 percent of the population in most periods, accounting fraud qualifies as a
rare event. Using a random subsample of observations drawn from the total population is one
technique for dealing with this issue, so I select 15% of Compustat firms during the sample
period.14 Firms are selected so that each separate year has 15% of Compustat firms for that year

13

To summarize, the difficulty arises for two reasons: (1) because the statistical properties of binary regression
models are not invariant to the (unconditional) mean of the dependent variable and (2) because the method of
computing probabilities of events in logistic analysis is suboptimal in finite samples of rare events data.
14

I conduct hazard analysis using random samples of 5%, 10%, and 15% of the Compustat population and find that
the magnitude and statistical significance of my results does not vary. Further, 25 random samples were
generated to insure that the results are not determined by the specific firms in any one random sample.

38

Table 5 B
Hazard Analysis: Compensation Sub-Sample
GDP
GDP

Change

Peak

1.611 ***
(2.96)

GDP Change

1.870 *
(1.75)

Peak

2.232 ***
(5.41)

Trough

0.125 **
(-2.46)

Surprise

0.997
(-0.27)

0.988
(-0.71)

1.007
(1.11)

Volatility

1.095
(0.56)

1.171
(1.00)

1.079
(0.95)

Risk Premium

0.108 **
(-2.22)

0.075 **
(-2.25)

0.197 ***
(-3.28)

SEC

0.996 *
(-1.91)

0.996 *
(-1.66)

0.992 ***
(-2.10)

Detect

0.199

0.099

0.194

(-1.56)

(-1.34)

(-0.99)

0.998
(-1.42)

0.997
(-1.19)

0.995
(-1.20)

Capital

1.577
(1.17)

1.567
(1.15)

1.567
(1.15)

Lag Ab Return

1.084
(0.36)

1.088
(0.37)

1.125
(0.55)

0.999
(-0.01)

1.000
(0.00)

0.999
(-0.01)

0.22
104
1046

0.12
104
1046

0.17
104
1046

IPO

Wealth

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic and firm-level conditions
present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates. Standard
errors are clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to a different way of measuring aggregate performance. Z-stats
are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
GDP is gross domestic product in chained 2005 100's of billions of dollars, adjusted for inflation and detrended using the HodrickPrescot filter. GDP Change is the change in detrended GDP in 100s of billions of dollars. Peak is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the
year is in the 2 years prior to an NBER defined economic peak. Trough is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the year is in the 2 years
following an NBER defined trough. Surprise is the difference between actual GDP and forecasted GDP. Volatility is the standard
deviation of the monthly market return. Risk premium is the long term Baa corporate bond rate less the 10 year government treasury
rate. SEC is the SEC annual budget, expressed in millions of dollars. Detect is the average time to detection in years for accounting

39

Table 5B: Continued


frauds beginning in the current year. IPO is the number of IPOs in the last 3 years. Capital is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the firm
issued debt or stock in the current period. Lag Ab Return is the lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual market return.
Wealth is the delta of all shares held by the CEO, calculated using the Core & Guay methodology.

included in the analysis. To be included in the analysis, firms must have two years of data.15
Because incentive compensation data is only available for a subset of firms and only from 1992
onward, I report my results in two separate tables. The hazard models presented in Table 5B
include 104 fraud firms and 1046 non-fraud firms. In both tables, standard errors are clustered
by firm and by year.

I test Hypothesis 2 using survival analysis. Here, I extend the Cox proportional hazards
model I estimate to test Hypothesis 1 to include three proxies for market wide incentives. The
market-incentive proxies measure the average correlation between firm returns and the market
return, the average median absolute forecast error for the period, and the average market priceearnings ratio for the period. Because these proxies exhibit strong correlations with one
another, I test each proxy separately. Additionally, I estimate an index from a principal
components analysis to test whether the market incentive proxies have incremental explanatory
power16.

15

Two years of data is required to calculate lagged abnormal returns for the fraud year. My results are not
sensitive to this distinction. I repeat my analysis requiring three years of data and imposing no restriction on the
data with similar results in terms of magnitude and statistical significance. Requiring more than two years of data
severely reduces the size of my sample.
16

Principal components analysis can produce unreliable results when done on a small number of observations.
Given that the market-incentive proxies have only 26 independent values, this is a legitimate concern in my
analysis.

40

How much weight the market places on idiosyncratic news influences the benefit of
committing accounting fraud. Ang and Chen [2002] show that the correlation between firm
returns and the market return is relatively high during recessions and relatively low during
booms. During recessions, price is determined more so by news about markets and industries
with firm-level news being of relatively low importance. During booms, on the other hand, the
market places greater weight on idiosyncratic news when setting price. In periods wherein firm
news is more important, managers have more to gain from fraudulently inflating earnings. In
periods wherein strong inferences about individual performance are made from reported
earnings, managers may face a greater risk of losing their job if they report performance below
their firms expectations.

Earnings news is not highly informative without context. Whether it is explicitly written
into compensation contracts or used as a general evaluation metric, firm performance is
measured against that of other firms in the economy. A firm that misses its forecast is evaluated
differently in periods wherein many firms miss their forecasts than in periods wherein few
firms miss their forecasts. Uncertainty about performance can also affect incentives to commit
accounting fraud. In periods characterized by high uncertainty and low forecast accuracy, both
the ex ante forecast and whether or not that forecast is met are likely to have a lessened effect on
price. There are many explanations for high uncertainty about performance and low forecast
accuracy and many of these also explain poor performance. The less certain the market is when
forming expectations, the less likely it is to be surprised when a manager falls short. As such,

41

managers have weaker incentives to commit accounting fraud when predicting performance is
difficult.

The sensitivity of price to news can greatly influence the incentives to commit
accounting fraud. In periods wherein earnings has a large effect on price, managers will have
stronger incentives to avoid reporting poor performance. Dechow et al [2010], note that class
action lawsuits are often filed against firms when their stock prices suffer large decreases.
Managers have strong incentives to avoid these lawsuits and the large decreases in their firms
stock price that precede them. Additionally, the effect of fraudulently inflating earnings on a
managers wealth will be higher in periods wherein these inflated earnings have the largest
effect on price.

The results I obtain for Hypothesis 2, presented in Tables 6A and 6B, are strong for all
three proxies for market wide incentives. The hazard rates for covariance asymmetry (CA),
median absolute forecast error (MAFE), and price-earnings ratio (PE) are all significant in the
predicted directions at the 5 percent level in every estimation. The principal components index
is only significant at the 10 percent level. Further, the r-squared value for this model is smaller
than it is for other models17. This is odd, as the PCI should not have less explanatory power
than the individual components. This could be due to the potential unreliability of principal
components analysis when the index is determined by a small number of independent
observations. The economic significance associated with a 1 unit change in the PCI is rather

17

Rouam, Moreau, and Broet [2011] provide one technique for estimating an r-squared value in hazards models.

42

Table 6 A
Hazard Analysis: Market Incentive Proxies
CA
GDP

CA

1.172 **
(2.62)

MAFE
1.567 ***
(4.39)

PE
1.814 ***
(3.99)

PCI
1.498 ***
(3.84)

0.918 ***
(-2.83)

MAFE

0.897 ***
(-2.69)

PE

1.162 **
(2.38)

PCI

0.855 *
(-1.85)

Surprise

1.014 ***
(3.85)

1.012 ***
(2.75)

1.009 *
(1.93)

1.008 *
(1.72)

Volatility

1.771 ***
(4.82)

1.381 ***
(3.47)

1.315 ***
(3.10)

1.263 ***
(2.82)

Risk Premium

0.461 **
(-2.11)

0.359 **
(-2.24)

0.499 *
(-1.75)

0.578
(-1.48)

SEC

0.999
(-1.41)

0.997 ***
(-3.46)

0.999
(-0.56)

0.999
(-1.01)

Detect

0.543
(-1.26)

0.410
(-1.42)

0.527
(-1.10)

0.495
(-1.28)

IPO

1.001
(0.89)

1.001
(1.61)

1.002 ***
(3.05)

1.001 **
(2.48)

Capital

1.269
(1.37)

1.268
(1.36)

1.265
(1.33)

1.272
(1.38)

Lag Ab Return

1.083 **
(2.34)

1.085 **
(2.25)

1.084 **
(2.23)

1.085 **
(2.28)

PE - Firm Level

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

1.001
(0.48)
0.16
271
2987

0.14
271
2987

0.15
271
2987

0.13
271
2987

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic, market incentive, and firmlevel conditions present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates.
Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to the different market incentive proxy tested. Z-stats
are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
GDP is gross domestic product in chained 2005 100's of billions of dollars, adjusted for inflation and detrended using the Hodrick-

43

Table 6A: Continued


Prescot filter. CA is the average correlation between monthly firm returns and the monthly equal weighted market return. MAFE is the
average absolute median forecast error for the period. PE is the average price-earnings ratio for the period. PCI is a principal
components index of CA, MAFE, and PE. S urprise is the difference between actual GDP and forecasted GDP. Volatility is the standard
deviation of the monthly market return. Risk premium is the long term Baa corporate bond rate less the 10 year government treasury
rate. S EC is the S EC annual budget, expressed in millions of dollars. Detect is the average time to detection in years for accounting
frauds beginning in the current year. IPO is the number of IPOs in the previous 3 years. Capital is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the
firm issued debt or stock in the current period. Lag Ab Return is the lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual market return.
PE - Firm Level is the PE ratio for individual firms.

large though. A one standard deviation change in the PCI reduces the hazard rate to 0.73.
Regardless, the analysis does not show that the market incentive proxies have much
incremental explanatory power relative to one another. The results for Hypothesis 2 suggest
that managers are more willing to commit accounting fraud when share price is determined
more by firm-level news than by market news. The economic effect is large; for example,
moving from the median to the 75th percentile (a 3% movement) is associated with a 24.6%
decrease in observed accounting fraud. Ceteris paribus it is reasonable to expect that as the
market places more weight on managerial performance, more managers will commit
accounting fraud.

