You are on page 1of 69

Unilateral Trade Policy

Professor Ralph Ossa


33501 International Commercial Policy

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Introduction
So far, we compared two extreme scenarios, autarky
and free trade, and concluded that countries are usually
better off under free trade.
But is free trade also a countrys optimal trade policy?
And why do governments engage in trade policy in
practice?
In this lecture we look at unilateral trade policy only. In
the next lecture we will then consider multilateral trade
negotiations.
2

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments


Governments use a wide range of trade policy
instruments in practice. The most important ones are:
(i) import tariffs,
(ii) export subsidies,
(iii) import quotas,
(iv) voluntary export restraints, and
(v) local content requirements

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments import


tariffs
Import tariffs are simply taxes on imported goods.
Governments usually impose one of two types of import
tariffs:
A specific tariff, i.e. a tariff charged per unit of imports,
say $1,000 per imported automobile.
An ad valorem tariff, i.e. a tariff charged per value of
imports, say $.1 per $1 worth of imported automobiles
(or simply 10 percent).
4

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments import


tariffs (cont.)
In the U.S., tariffs are relatively modest by international
standards. Currently, the U.S. average (ad valorem
equivalent) tariff is less than 2 percent.
However, this does not imply that U.S. tariffs are low in
all sectors. Indeed, the U.S. imposes much higher tariffs
in sectors such as clothing and apparel, leather and
footwear, and agriculture. Remember also our
discussion on antidumping duties.

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments export


subsidies
Export subsidies are simply subsidies on exported
goods. Governments again usually impose one of two
types of export subsidies:
A specific export subsidy, i.e. a subsidy paid per unit of
exports, say $1,000 per exported automobile.
An ad valorem export subsidy, i.e. a subsidy paid per
value of exports, say $.1 per $1 worth of exported
automobiles (or simply 10 percent).
6

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments export


subsidies (cont.)
In the U.S., export subsidies are mainly applied in
agriculture. An example is the Department of
Agricultures Dairy Export Incentive Program (DEIP).
The DEIP is designed to help exporters of dairy
products meet prevailing world prices for targeted dairy
products and destinations.
The E.U.s Common Agricultural Policy is another wellknown agricultural export subsidy program (more on
that later).
7

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments import


quotas
An import quota is a restriction on the quantity of a
good that may be imported.
This restriction is usually enforced through import
licenses. While these are usually issued to importers in
the importing country, they are also sometimes issued
to governments of exporting countries.
In the U.S., the quota on sugar imports is an example of
the latter kind. It restricts yearly sugar imports to
approximately 1.4 million tons.
8

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments voluntary


export restraint
A voluntary export restraint (VER) is essentially an
export quota. Despite its name it is typically not fully
voluntary but instead requested by an importing country.
The Japanese VER on auto exports to the U.S. between
1981 and 1985 is perhaps the best known example. It
restricted Japanese auto exports to the U.S. to 1.68
million units initially and 1.85 million units eventually.

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments local


content requirement
A local content requirement is a regulation that
requires a specific fraction of the final good to be
produced domestically. In may be specified in terms of
value or of physical units.
In the U.S., the Buy American Act is a good example. It
was originally passed in 1933 and requires government
agencies to give preference to U.S. firms in their
procurement. In particular, a bid by a foreign company
can only be accepted if it is a specified percentage
below the lowest bid by a U.S. firm.
10

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of trade policy instruments local


content requirement (cont.)
Also, American firms are not allowed to simply act as
sales agents for foreign firms. While American
products may contain some foreign parts, 51 percent of
the materials must be domestic.
This requirement can lead to some curious situations.
For example, the made in the USA buses bought in
1995 by the cities of Miami and Baltimore were really 49
percent made in Hungary.

11

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Overview of the lecture


Unfortunately, we cannot discuss all effects of all these
trade policy instruments in detail.
We only analyze import tariffs and export subsidies in a
simple perfectly competitive environment:
(i) What is a countrys optimal import tariff? Why do
governments impose import tariffs in practice?
(ii) What is a countrys optimal export subsidy? Why do
governments impose export subsidies in practice?
12

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework


Consider an industry in which Home is an importer and
Foreign is an exporter.
It is useful to illustrate the (partial) equilibrium using
import demand and export supply curves.
Homes import demand curve measures the quantity
Homes consumers demand minus the quantity Homes
producers supply for any given Home price.

13

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)

Price

No-trade
equilibrium

Price
S

PA

A'

Eachpointontheimport
demandcurveisapoint
thatcorrespondstoHome
importsatagivenHome
price

A
B

PW
D
S1Q0D1Quantity

14

Imports,M1

Importdemand
curve,M
M1Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)


Foreigns export supply curve measures the quantity
Foreigns producers supply minus the quantity Foreigns
consumers demand for any given Foreign price.
Home is typically referred to as small, if changes in
Homes import demand have only a negligible effect on
Foreigns price so that Foreigns export supply curve
facing Home is flat.
Home is typically referred to as large, if changes in
Homes import demand have a non-negligible effect on
Foreigns price so that Foreigns export supply curve
facing Home is upward sloping.
15

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)

Price

No-trade
equilibrium

Case1:Homeissmall

Price
S

PA

A'
A
B

PW
D
S1Q0D1Quantity

16

Imports,M1

Foreignexport
supply,X*
Importdemand
curve,M

M1Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)

Price

No-trade
equilibrium

Case2:Homeislarge

Price
S

PA

A'
Foreignexport
supply,X*

A
B

PW
D
S1Q0D1Quantity

17

Imports,M1

Importdemand
curve,M
M1Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)


Consumer welfare can be measured by consumer
surplus, in this supply and demand framework.
Consumer surplus is given by the difference between
what consumers would be maximally willing to pay and
what they actually pay.
Graphically, it can be represented by the area below the
demand curve and above the price.

18

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)

19

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)


Producer welfare can be measured by producer
surplus in this supply and demand framework.
Producer surplus is given by the difference between
what producers would be minimally willing to charge
and what they actually charge. We can loosely refer to
this difference as profits.
Graphically, it can be represented by the area above the
supply curve and below the price.
20

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)

21

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff basic framework (cont.)


Suppose now that Homes government imposes a
specific import tariff.
Notice that the tariff drives a wedge between the price in
Home and the price in Foreign.
For example, if the tariff is $1,000 per unit, PT = PT* +
1,000. In general, PT = PT* + t.

22

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff overview


The effects of Homes tariff differ in important ways
between the small country and the large country case
and we discuss both cases in turn.
First, we demonstrate that the optimal tariff of a small
country is zero.
Second, we show that the optimal tariff of a large
country is positive.

23

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case


Homepricerisesbytheamount
ofthetariff

No-trade
equilibrium
Price

Price
S

Homesupplyincreasesand
Homedemanddecreases
importsfalltoM2
Foreignproducersstillreceive
thenet-of-tariffpricePW

PT=PW+t

PT*=PW

PW

X*+t

D
DD
S1S

2
2

1
M2
24

Quantity

Foreignexport
supply,X*
M

M2

M1

Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case (cont.)


No-trade
equilibrium

Thelossinconsumer
surplusduetothehigher
pricewiththetariffisequal
totheshadedarea(a+b+c
+d)

Price
S
A

PW+t

PW

D
S1S2D2D1Quantity
25

M2

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case (cont.)


No-trade
equilibrium

Thegaininproducer
surplusduetothehigher
pricewiththetariffisequal
totheshadedarea(a)

Price
S
A

PW+t

PW

D
S1S2D2D1Quantity
26

M2

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case (cont.)