The results also suggest that managers are more likely to commit accounting fraud in
periods wherein earnings is easier to predict. A one standard deviation increase in MAFE (3
units) is associated with a 30.9% decrease in observed accounting fraud. Several interpretations
are consistent with this result: on the one hand, it could be that managers are penalized more
severely for falling short in periods wherein earnings are easier to predict; on the other, it could
be that, in periods wherein earnings are more difficult to predict, managers have several
plausible explanations for their failure to meet performance expectations. It could also be that

44

managers feel more comfortable borrowing from the future in periods wherein performance is
easier to predict.

Finally, I find that more managers start to commit accounting fraud in periods of high
price sensitivity to short-term earnings news. This finding is consistent with the predictions
made in Benmelech et al [2010]. Both the penalty for reporting poor performance and the
benefit of exceeding expectation are generally higher when news has a stronger effect on price.18
I include in this model the PE ratios of individual firms to discern whether increases in the
individual fraud firms PE ratios drive the significance of the aggregate PE ratio19. Ultimately, I
find that the firm-level PE ratio is insignificant, while the aggregate PE ratio is positive and
significant. The economic effect is large. A one standard deviation increase in PE ($2.80) is
associated with a 45.4% increase in observed accounting fraud. This finding suggests that what
creates the strongest incentives for managers to misreport is economy wide price sensitivity to
news. Incentives for managers to commit fraud are high when all firms in the economy have
high expectations built into their share price.

Interpreting the economic significance of the results across the A and B tables requires
some adjustments. The data in the B tables is only from 1992 onwards so the mean and

18

While price-earnings ratios capture the markets sensitivity to earnings news, they also capture the discount rate
the market applies to future cash flows. Including the market risk premium should control for the discount rate
and allow the PE ratio to be interpreted as a measure of the sensitivity of price to earnings news.
19

I do not include firm level measures for CA or MAFE. I cannot calculate the correlation between 1 firms annual
return and the market return this is just a correlation between two numbers. The correlation between monthly
returns would not likely provide much more insight. The firm-level MAFE would not provide much insight into the
firms information environment, it would just show whether one firm hit its forecast or not.

45

Table 6 B
Hazard Analysis: Compensation Sub-Sample
CA
GDP

CA

MAFE

1.376
(1.33)

4.384 ***
(5.76)

PE
6.836 ***
(5.97)

0.829 ***
(-2.89)

MAFE

0.662 **
(-2.19)

PE

1.951 **
(2.55)

Surprise

1.016
(1.40)

Volatility

2.706 ***
(2.91)

0.999
(-0.04)
1.332 **
(2.03)

0.978
(-1.09)
1.268 ***
(3.42)

Risk Premium

0.117 **
(-2.25)

0.024 *
(-1.89)

SEC

0.998
(-1.04)

0.988 **
(-2.25)

Detect

0.341
(-0.96)

0.116
(-1.32)

0.280
(-0.68)

IPO

0.998 *
(-1.90)

0.995
(-1.48)

1.000
(0.12)

Capital

1.581
(1.19)

1.579
(1.19)

1.577
(1.57)

Lag Ab Return

1.074
(0.56)

1.085
(0.64)

1.109
(0.48)

PE - Firm Level

Wealth

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

0.180 ***
(-3.48)
1.000
(0.11)

1.001
(0.69)
0.991
(-0.48)

0.991
(-0.50)

0.998
(-0.06)

0.26
104
1046

0.20
104
1046

0.28
104
1046

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic, market incentive, and firmlevel conditions present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates.
Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to the different market incentive proxy tested. Z-stats
are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
GDP is gross domestic product in chained 2005 100's of billions of dollars, adjusted for inflation and detrended using the Hodrick-

46

Table 6B: Continued


Prescot filter. CA is the average correlation between monthly firm returns and the monthly equal weighted market return. MAFE is the
average absolute median forecast error for the period. PE is the average price-earnings ratio for the period. PCI is a principal
components index of CA, MAFE, and PE. S urprise is the difference between actual GDP and forecasted GDP. Volatility is the standard
deviation of the monthly market return. Risk premium is the long term Baa corporate bond rate less the 10 year government treasury
rate. S EC is the S EC annual budget, expressed in millions of dollars. Detect is the average time to detection in years for accounting
fraudsbeginning in the current year. IPO is the number of IPOs in the previous 3 years. Capital is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the
firm issued debt or stock in the current period. Lag Ab Return is the lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual market return.
PE - Firm Level is the PE ratio for individual firms. Wealth is the delta of all shares held by the CEO, calculated using the Core & Guay
methodology.

standard deviations of the macro variables are different here. For example, in Table 6B, moving
from the median to the 75th percentile for the CA variable is associated with a 61% decrease in
the number of fraud firms, compared to a 25% decrease in Table 6A. One reason for the
difference is that moving from the median to the 75th percentile is a 3.6 unit increase in Table 6B
instead of a 3 unit increase. Other reasons are the different years in the sample and the smaller
number of observations in the sample, leading to certain years having more influence on the
results. Results for volatility, the risk premium, the SEC budget, detection time, IPO, capital,
and lagged abnormal returns are similar in direction and significance to those reported in
Tables 5A and 5B. Results for GDP Surprise are not consistent within or across the B tables.

Macroeconomic variables are often correlated with multiple forces. Though the market
wide incentive proxies likely capture market wide incentives, they may also be correlated with
other factors that could influence a managers decision to commit accounting fraud. Two
related explanations for time-variance in accounting fraud are changes in the detection
environment and changes in the litigation environment. Though it is not clear in what direction
either would be correlated with my sample of accounting fraud, it is possible that they affect a
managers decision to commit fraud in the same way I argue market wide incentives do. In
47

periods wherein monitors exert high effort, it is reasonable to assume that a higher proportion
of accounting fraud will be detected. If this is true and if, in addition, periods wherein monitors
exert high effort are correlated with periods of strong aggregate performance, then an increase
in the number of detected cases of accounting fraud in these periods could result from an
increased detection rate and not from an increase in the number of managers reporting
fraudulently. While measuring effort empirically is difficult, most theoretical research predicts
that monitoring effort actually decreases during periods of strong aggregate performance. This
finding argues against the conclusion that increases in AAERs during periods of high
performance are caused by an increased detection rate of accounting fraud.

On the other hand, if monitors do in fact reduce their effort during good times, then one
could argue that their reduced effort increases the true number of fraud firms in the economy,
which in turn may explain part of the increase in detected cases of accounting fraud. Again, the
difficulty in measuring effort makes this hypothesis hard to test or refute. Dyck et.al. [2007]
find that whistleblowers detect more cases of accounting fraud than do other agents. Further,
they find that a large amount of accounting fraud is detected by agents who are not employed
as monitors; they note in particular that the media and analysts detect a reasonable number of
fraud cases. It is not clear whether the benefits a reporter stands to gain from breaking a big
story or the ethics and/or willingness of a lower level employee to speak up vary much over
time, or are correlated with market covariance asymmetry or price-earnings ratios.
Whistleblowers in particular do not monitor the firm per se and tend to uncover fraudulent
activity simply in the course of doing their job. If the effort levels of agents that detect the vast
48

majority of accounting fraud cases do not vary over time, then the detection environment is less
likely to be a concern in this setting.

The evidence suggests that the SEC budget effectively controls for changes in the
litigation environment. The relation between accounting fraud and the SEC budget is negative
and significant in most estimations, which is consistent with fewer managers committing
accounting fraud in periods wherein the SEC has more resources at its disposal. The SEC
budget should control for the SECs resources for detecting accounting fraud, but as mentioned
above, many other agents detect accounting fraud. The relation between accounting fraud and
average fraud detection time is also negative but rarely significant. This suggests that managers
are less likely to commit fraud when detection effort is low. This result is plausible if it is due to
higher detection rates when monitoring effort is higher. That said, these variables are difficult
to interpret because it is not clear whether managers are aware of changes to the SECs
resources or to fraud detection times and respond accordingly, or if changes to these variables
are responses that come after a large increase in aggregate fraudulent reporting. The political
environment could influence both the SECs litigation practices and the effort exerted by certain
monitors. Appendix Table 3 re-estimates that hazards models presented in Table 6A but
includes SEC chairperson fixed effects. The SEC chairperson is appointed by the president and
often only serves for a few years. Some chairpersons might be much more litigation prone than
others and may have been appointed with an agenda in mind. This proxy cannot control for all
the changes in the political environment, but over my sample period there are seven
presidential elections and seven different SEC chairpersons; the chairperson does change with
49

political regimes and following elections. The results in Appendix Table 3 are consistent in
direction and magnitude with those presented in Table 6A except for that GDP Surprise is now
never significant, and IPO has switched from positive to negative (though not significantly so).
The explanatory power of the models goes up a great deal, from around 15% to 22%.

To reduce the likelihood that the statistical significance of the proxies for market wide
incentives is due to correlated omitted variables, I recalculate each of these proxies at the
industry level using the Fama-French 5 and 12 industry definitions and re-estimate the hazards
models. Doing so increases the cross-sectional variation in the proxies which should in and of
itself increase the reliability of the results. Assuming the cross-sectional variation reduces the
likelihood that the market incentive proxies also serve as proxies for changes in either the
detection or litigation environments, then these recalculations provide more support for
Hypothesis 2. As presented in Appendix Table 4, the results do support Hypothesis 2. Here, I
substitute the market incentive proxies for two variables: the proxy calculated for the industry
the firm is in, and the proxy calculated for the rest of the firms in the market. Both measures are
used so that the results can be attributed to industry variance in the measure and not simply
because most industries have to be correlated with the market20. The industry-level proxies for
market wide incentives are statistically significant in the predicted directions in five out of six
models. To conclude that these results are driven by changes in detection or litigation, the effort
to detect accounting fraud or the propensity to litigate for each separate industry would need to

20

Because the industry and market measures are correlated with one another I also estimate the models using
only the industry incentive proxies with no change in the results.

50

change with the proxies for market incentives measured at the industry level when controlling
for changes in the rest of the market. At the very least, such a finding is far less plausible than
when the proxies are measured at the economy level. The standard errors in Appendix Table 4
are clustered by industry and by year. The control variables exhibit behavior similar to that
reported in Table 6A.

I use logistic regressions to test Hypotheses 3A and 3B, namely, that the relations
between accounting fraud and incentive compensation and accounting fraud and raising
capital, respectively, are stronger in periods wherein price is highly sensitive to news. The
evidence presented in Table 7 supports Hypothesis 3A. In general, the relation between CEO
delta and the propensity to observe new cases of accounting fraud is positive but not significant
(z-stat of 0.41). However, the interaction of CEO delta and PE ratio is positive and significant at
the 10 percent level. These findings are consistent with those of Benmelech et al [2010] and
support the conclusion that a CEOs wealth positively influences his decision to commit
accounting fraud in periods wherein share price, and by extension wealth, is highly sensitive to
short-term earnings news. Interpreting the magnitude of the interaction coefficient of two
continuous variables in a logistic regression is not easy, but there is reason not to dismiss the
0.0054 coefficient on the interaction as economically insignificant. The aggregate PE ratio in this
sample is around 13 and the interaction coefficient is approximately 1/13th the size of the
coefficient on wealth. Further, PE has a standard deviation of approximately 3 units and wealth

51

Table 7
Logistic Regressions: Interactions
Wealth
PE

0.488 *
(1.67)

Wealth

0.071
(0.41)

Capital
0.080
(1.02)

Capital

0.091
(0.16)

Interaction

0.005 *
(1.86)

0.021 *
(1.79)

GDP

1.448 ***
(2.89)

0.382 **
(2.40)

Surprise

-0.024
(-1.10)

0.017 **
(2.41)

Volatility

0.228
(1.06)

0.316 ***
(4.45)

Risk Premium
SEC

-0.685
(-0.31)

-0.450
(-0.94)

0.004
(1.00)

0.004 ***
(3.32)

-1.044
(-0.57)

-1.249 ***
(-2.76)

IPO

0.001
(0.05)

0.001 ***
(3.66)

Capital

0.631 **
(2.05)

Detect

Lag Ab Return

-0.094
(-0.67)

0.072 *
(1.66)

PE - Firm Level

-0.001
(-0.05)

0.002
(1.41)

Constant

-8.737
(-0.78)

-5.163 ***
(-2.82)

Pseudo R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

8.40%
104
1046

5.20%
271
2987

This table shows results from logistic regressions testing the interaction between price sensitivity to news (measured using PE ratios)
and various potential firm-level determinants of accounting fraud. Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm and the
interaction has been adjusted using the Norton, Wang, and Ai correction technique. Each column corresponds to the specific interaction
tested. Z-stats are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.

52

Table 7: Continued
PE is the average price-earnings ratio for the period. Wealth is the delta for all CEO shares calculated using the Core & Guay
methodology. Capital is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the firm issued debt or stock in the current period. The interaction is the PE
ratio multiplied by the variable listed beneath it in each model. GDP is gross domestic product in chained 2005 100's of billions of
dollars, adjusted for inflation and detrended using the Hodrick-Prescot filter. S urprise is the difference between actual GDP and
forecasted GDP. Volatility is the standard deviation of the monthly market return. Risk premium is the long term Baa corporate bond
rate less the 10 year government treasury rate. S EC is the S EC annual budget, expressed in millions of dollars. Detect is the average
time to detection in years for accounting frauds beginning in the current year. IPO is the number of IPOs in the previous 3 years. Lag
Ab Return is the lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual market return. PE - Firm Level is the PE ratio for individual firms.

a standard deviation of 4 units. A 1 unit change in the interaction term likely represents a
rather small change, so a small coefficient is not surprising.

The evidence presented in Table 7 also supports Hypothesis 3B. The relation between
raising capital and accounting fraud is positive but not significant; the coefficient on the
interaction of raising capital and price sensitivity to news is positive and significant at the 10
percent level. This finding indicates that incentives to commit accounting fraud arising from a
dependency on external financing are only strong enough to lead to fraud in periods of high
price sensitivity to news. The effect of price sensitivity to news can be determined for firms that
do and do not issue capital in this model. The interaction coefficient (a log odds ratio) implies
that the relation of PE to accounting fraud is approximately 2.3% greater for firms that raise
external financing. In this model, the base effect of PE is approximately 8.5%, so raising capital
increases the effect of PE on observed accounting fraud by 27%. This finding also might explain
the inconsistent results found in the literature when studying this question. The standard errors
for the logistic regressions presented in Table 7 are adjusted using the Norton, Wang, and Ai
[2004] correction technique.

The results presented in Table 7 serve two purposes. First, they show the conditions
present when the incentives created by CEO compensation and a firms need to raise external
53

capital are strong enough to prompt more managers to commit accounting fraud. This aspect of
the results supports recent research on these firm-level determinants and can explain why past
studies have often reported contradictory results. Second, they show two of the channels
through which market wide incentives in the form of price sensitivity to news can influence
managers.

I use survival analysis to test Hypothesis 4, that managers commit different types of
accounting fraud in response to different incentives. In this analysis, I group fraud into three
categories: revenue fraud, expense fraud, and balance sheet fraud. I perform the analysis in two
ways: allowing overlap and disallowing overlap. In the analysis allowing overlap a manager
who commits multiple types of accounting fraud is included in each fraud type model. This
allows me to keep as many fraud firms in the sample as possible but could introduce noise into
the analysis. A manager who commits multiple types of accounting fraud is less likely to be
influenced by incentives from one source alone. In the analysis disallowing overlap firms are
only included when the AAER notes that the primary motivation was limited to one type of
accounting fraud as defined above. This allows for better identification but reduces the sample
size.

I have to rely on the information in the AAERs to determine the type of manipulation
and the motivation, particularly with regards to balance sheet fraud. Every entry (or non entry)
will eventually affect the balance sheet, if only through retained earnings, and could thusly be
considered balance sheet fraud. I categorize a fraud as a balance sheet fraud only where there is
evidence that a major part of the motivation was to strengthen the balance sheet. For example,
54

executives at PowerLinx, Inc were indicted for accounting fraud related to improperly
recognizing consignment sales as revenue. In this case, the balance sheet was fraudulently
represented because receivables were overstated and inventory was understated, and
eventually retained earnings might be overstated depending on what happens with the
consigned goods. Nevertheless, I treat this just as revenue fraud because the primary
motivation of PowerLinxs executives was to overstate revenues and because the effect of the
fraud on net assets is driven through the effect of the fraud on revenues. Conversely,
sometimes the primary motivation for fraud is to strengthen the balance sheet but there is a
residual effect on the income statement. A number of executives have been indicted for
improperly removing debt from the balance sheet. While it is likely that in some cases the
correct amount of interest expense was not recognized, the primary motivation was to remove
debt to improve the balance sheet and the amount by which expenses are understated is usually
immaterial. I treat such a fraud as a balance sheet fraud only.