No-trade
equilibrium

Thegainingovernment
revenueduetothetariffis
equaltotheshadedarea(c)

Price
S

Thisequalsthetariff,t,times
thequantityofimports,M2

PW+t

PW

D
S1S2D2D1Quantity
27

M2

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case (cont.)


The optimal tariff of a small country is therefore zero:
Fallinconsumersurplus
Riseinproducersurplus

Riseingovernmentrevenue
NeteffectonHomewelfare

-(a+b+c+d)
+(a)
+(c)
-(b+d)

The area (b+d) is referred to as deadweight loss or


efficiency loss. It arises because the tariff distorts
consumption and production decisions.
28

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case (cont.)


No-trade
equilibrium

(a)isatransferfrom
consumerstoproducers

Price

(c)isatransferfrom
consumerstothe
government
(b+d)isdeadweightloss

S
A

PW+t

PW

D
S1S2D2D1Quantity
29

M2

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff small country case (cont.)


Thedeadweightlosscan
alsobeillustratedinthe
importdemandandexport
supplydiagram

Price
Deadweightloss
duetotariff,b+d

X*+t

X*

M
M2
30

M1

Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case


Homepricenowrisesbyless
thantheamountofthetariff
Price

Price

No-trade
equilibrium

Foreignproducersare
absorbingpartofthetariff
X*+t

S
A
PT*+t

PW
PT*

X*

C
B*
C*

M
S1S2D2D1Quantity

M2
M1
31

M2M1

Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case (cont.)

No-trade
equilibrium

Price

Price

X*+t

b+d

A
PT*+t
PW
PT*

X*

-(a+b+c+d)
+(a)
+(c+e)
-(b+d)+(e)

Fallinconsumersurplus
Riseinproducersurplus
Riseingovernmentrevenue
NeteffectonHomewelfare

B*
D

C*
M

S1S2D2D1Quantity
32

M2M1

Imports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case (cont.)


The net effect on Home welfare is therefore ambiguous.
It is positive if e > b + d and negative if e < b + d.
On the one hand, there is again a deadweight loss (b
+ d) just as in the small country case. It again arises
because the tariff distorts Homes consumption and
production decisions.
But on the other hand, there is now also a terms-oftrade gain (e). It arises because the tariff lowers
Foreigns export prices.
33

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case (cont.)


It can be shown that the terms-of-trade gain dominates
the deadweight loss for a sufficiently small tariff so that
the optimal tariff of a large country is positive.
The derivation of this result is actually not too difficult. If
you are interested, you can take a look at the appendix
to chapter 9 in K-O.

34

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case (cont.)


Theoptimaltariffmaximizes
theimporterswelfare,pointC
Toohighofatariffwilldecrease
importerswelfareandcan
increasetothepointwhere
thereisnotrade

Termsoftradegain
exceedsdeadweight
loss

Importers
Welfare

FreeTrade

B'
B
A

NoTrade

35

Termsoftradegainis
lessthandeadweight
loss

Optimal
Tariff

Prohibitive
Tariff

Tariff

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case (cont.)


It turns out that the optimal tariff is just the inverse of the
elasticity of Foreign export supply:
Optimal tariff = 1/EX*
EX* is the percentage increase in the quantity exported
in response to a percentage increase in the world price
of the export.
Intuitively, the optimal tariff is decreasing in EX* since
Homes monopsony power in world markets is
decreasing in EX*.
36

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal import tariff large country case (cont.)


As is easy to verify, Homes gain from a tariff comes
directly at Foreigns expense. This is because Homes
terms-of-trade gain is Foreigns terms-of-trade loss.
The optimal tariff is therefore a beggar-thy-neighbor
policy.
This observation will play a crucial role in our discussion
of trade negotiations next week.