Table 8 presents results consistent with Hypothesis 4A. In both sets of analysis revenue
fraud is significant and positively related to price revenues ratios, but the relation between
revenue fraud and price earnings ratios is not significant. Surprisingly, the statistical and
economic significance is higher for the analysis involving overlap. This could be because the
analysis disallowing overlap lacks power, as it has only slightly more than half of the fraud firm
observations the overlap analysis has. Price revenues ratios are not significantly related to
either expense or balance sheet fraud. I present coefficient estimates in Table 8 instead of
hazard rates because I test the difference between these coefficients in Table 9. Chi squared
55

Table 8
Hazard Analysis: Fraud Type
Revenue Fraud
With
Without
Overlap
Overlap

Expense Fraud
With
Without
Overlap
Overlap

Balance Sheet Fraud


With
Without
Overlap
Overlap

GDP

0.162 ***
(2.84)

0.234 **
(2.37)

0.188
(1.15)

0.202
(0.95)

0.090
(0.62)

-0.613 ***
(-3.03)

PE Ratio

0.150
(1.12)

0.153
(1.26)

0.153 *
(1.96)

0.088
(1.26)

0.029
(0.36)

-0.81 ***
(-4.38)

PR Ratio

0.133 **
(2.11)

0.089 *
(1.90)

0.034
(0.63)

0.039
(0.70)

0.008
(0.48)

0.007
(0.43)

Risk Premium

-0.424
(-0.48)

-0.790
(-0.59)

0.247
(0.43)

-1.078 *
(-1.81)

0.446 *
(1.94)

2.851 **
(2.11)

Surprise

0.005
(0.65)

0.010
(0.76)

0.009
(0.92)

0.010
(1.07)

0.029 **
(2.20)

0.086 ***
(3.44)

Volatility

0.308 *
(1.89)

0.278
(0.93)

0.118
(1.33)

0.116
(0.84)

0.312
(1.50)

-0.034
(-0.13)
0.002
(0.67)

SEC

-0.001
(-0.37)

0.000
(0.02)

-0.004 *
(-1.80)

-0.001
(-0.56)

-0.003
(-1.23)

Detect

-0.054
(-0.05)

-0.010
(-0.06)

0.392
(0.61)

-0.375
(-0.48)

-0.480
(-0.50)

-4.002 **
(-2.50)

IPO

0.002 ***
(3.01)

0.002
(1.51)

0.001
(1.50)

-0.001
(-0.92)

0.003 **
(2.36)

0.004 **
(2.08)

Capital

0.084
(0.50)

0.042
(0.18)

0.428
(1.44)

0.252
(0.52)

0.337 *
(1.69)

0.520
(0.86)

Lag Ab Return

0.062 *
(1.79)

0.080 *
(1.83)

0.073
(1.34)

0.133 *
(1.96)

0.057
(0.89)

0.144
(1.19)

PE - Firm Level

0.002 **
(2.21)

0.002
(1.22)

0.000
(0.04)

-0.003
(-0.55)

0.001
(0.80)

0.24
81
3177

0.18
92
3166

0.21
30
3228

0.30
68
3190

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-fraud Firms

0.23
155
3103

-0.008 ***
(-3.26)
0.31
27
3231

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the relation between type of accounting fraud
and price sensitivity to that type of news. The table presents coefficient estimates. The revenue columns represent results for revenue
fraud, expense for expense fraud, and balance sheet for balance sheet fraud. The with overlap columns include all fraud firms of that
type. The without overlap columns include fraud firms that only committed that type of fraud. Standard errors are clustered annually
and by firm. Z-stats are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
GDP is gross domestic product in chained 2005 100's of billions of dollars, adjusted for inflation and detrended using the HodrickPrescot filter. PE ratio is the average price-earnings ratio for the period. PR ratio is the average price-revenue ratio for the period. Risk
premium is the long term corporate bond interest rate less less the 10 year government treasury rate. Surprise is the difference
between actual GDP and forecasted GDP. Volatility is the standard deviation of the monthly market return. SEC is the SEC annual
budget, expressed in millions of dollars. Detect is the average time to detection in years for accounting frauds beginning in the current

56

Table 8: Continued
year. IPO is the number of IPOS in the previous 3 years. Capital is an indicator variable equal to 1 if the firm issued debt or equity in
the current period. Lag Ab Return is the lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual market return. PE - Firm Level is the PE
ratio for individual firms.

tests show that the coefficient on price revenue ratios for the revenue fraud models is
significantly larger than the coefficient on price revenue ratios for either of the expense or
balance sheet fraud models at the 10 percent level or better.

Table 8 also presents results consistent with Hypothesis 4B. Both sets of analysis
document a positive and significant relation between balance sheet fraud and the default risk
premium. However, the results for Hypothesis 4B are stronger in the analysis without overlap.
It appears as though the smaller sample size does not present power issues for this analysis.
The risk premium is not significantly related to revenue or expense fraud, except in one case,
where it is negatively related to expense fraud. Chi squared tests reported in Table 9 show that

Table 9
Chi Squared Tests
Price - Re ve nue Te sts

Chi Square d Value


P Value

Re ve nue and Expe nse Frauds

Re ve nue and Balance She e t Frauds

2.97

4.43

0.0847

0.0352
Risk Pre mium Te sts

Balance She e t and Re ve nue Frauds


Chi Square d Value
P Value

Balance She e t and Expe nse Frauds

5.95

9.17

0.0147

0.0025

This table presents results from Chi-squared tests testing the difference between coefficients across two fraud type models. Coefficients
tested are those for Price-Revenue Ratio and Risk Premium from the revenue, expense, and balance sheet fraud type models estimated
in Table 8.

57

the coefficient on the risk premium for the balance sheet fraud model is significantly larger than
the coefficient on the risk premium for either of the revenue or expense fraud models at the 5
percent level or better.

Overall, the results suggest that the type of fraud committed is driven by incentives to
improve performance along that specific dimension. Just as the total strength of incentives
managers have to misreport can vary over time, so too can the source of those incentives.
Further, these results suggest that studying the relation between all forms of accounting fraud
and market or firm-level determinants is not always the appropriate research design. To
properly test certain relations, the researcher may need to separate accounting fraud into
subgroups. It is possible that even my earlier analysis which finds significant relations between
accounting fraud and market-wide incentives may sacrifice the level of understanding we can
gain from them. Table 3 reports that revenue fraud is negatively correlated with covariance
asymmetry (-0.05), whereas expense fraud (0.02) and balance sheet fraud (0.01) are not. The
significant relation between Fraud and CA appears entirely driven by the relation between
Revenue and CA.

6. Robustness Checks

My robustness tests are primarily intended to show that my results are not sensitive to
variable choice or measurement. Results are presented in the appendix tables, many of which
have already been discussed. Prior research finds some evidence that accounting fraud is
positively related to the need to raise external financing, lagged abnormal returns, and CEO
58

incentive compensation. I also find some evidence of these relations, but correlations between
these firm-level variables and the macro variables included in my models could influence the
direction or strength of the relations. In Appendix Table 5 I estimate a hazards model including
only firm-level variables. The results are similar to those reported in previous tables. The
association between external financing and fraud is positive, and is significant in the
compensation sub-sample. Lagged abnormal returns are positively associated with fraud; the
result is significant in the full sample. The relation between fraud and both firm-level PE ratios
and CEO delta is positive, but never close to significant statistically or economically. The
inclusion of macro variables in the survival analysis does not influence the direction or
significance of potential firm-level determinants of accounting fraud.

To reduce concerns that results for Hypothesis 2 are driven by how the market incentive
proxies are measured, I calculate each proxy in a different way and re-estimate the hazards
models presented in Table 6A. I calculate the relative weight markets give firm-level versus
market news by taking the r-squared value from the following regression:

firm _ return market _ return for each year. This value should be a close proxy for the
correlation between firm returns and the market return. I choose to present main results using
CA because the literature on covariance asymmetry between firm returns and the market return
generally refers to the underlying construct as the correlation between the two.

I use the percentage of firms that fail to meet their consensus median analyst forecast as
another measure of the information environment and the predictability of earnings. This proxy
captures how often firms report earnings below their forecast, rather than capturing the
59

magnitude of forecast errors. I do not believe this proxy captures the underlying construct I am
trying to measure as well as the MAFE does. The environment where X number of firms report
below their forecast by $0.01 is different from the environment where X firms report below their
forecast by $0.50. But, this variable can provide insight regarding the tradeoff between the
number of managers that have some positive incentive to commit accounting fraud and the
strength of the incentive. Taken to the extremes, if all firms fail to meet their earnings forecast,
then many managers have a positive incentive to inflate earnings, but the incentive is relatively
weak. Given how risky it is to commit accounting fraud and how rarely it occurs, it is
reasonable that the managers incentives have to be strong before taking such a risk. At the
other extreme, if all firms but one beat their forecast, the manager of the one firm that
performed poorly likely has very strong incentives to inflate earnings. A significant result
could indicate that the number of firms performing poorly is a stronger determinant than the
magnitude of poor performance. An insignificant result could indicate that the above tradeoff
is not dominated by one side; fraud does not peak when many firms are performing poorly or
when few firms are performing poorly, but somewhere in the middle.

I use the annual average earnings response coefficient as a substitute for the average
market PE ratio to test market price sensitivity to news. I expect the two to behave similarly. I
use the PE ratio in my main tests for two reasons. First, if markets are efficient, then price
should incorporate all available information and update future expectations properly when
responding to earnings news. Second, the nature and strength of the ERC relationship is
debatable. The ERC represents the slope coefficient of a linear equation between unexpected
60

earnings and returns. However, it is not clear that this relation is linear. Further, unexpected
earnings is likely measured with noise. The results reported in Appendix Table 6 are generally
consistent with those reported in Table 6A. The hazard rates for R-squared and ERC are
significant in the predicted directions at the 1% level. The relation between accounting fraud
and forecast is negative, but not significant. This is not necessarily an unexpected result given
what this variable is capturing. These results support Hypothesis 2 and reduce concerns that
the results for CA and PE, presented in Table 6A, are driven by variable choice or measurement.

Wang and Winton [2010] find that firms in competitive industries have a strongly procyclical propensity to commit accounting fraud. This suggests that firms in different industries
have different sets of incentives to report fraudulently. Therefore, I re-estimate the industry
hazards models presented in Appendix Table 4 and report results for each separate industry21.
This analysis is only performed using the Fama-French 5 industry definitions because the
number of fraud firm observations becomes rather small in some industries when using 12
industries. In this analysis, I use only the given industrys value for CA, MAFE, and PE. The
results, presented in Appendix Table 7, are generally consistent with Hypothesis 2 and with
Wang and Winton [2010]. Panel A documents that CA is negative and significantly associated
with accounting fraud in four of five industries. A great deal of variance exists in both the
statistical and economic significance of the results, suggesting that the strength of different
incentives does vary across industry, but the relation between CA and fraud is consistent and

21

Because the models are estimated for each industry separately, I cluster standard errors by year and firm instead
of by year and industry.

61

strong. Industries 2 and 4 show results most different from previous analysis. Both GDP and
lagged abnormal returns have negative hazard rates (though not significant); those variables are
consistently positive in previous analysis. Both variables have positive hazard rates in the other
three industries, significantly so in two of them. Industries 2 and 4 have 32 and 25 fraud firms,
respectively, spread out over 20 years. This could explain why results look different in these
industries. Of course, it could also be that fraud is driven by additional incentives in these
industries as well. Further, results could be skewed for many of the macro proxies because they
should be measured at the industry level instead of economy level. This would be ideal, but
cannot be done for GDP, GDP surprise, or the SEC budget. Also, detect would become highly
volatile as in some industry years there are only one or two new cases of accounting fraud; this
would not likely be a good proxy when measured at the industry level. Looking at Panel B,
MAFE is negatively associated with accounting fraud in four industries, significantly so in three
of them. Here though, the relation is positive for industry 1. Other variables behave similarly
to Panel A. Finally, looking at Panel C, PE is positive and significantly related to accounting
fraud in three of five industries. The relation is negative in industries 2 and 5, though it is not
significant. Overall, most individual industries show results consistent with Hypothesis 2, and
the only statistically significant results are always consistent with H2. The variance across
panels could be due to the different incentive proxies capturing different incentives that could
vary in strength across industry. The small number of observations in some industries could
also influence the results. For example, in industry 2, where there are only 32 fraud

62

observations, if many of these frauds take place in two or three years, then the results are driven
by possibly one or two large values over the 25 year period.

Prior research on the link between CEO incentive compensation and accounting fraud
uses multiple measures for incentive compensation. I use the delta of all of the CEOs
stockholdings because my prediction is that the sensitivity of the CEOs net worth to changes in
price creates incentives strong enough that some managers commit fraud. However, it is
possible that the incentives are created simply by the firm providing a great deal of incentive
compensation to the CEO irrespective of the net worth effect. To investigate this possibility, I
re-estimate the logistic regression presented in Table 7 and substitute CEO delta with the
number of option and stock grants the CEO has received. The results are presented in
Appendix Table 8. The relation between CEO stock grants and accounting fraud is positive, but
not significant economically or statistically. The coefficient on the interaction is zero to the 4th
significant digit. The combined results indicate that the incentives to commit fraud are driven
by the net worth effect to the CEO and are only strong enough to lead to fraud in periods of
high price sensitivity, and thus high net worth sensitivity, to earnings news.

Dechow et al [2010] initially test three different measures for a need for external
financing. They find that an indicator variable for whether or not the firm raises external
financing in the fraud year has superior power to predict accounting fraud. Therefore, I use this
measure in my main analysis. But, to rule out that my results are driven by variable
measurement, I re-estimate the logistic regression presented in Table 7 using the other two
measures of external financing presented in Dechow et al [2010]. Xfin takes a value of 1 if cash
63

flow from operations less average capital expenditures over the last three years all scaled by
current assets is less than -0.5 and 0 otherwise. CFF is the level of external financing raised in
the current year scaled by average total assets. Results are presented in Appendix Table 8 and
are similar to those reported in Table 7. The coefficient on Xfin is positive and significant at the
5% level while the coefficient on CFF is positive and significant at the 10% level. The results
testing the relation between accounting fraud and the interaction between a need for external
financing and price sensitivity to news are robust to how a need for external financing is
measured.

As discussed above, I use average annual earnings response coefficients as a second


proxy for price sensitivity to earnings news in Appendix Table 6 and the results suggest the
ERC is a good substitute for the PE ratio. In Appendix Table 9 I report results from reestimating the fraud type hazards models substituting the ERC for the PE ratio. The results are
consistent with those reported in Table 8. The coefficient on the revenue response coefficient is
positive and significantly related to revenue fraud, but not significantly related to expense or
balance sheet fraud. This suggests that the results related to revenue and expense fraud are not
driven by using PE ratios as a proxy for price sensitivity to news. Though there is not much
reason to have predicted otherwise, the coefficient on the risk premium remains positive and
significantly related to balance sheet fraud and remains not significantly related to revenue or
expense fraud.

64

8. Conclusions

In this paper I find that more managers are observed committing accounting fraud
during periods of stronger aggregate performance and in the two years leading up to an
economic peak. Survival analysis suggests that proxies for market wide incentives that measure
the relative weight the market places on firm-level news, the ability of the market to predict
earnings, and the sensitivity of price to earnings news are all related to a given managers
decision to commit accounting fraud. These results support the conclusion that market wide
incentives influence whether a manager decides to commit accounting fraud. I find that the
delta of all CEO stockholdings and the decision to raise capital are both positively related to
accounting fraud in periods of high price sensitivity to earnings news. Finally, I find that only
revenue fraud is positively related to the price response to revenue news and that only balance
sheet fraud is positively related to the default risk premium.