37

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff


This model can be used to estimate how costly tariffs
are in practice.
We illustrate this using the case of U.S. steel tariffs,
which were in place from March 2002 until December
2003. For simplicity, we consider only the small country
case.
Of course, this estimate is very rough since it relies on
many special assumptions (small country, no variety
effects, no productivity effects, etc.). However, it is a
useful starting point for more sophisticated calculations.
38

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)


During the 2000 presidential campaign, George W.
Bush promised to protect the U.S. steel industry. To
deliver on this promise, he requested that the
International Trade Commission (ITC) initiate a Section
201 investigation into the steel industry.
As we will discuss in more detail next week, Section 201
of the U.S. Trade Act of 1974 mirrors Article XIX of the
General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT),
known as the safeguard or escape clause. It allows a
temporary tariff to be used under certain circumstances.
39

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)


After investigating, the ITC determined that the
conditions of section 201 and Article XIX were met and
recommended that tariffs be put in place to protect the
U.S. steel industry.
The tariffs recommended by the ITC varied across
products, ranging from 10 percent to 20 percent for the
first year and then falling over time so as to be
eliminated after three years. President Bush accepted
the ITCs recommendation but applied even higher
tariffs.
40

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)

41

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)


Knowing that U.S. trading partners would be upset by
this action, President Bush exempted some countries
from the tariffs on steel.
The countries exempted included Canada, Mexico,
Jordan, and Israel, all of which have free-trade
agreements with the U.S., and 100 small developing
countries that were exporting only a very small amount
of steel to the U.S..

42

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)


RecallthattheDWLis
givenbytheareaofthe
triangle(b+d)

Price

Deadweightlossdue
tothetariff,b+d
PW(1+)
P=PW

DWL=PWM

PW
M
M2M1Imports
43

Inourcalculation,we
havetotakeintoaccount
thatthesteeltariffis
quotedasanadvalorem
tariff

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)


It is convenient to first compute the DWL relative to the
import value in the year prior to March 2002:
DWL 1 PW M 1
=

= ( )(%M )

PW M1
2 PW M1
2

Since the most commonly used steel products had a


tariff of 30 percent in the year following March 2002, we
set = .3.
Since the quantity of steel imports in the year following
March 2002 was about 25 percent less than in the year
prior to March 2002, we set %M = -.25.
44

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application U.S. steel tariff (cont.)


Hence, DWL = 1 ( )(%M ) = 1 (.3)(.25) = .0375
PW M

The welfare loss in the year after March 2002 was


therefore equal to around 3.75 percent of the import
value in the year prior to March 2002.
Since the import value in the year prior to March 2002
was equal to around $4.7 billion, the net welfare loss to
the U.S. economy in the year after March 2002 was
equal to around $176 million.
45

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice


The above analysis suggests three motives for
governments to impose import tariffs:
(i) raising government revenue,
(ii) increasing producer welfare,
(iii) increasing overall welfare.
All these motives appear to be relevant in practice.

46

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice raising government


revenue
Recall that one effect of an import tariff is to generate
government revenue.
While tariffs are more distortionary than income or
value-added taxes, they are also much easier to collect.
This makes them an attractive source of government
revenue especially for poor countries.
Even in the U.S., tariff revenue was the main source of
federal government revenue from the 1790s until the
1910s.
47

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice raising government


revenue (cont.)

48

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice increasing producer


welfare
Recall that another effect of an import tariff is to
increase producer welfare.
Producers are usually better organized politically than
consumers and therefore lobby the government more
effectively so that the government puts more weight on
producer surplus in its trade policy decisions.
One reason for this asymmetry is that the political
collective action problem is easier to overcome the
smaller is the number of benefitting individuals.
49

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice increasing producer


welfare (cont.)
Most economists believe such special interest politics to
be at the heart of most trade policy decisions.
In a famous study, Princeton professor Penny Goldberg
and Yale professor Giovanni Maggi (1999) find that the
degree of import protection is systematically related to
campaign contributions in the U.S..
In particular, industries donating more generously tend
to receive more import protection in return.
50