65

References

Agrawal, A., Cooper, T., 2007. Insider Trading Before Accounting Scandals. Working Paper.
Altman, E., Saunders, A., 1998. Credit Risk Management: Developments Over the Last 20
Years. Journal of Banking and Finance: no.21, 1721-1742.
Ang, A., Chen, J., 2002. Asymmetric Correlations of Equity Portfolios. Journal of Financial
Economics: vol.63, 443-494.
Antle, R., Smith, A., 1986. An Empirical Investigation of the Relative Performance Evaluation of
Corporate Executives. Journal of Accounting Research: vol.24, no.1, 1-39.
Armstrong, C., Jagolinzer, A., Larcker, D., 2009. Chief Executive Officer Equity Incentives and
Accounting Irregularities. Journal of Accounting Research: vol.48, no.2, 225,271.
Baker, M., Ruback, R., Wurgler, J., 2007. Behavioral Corporate Finance: A Survey. Handbook of
Corporate Finance, no.1, chapter 4.
Baker, M., Wurgler, J., 2006. Investor Sentiment and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.
Journal of Finance: vol.61, no.4, 1645-1680.
Baker, M., Wurgler, J., 2007. Investor Sentiment in the Stock Market. Journal of Economic
Perspectives: vol.21, no.2, 129-151.
Ball, R., 2009. Market and Political/Regulatory Perspectives on the Recent Accounting Scandals.
Journal of Accounting Research, no.47.
Baxter, M., King, R., 1999. Measuring Business Cycles: Approximate Band-Pass Filters for
Economic Time Series. Review of Economics and Statistics, vol.81, 575-593.
Becker, G., 1968. Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach. Journal of Political
Economy: vol. 76, no.2, 169-217.
Beneish, M., 1999. Incentives and Penalties Related to Earnings Overstatements that Violate
GAAP. The Accounting Review, vol.74, no.4, 425-457.
Benmelech, E., Kandel, E., Veronesi, P., 2010. Stock-Based Compensation and CEO (Dis)
Incentives. Working paper.
Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., 1989. Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations.
American Economic Review: vol.79, no.1, 14-31.
Bonner, S., Palmrose, Z., Young, S., 1998. Fraud Type and Auditor Litigation: an Analysis of
SEC Accounting and Auditing Enforcement Releases. The Accounting Review: vol.73, no.4,
503-532.
66

Cao, J., Laksmana, I., 2010. The Effect of Capital Market Pressures on the Association between
R&D Spending and CEO Option Compensation. Review of Quantitative Finance and
Accounting: vol.34, no.2, 273-300.
Collard, D., 1996. Pigou and Modern Business Theory. The Economic Journal: no.106, 912-924.
Core, J., Guay, W., 2002. Estimating the Value of Employee Stock Option Portfolios and Their
Sensitivities to Price and Volatility. Journal of Accounting Research: vol. 40, no.3, 613-630.
Correia, M., 2010. Political Connections, SEC Enforcement, and Accounting Quality. Working
paper.
Cunningham, L., 2005. Finance Theory and Accounting Fraud: Fantastic Futures versus
Conservative Histories. Buffalo Law Review: 1-19.
Dechow, P., Ge, W., Larson, C., Sloan, R., 2010. Predicting Material Accounting Manipulations.
Contemporary Accounting Research, forthcoming.
Dechow, P., Sloan, R., Sweeney, A., 1996. Causes and Consequences of Earnings Manipulation:
An Analysis of Firms Subject to Enforcement Actions by the SEC. Contemporary Accounting
Research vol.13 1-36.
Dyck, A., Morse, A., Zingales, L., 2007. Who Blows the Whistle on Corporate Fraud? Working
paper.
Ebert, L., Gagne, M., 2007. A Monopoly Model of Accounting Fraud. Journal of Business &
Economics Research: vol.5, no.4, 11-18.
Erickson, M., Hanlon, M., Maydew, E., 2004. How much will Firms Pay for Earnings that do
not Exist? Evidence of Taxes Paid on Allegedly Fraudulent Earnings. The Accounting review:
vol.79, issue 2, 387-408.
Ertimur, Y., Livnat, J., Martikainen, M., 2003. Differential Market Reactions to Revenue and
Expense Surprises. Review of Accounting Studies: no.8, 185-211.
Fernandes, N., Guedes, J., 2009. Keeping up with the Joneses: a Model and a Test of Collective
Accounting Fraud. European Financial Management: vol.16, no.1, 72-93.
Galbraith, J. K., 1961. The Great Crash, 1929. London: Penguin Books.
Gerety, M., Lehn, K., 1997. The Causes and Consequences of Accounting Fraud. Managerial
and Decision Economics: no.18, 587-599.
Ghosh, A., Gu, Z., Jain, P., 2005. Sustained Earnings and Revenue Growth, Earnings Quality,
and Earnings Response Coefficients. Review of Accounting Studies: vol.10, no.1, 33-57.

67

Gibbons, R., Murphy, K., 1992. Optimal Incentive Contracts in the Presence of Career Concerns:
Theory and Evidence. Journal of Political Economy: vol.100, no.3, 468-505.
Graham, J., Harvey, C., Rajgopal, S., 2005. The Economic Implications of Corporate Financial
Reporting. Journal of Accounting and Economics: vol.40, no.1, 3-73.
Gray, S., Meek, G., Roberts, C., 1995. International Capital Market Pressures and Voluntary
Annual Report Disclosures by U.S. and U.K. Multinationals. Journal of International Financial
Management and Accounting: vol.6, no.1 43-68.
Hertzberg, A., 2005. Managerial Incentives, Misreporting, and the Timing of Social Learning: A
Theory of Slow Booms and Rapid Recessions. Working paper.
Hodrick, R., Prescott, E., 1997. Postwar US Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation.
Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking: vol.29, 1-16.
Johnson, S., Ryan, H., Tian, Y., 2009. Executive Compensation and Corporate Fraud. Review of
Finance: vol.13, no.1, 115-145.
Kedia, S., Koh, K., Rajgopal, S., 2010. Evidence on Contagion in Corporate Misconduct.
Working paper.
Kedia, S., Philippon, T., 2007. The Economics of Fraudulent Accounting. Review of Financial
Studies: vol.22, no.6, 2169-2199.
King, G., Zeng, L., 2001. Logistic Regression in Rare Events Data. Political Analysis: vol.9, no.2,
137-163.
Lavington, F., 1922. The Trade Cycle: An Account of the Causes Producing Rhythmical Changes
in the Activity of Business. P.S. King and Sons.
Martin, K., McConnell, J., 1991. Corporate Performance, Corporate Takeover, and Management
Turnover. The Journal of Finance: vol.46, no.2, 671-687.
Miller, G., 2006. The Press as a Watchdog for Accounting Fraud. Journal of Accounting
Research: vol.44, issue 5, 1001-1033.
Myers, J., Myers, L., Skinner, D., 2006. Earnings Momentum and Earnings Management.
Working paper.
Norton, E., Wang, H., Ai, C., 2004. Computing Interaction Effects and Standard Errors in Logit
and Probit Models. The Stata Journal: vol.4, no.2, 154-167.
Povel, P., Singh, R., Winton, A., 2007. Booms, Busts, and Fraud. Review of Financial Studies:
vol.20, no.4, 1219-1254.

68

Rajgopal, S., Shivakumar, L., Simpson, A., 2007. A Catering Theory of Earnings Management.
Working paper.
Rouam, S., Moreau, T., Broet, P., 2011. A Pseudo-R Squared Measure for Selecting Genomic
Markers with Crossing Hazard Functions. BMC Medical Research Methodology: vol.11, no.28.
Sadka, G., 2006. The Economic Consequences of Accounting Fraud in Product Markets: Theory
and a Case from the US Telecommunications Industry (WorldCom). American Law and
Economics Review: vol.8, 439-475.
Schrand, C., Zechman, S., 2008. Executive Compensation and the Slippery Slope to Fraud.
Working paper.
Strobl, G., 2008. Earnings Manipulation and the Cost of Capital. Working paper.
Wang, T., Winton, A., 2010. Competition and Corporate Fraud Waves. Working paper.
Watts, R., 2003. Conservatism in Accounting. Accounting Horizons: vol.17

69

70

Appendix Table 1

Indicator variable equal to 1 in the period a manager begins committing accounting fraud.
2005 chained GDP, inflation adjusted, expressed in 100s of billions of dollars and detrended
using the Hodrick-Prescot filter.
First difference of the GDP variable.
Indicator variable - 1 if the year is 1 or 2 years before an economic peak.
Indicator variable - 1 if the year is 1 or 2 years after an economic trough.
Average correlation between monthly firm returns and the equal weighted market return.
Average median absolute forecast error. Calculated as the absolute value of EPS less the
consensus analyst forecast closest to the report date, scaled by beginning of period price.
Equal weighted average price-earnings ratio.
Index from a principal components analysis of CA, MAFE, and PE.
Detrended difference between GDP and GDP forecast as provided by the Philadelphia FED
'Survey of Professional Forecasters'.
Standard deviation of the monthly market return.
Difference between the long term Baa corporate bond rate and the 10 year US Treasury rate.
SEC annual budget, expressed in millions of dollars.
Average time to detection in years for accounting frauds beginning in the current year
Number of IPOs in the last 3 years.
Indicator variable - 1 if the firm issued debt or stock in the current period.
Lagged annual firm return less the lagged annual value weighted market return.
Price/earnings ratio for the firm.
Delta of all shares held by the CEO at year end calculated using the Core & Guay methodology.
Number of total options and restricted stock held by the CEO.
Indicator variable coded 1 if [(cash flow from operations - past three year average capital
expenditures)/current assets]<-0.5.
Level of external finance raised scaled by average total assets.
Equal weighted average price-revenue ratio.
CA, MAFE, or PE value for the market calculated excluding the respective industry value
for the individual firm.
R-squared obtained by regressing the monthly value-weighted market return on firm returns.
Percentage of firms that fail to meet their consensus median analyst forecast.
Earnings response coefficient calculated by regressing earnings surprise on abnormal returns.
Revenue response coefficient calculated by regressing revenue surprise on abnormal returns.

Fraud
GDP

R2
Forecast
ERC
RRC

CFF
PR
Market

Volatility
Risk Premium
SEC
Detect
IPO
Capital
Lag Ab Return
PE - Firm Level
Wealth
Grant
Xfin

PE
PCI
Surprise

GDP Change
Peak
Trough
CA
MAFE

Definition

Variable

Variable Definitions

CRSP
IBES and Compustat
Compustat and CRSP
Compustat and CRSP

Compustat
Compustat
CRSP, IBES, and Compustat

Compustat
CRSP, IBES, and Compustat
Bureau of Economic Accounts
and the Philadelphia FED
CRSP
St.Louis FED
SEC
SEC - AAER
CRSP and Jay Ritter
Compustat
CRSP
Compustat
Execucomp
Execucomp
Compustat

Bureau of Economic Accounts


National Bureau of Economic Research
National Bureau of Economic Research
CRSP
IBES and Compustat

SEC - AAER
Bureau of Economic Accounts

Data Sources

Appendix Table 2
Descriptive Statistics
Variable

Mean

Std. Dev.

25th

Median

75th

Fraud Firms
Capital

59.20%

Lag Ab Ret

16.60%

0.907

-44.70%

-6.20%

42.40%

PE - Firm Level

16.85

66.87

4.17

11.01

24.99

Wealth

2195

6157

84

226

1030

Non Fraud Firms


Capital

52.60%

Lag Ab Ret

4.90%

0.669

-34.20%

-5.30%

25.30%

PE - Firm Level

14.69

52.52

1.32

12.38

21.21

913

3675

30

93

427

Wealth

This table provides descriptive statistics for firm-level variables for fraud firms and non-fraud firms.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

71

Appendix Table 3
Hazard Analysis: SEC Chair Fixed Effects
CA
GDP

CA

MAFE

1.076
(0.44)

1.392 *
(1.94)

PE
1.626 *
(1.94)

0.915 **
(-1.99)

MAFE

0.857 *
(-1.92)

PE

1.152 **
(2.03)

Surprise

1.013
(1.26)

1.000
(0.00)

1.004
(0.46)

Volatility

1.793 **
(2.18)

1.263 **
(2.66)

1.245 **
(2.53)

Risk Premium

0.635
(-0.83)

0.956
(-0.76)

1.039
(0.08)

Detect

0.999
(-0.02)

0.999
(-0.76)

1.001
(1.25)

IPO

0.701
(-0.90)

0.516
(-1.47)

0.735
(-0.75)

Capital

1.231
(1.46)

1.231
(1.45)

1.220
(1.39)

Lag Ab Return

1.220 **
(2.09)

1.230 **
(2.19)

1.220 **
(2.09)

PE - Firm Level

SEC Chair Fixed Effects


R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

1.001
(0.91)
Yes

Yes

Yes

0.22
271
2987

0.23
271
2987

0.22
271
2987

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic, market incentive, and firmlevel conditions present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates.
Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to the different market incentive proxy tested. Z-stats
are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

72

Appendix Table 4
Hazard Analysis: Industry Level
Fama-French 5 Industry
CA
MAFE
PE

Fama-French 12 Industry
CA
MAFE
PE

GDP

1.138 **
(2.04)

1.203 *
(1.90)

1.742 ***
(2.63)

1.142 **
(2.05)

1.221 *
(1.91)

1.539 *
(1.70)

Surprise

1.015 ***
(2.80)

1.014 **
(2.27)

1.013 **
(2.03)

1.015 ***
(2.95)

1.014 **
(2.26)

1.014 *
(1.76)

Volatility

1.432 ***
(3.21)

1.303 ***
(2.69)

1.376 ***
(2.97)

1.472 ***
(3.38)

1.303 ***
(2.70)

1.373 ***
(3.17)

Risk Premium

0.563
(-1.29)

0.772
(-0.48)

0.536 *
(-1.70)

0.534
(-1.41)

0.739
(-0.57)

0.53
(-1.59)

SEC

0.999
(-1.24)

0.999
(-0.64)

1.001
(0.53)

0.999
(-1.28)

0.999
(-0.60)

1.000
(0.24)

Detect

0.523
(-1.14)

0.575
(-0.97)

0.559
(-0.98)

0.525
(-1.12)

0.57
(-0.99)

0.554
(-1.04)

IPO

CA - Industry

1.000
(0.43)

1.002 ***
(2.68)

1.002 ***
(4.10)

0.004 ***
(-3.21)

MAFE - Industry

1.000
(0.20)

1.002 ***
(2.72)

1.002 ***
(3.34)

0.001 ***
(-3.12)
0.787 **
(-2.29)

PE - industry

0.862 *
(-1.73)
1.155 *
(1.82)

1.103
(0.97)

Market

5.455 **
(2.41)

1.042 ***
(3.22)

0.993
(-0.45)

7.385 ***
(4.28)

1.009 *
(1.69)

0.988
(-0.87)

Capital

1.113
(0.73)

1.02
(0.13)

0.994
(-0.04)

1.155
(0.96)

1.014
(0.09)

0.991
(-0.06)

Lag Ab Ret

1.048
(1.16)

1.061
(1.44)

1.05
(1.34)

1.069 *
(1.80)

PE - Firm Level

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

1.067 *
(1.84)
1.002 ***
(2.61)

0.18
271
2987

0.13
271
2987

1.065 *
(1.77)
1.002 **
(2.57)

0.17
271
2987

0.19
271
2987

0.12
271
2987

0.16
271
2987

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic, market incentive, and firmlevel conditions present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates.
All market incentive proxies are calculated at the industry level using the Fama-French industry definitions. Standard errors are
clustered annually and by industry. Each column corresponds to the different market behavior proxy tested using either 5 or 12
industries. Z-stats are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

73

Appendix Table 5
Hazard Analysis: Firm-Level Variables
Full Sample

Wealth

Capital

1.249
(1.56)

1.694 *
(1.68)

Lag Ab Return

1.196 *
(1.78)

1.127
(0.46)

PE - Firm Level

1.001
(1.03)

1.001
(0.47)

Wealth

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

1.002
(0.29)
0.014
271
2987

0.034
104
1046

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the firm-level conditions present when
managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates. Standard errors are
clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to a different way of measuring aggregate performance. Z-stats are
presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

74

Appendix Table 6
Hazard Analysis: Market Incentive Proxies
R2
GDP

R2

1.286 ***
(3.90)

Forecast
1.259 **
(2.10)

ERC
1.374 ***
(5.92)

0.876 ***
(-3.53)

Forecast

0.982
(-0.56)

ERC

1.403 ***
(4.94)

Surprise

1.009 **
(2.33)

1.012
(1.41)

1.002
(0.68)

Volatility

1.398 ***
(3.96)

1.236 ***
(3.04)

1.270 ***
(3.33)

Risk Premium

0.611
(-1.16)

0.409 *
(-1.79)

SEC

0.998 ***
(-3.66)

0.999
(-0.88)

0.519
(-1.41)

Detect

0.539
(-1.22)

0.381 **
(-1.96)

0.991 ***
(-5.36)

IPO

0.999
(-0.16)

1.000
(0.69)

1.002 ***
(3.86)

Capital

1.273
(1.39)

1.276
(1.39)

1.271
(1.37)

Lag Ab Return

1.260 ***
(2.89)

1.270 ***
(2.95)

1.083 **
(2.27)

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

0.17
271
2987

0.12
271
2987

1.492
(1.08)

0.14
271
2987

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic, market incentive, and firmlevel conditions present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates.
Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm. Each column corresponds to the different market incentive proxy tested. Z-stats
are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

75

Appendix Table 7
Hazard Analysis: Industry Level
Panel A
Fama French 1
GDP

CA - Industry

1.168 **
(2.09)
0.849 ***
(-3.31)

Fama French 2

Fama French 3

0.998
(-0.02)

1.053 ***
(3.29)

1.012
(0.61)

Volatility

2.506 ***
(3.41)

0.996
(-0.02)

Fama French 5

0.987
(-0.04)

1.222
(0.84)

0.975 *
(-1.86)

1.020
(0.39)

0.918 *
(-1.72)

0.993
(-0.70)

1.017
(1.05)

1.022
(1.32)

1.065
(0.15)

1.291
(1.19)

1.491 **
(2.32)

0.908 **
(-2.05)

Surprise

Fama French 4

1.360 *
(1.71)

Premium

0.164
(-1.63)

1.091
(0.06)

0.658
(-0.45)

2.399
(0.48)

0.313
(-0.85)

SEC

0.999
(-0.10)

0.999
(-0.04)

0.998
(-0.90)

0.993
(-1.26)

0.995
(-0.90)

Detect

0.308
(-1.03)

2.843
(0.76)

0.211 *
(-1.69)

4.002
(0.79)

0.839
(-0.13)

IPO

0.996 *
(-1.86)

1.001
(0.28)

1.002
(1.55)

1.004 **
(2.39)

0.997
(-1.52)

Capital

1.136
(0.42)

1.687
(1.13)

1.149
(0.58)

1.136
(0.30)

Lag Ab Ret

1.160 **
(1.98)

Fraud Firms
Non Fraud Firms

77
562

0.824
(-0.41)

1.063 **
(2.03)

32
612

89
751

2.942 ***
(2.62)

0.935
(-0.67)

1.130
(1.34)

25
264

48
798

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the macroeconomic, market incentive, and firmlevel conditions present when managers begin committing accounting fraud. The table presents hazard rates, not coefficient estimates.
All market incentive proxies are calculated at the industry level using the Fama-French industry definitions. Standard errors are
clustered annually and by industry. Each column corresponds to the different market behavior proxy tested using either 5 or 12
industries. Z-stats are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

76

Appendix Table 7: Continued


Hazard Analysis: Industry Level
Pane l B

GDP

Fama -

Fama -

Fama -

Fama -

Fama -

Fre nch 1

Fre nch 2

Fre nch 3

Fre nch 4

Fre nch 5

1.247 **

1.215

1.078

(2.11)

(0.31)

(0.17)

0.867

0.077 **

0.742 *

1.099 **
(2.01)

MAFE - Industry

Surprise

Volatility

Pre mium

SEC

De te ct

IPO

Capital

Lag Ab Re t

2.301

Non Fraud Firms

(-0.62)
0.605 **

(0.56)

(-2.08)

(-1.62)

1.028

1.014

1.004

1.036 *

1.009

(1.35)

(0.90)

(0.44)

(1.83)

(0.68)

1.851

0.917

1.251

1.206

1.007

(1.45)

(-0.41)

(1.63)

(0.85)

(0.04)

(-2.11)

(-1.71)

0.099

3.990

1.119

1.679

0.535

(-1.40)

(0.63)

(0.11)

(0.38)

(-0.40)

1.003

0.997

0.998

0.997

0.994

(0.47)

(-0.69)

(-0.96)

(-0.56)

(-1.12)

0.090

4.032

0.508

2.705

0.458

(-1.23)

(0.94)

(-0.86)

(0.67)

(-0.65)

1.000

1.001

1.002 ***

1.005 **

(0.28)

(0.29)

(2.66)

(1.97)

1.155

1.689

1.139

1.118

2.929 **

(0.47)

(1.14)

(0.54)

(0.26)

(2.62)

1.138 *

0.843

1.065 *

0.911

1.121 **

(1.74)
Fraud Firms

0.728

(-0.35)

(1.93)

(-0.82)

0.999
(-0.36)

(2.29)

77

32

89

25

48

562

612

751

264

798

77

Appendix Table 7: Continued


Hazard Analysis: Industry Level
Pane l C

GDP

PE - Industry

Surprise

Volatility

Fama -

Fama -

Fama -

Fama -

Fama -

Fre nch 1

Fre nch 2

Fre nch 3

Fre nch 4

Fre nch 5

1.249

0.704

1.658 **

2.748 **

1.042

(1.57)

(-0.85)

(2.35)

(2.10)

(0.10)

1.062 **

1.216 **

0.930

1.143 *
(1.90)

(-1.39)

(2.29)

(2.26)

1.029

1.032

1.001

1.056 **

1.005

(1.56)

(1.50)

(0.14)

(2.28)

(0.31)

1.940 *

0.935

1.407 **

1.675 *

1.017

(-0.32)

(2.25)

(1.73)

(0.10)

0.705

0.384

1.007

0.341

(-0.22)

(-1.01)

(0.01)

(-0.79)

(1.95)
Pre mium

0.072 *
(-1.95)

SEC

De te ct

IPO

Capital

Lag Ab Re t

PE - Firm

Fraud Firms
Non Fraud Firms

0.849

(-0.55)

1.001

1.001

0.999

1.008

0.994

(0.25)

(0.36)

(-0.24)

(0.93)

(-0.81)

0.102

1.233

0.228

6.155

0.312

(-1.47)

(0.17)

(-1.31)

(1.08)

(-0.89)

1.001

1.001

1.002 **

1.012 ***

(0.32)

(0.32)

(2.50)

(3.59)

0.999
(-0.28)

1.112

1.646

1.145

1.091

2.823 **

(0.34)

(1.07)

(0.57)

(0.20)

(2.58)

1.146 *

0.867

1.034 *

0.919

1.186 *

(1.88)

(-0.31)

(1.83)

(-0.68)

1.003

1.001

1.002 *

1.003

(1.37)

(0.45)

(1.67)

(0.76)

(1.70)
0.994 *
(-1.77)

77

32

89

25

48

562

612

751

264

798

78

Appendix Table 8
Logistic Regressions:
Interactions
8
Grant

Xfin

CFF

PE

0.611 **
(2.44)

0.067
(0.88)

0.086
(1.16)

Grant

0.014
(0.93)

Xfin

-0.298
(-0.54)

CFF
Interaction
GDP

-0.434
(-0.64)
-0.000
(-0.09)
1.732 ***
(3.05)

0.068 **
(2.01)

0.099 *
(1.83)

0.386 **
(2.47)

0.404 **
(2.59)

Surprise

-0.026
(-1.14)

0.014 **
(2.14)

0.014 **
(2.10)

Volatility

0.119
(0.53)

0.282 ***
(3.98)

0.304 ***
(4.26)

Risk Premium
SEC

-1195
(-0.48)
0.002
(0.57)

Detect

-1.382
(-0.68)

IPO

-0.002
(-0.43)

Capital

-0.442
(-0.91)
0.004 ***
(2.95)
-1.215 **
(-2.61)

-0.482
(-0.98)
0.004 ***
(3.08)
-1.172 **
(-2.50)

0.001 ***
(3.55)

0.001 ***
(3.15)

0.517 *
(1.66)

Lag Ab Return

-0.069
(-0.57)

0.064
(1.50)

0.044
(1.02)

PE - Firm Level

-0.000
(-0.09)

0.002 *
(1.95)

0.001
(1.44)

Constant

-4.735
(-0.38)

-4.538 **
(-2.43)

-4.772 **
(-2.59)

Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms
Pseudo R-Squared

104
1046
7.90%

271
2987
4.70%

271
2987
5.10%

This table shows results from logistic regressions testing the interaction between price sensitivity to news (measured using PE ratios)
and various potential firm-level determinants of accounting fraud. Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm and the
interaction has been adjusted using the Norton, Wang, and Ai correction technique. Each column corresponds to the specific interaction
tested. Z-stats are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

79

Appendix Table 9
Hazard Analysis: Fraud Type - ERC
Revenue Fraud
GDP

Expense Fraud

0.246 ***
(3.40)

Balance Sheet Fraud

0.477 ***
(3.81)

0.059
(0.51)

0.387 ***
(4.07)

0.301
(1.59)

ERC

-0.297 **
(-2.04)

RRC

0.233 **
(2.10)

0.103
(1.37)

0.078
(-0.48)

Surprise

0.001
(0.11)

0.002
(0.22)

0.007
(0.61)

Volatility

0.294 ***
(3.12)

0.355 ***
(4.75)

0.551 ***
(3.21)

Risk Premium

0.003
(0.20)

0.122
(1.43)

0.333 *
(1.85)

SEC

-0.005 *
(-1.79)

-0.015 ***
(-3.77)

-0.014 ***
(-2.94)

Detect

-0.220
(-0.32)

-0.593
(-1.28)

-2.096 ***
(-3.00)

IPO

0.003 ***
(3.07)

0.004 ***
(6.25)

0.004 ***
(5.79)

Capital

0.080 *
(0.47)

0.423
(1.42)

0.327
(1.60)

Lag Ab Return

0.058 *
(1.68)

0.069
(1.28)

0.056
(0.85)

PE - Firm Level

0.002 **
(2.33)

0.000
(0.11)

0.002
(0.89)

0.20
92
3166

0.26
68
3190

R-Squared
Fraud Firms
Non-Fraud Firms

0.17
155
3103

This table presents results from estimates of a Cox proportional hazards model testing the relation between type of accounting fraud
and price sensitivity to that type of news. The table presents coefficient estimates. The revenue column represents results for revenue
fraud, expense for expense fraud, and balance sheet for balance sheet fraud. Standard errors are clustered annually and by firm.
Z-stats are presented in parentheses. ***, **, and * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% levels respectively.
Detailed variable definitions and their data source are included in Appendix Table 1.

80

You might also like