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice increasing overall


welfare
Recall that a small import tariff can also increase overall
welfare in the large country case.
While the optimal tariff argument is analytically
impeccable, most economists believed it to be of little
relevance in practice.
Very recent evidence provided by Chicago Booth
professor Christian Broda together with coauthors,
however, suggests that this is not the case.
51

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Import tariffs in practice increasing overall


welfare (cont.)
For a sample of non-World Trade Organization (WTO)
member countries, Broda et al. (2009) find that import
tariffs are systematically related to export supply
elasticties.
In particular, import tariffs tend to be higher in
industries, which face a lower export supply elasticity,
just as predicted by the optimal tariff formula.
The reason they focus on non-WTO countries will
become apparent in the next lecture.
52

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy basic framework


Consider now an industry in which Home is an exporter
and Foreign is an importer.
We can again illustrate the equilibrium in this industry
using import demand and export supply curves.
Analogous to our above discussion, Foreigns import
demand curve facing Home is flat if Home is a small
country and downward sloping if Home is a large
country.
53

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy basic framework (cont.)


Case1:Homeissmall
Home
Price

World
Price
S

Homeexport
supply

B
PW
Foreignimport
demand

PA
A

D 1
54

X1

S1

Quantity

X1

Exports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy basic framework (cont.)


Case2:Homeislarge
Home
Price

World
Price
S

Homeexport
supply

B
PW

Foreignimport
demand

PA
A

D 1
55

X1

S1

Quantity

X1

Exports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy basic framework (cont.)


Suppose now that Homes government imposes a
specific export subsidy.
Notice that the subsidy again drives a wedge between
the price in Home and the price in Foreign.
For example, if the subsidy is $1,000 per unit, P*S = PS 1,000. In general, PS = PS* + s.

56

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy overview


The effects of an export subsidy again differ between
the small country and the large country case.
However, the differences matter less for the overall
result.
In particular, the optimal export subsidy is zero in both
cases.

57

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy small country case


Homepricerisesbytheamount
ofthesubsidy
Home
Price

World
Price

ForeignconsumersstillpayPW

Homesupplyincreasesand
Homedemanddecreases
exportsincreasetoX2
C

PS=PW+s
s

Xs

B
PS*=PW

PW

C'
s

D 2 D 1
58

X1
X2

S1 S2 Quantity

X1

X2

Exports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy small country case


(cont.)
Home
Price
PW+s
s

b
a

World
Price

Totaldeadweight
loss,b+d

Xs

C
B

PW

C'
s

D 2 D 1
59

X2

S1 S2 Quantity

X1

X2

Exports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy small country case


(cont.)
The optimal export subsidy of a small country is
therefore zero:
Fallinconsumersurplus
Riseinproducersurplus
Fallingovernmentrevenue
NeteffectonHomewelfare

-(a+b)
+(a+b+c)
-(b+c+d)
-(b+d)

The area (b+d) is again a deadweight loss arising


because of consumption and production distortions.
60

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy large country case


Homepricenowrisesbyless
thantheamountofthesubsidy
Home
Price

World
Price
D

X2

PS*+s
s

Foreignconsumersare
absorbingpartofthesubsidy
Homeexports
supply,X

S
s

X1

Xs

PW
PS*
Foreign
import
demand,M*
D 2 D 1

61

S1 S2 Quantity

X1

X2

Exports

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy large country case (cont.)


Fallinconsumersurplus
Riseinproducersurplus
Fallingovernmentrevenue
NeteffectonHomewelfare

Home
Price
D
PS*+s
s

PW

PS*

D 2 D 1
62

S1 S2 Quantity

-(a+b)
+(a+b+c)
-(b+c+d+e)
-(b+d+e)

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Optimal export subsidy large country case (cont.)


The optimal export subsidy of a large country is
therefore also zero. The welfare costs are even larger
than for a small country because of an additional termsof-trade loss.
As is easy to verify, Foreign gains from Homes export
subsidy in this case. This is because Homes terms-oftrade loss is Foreigns terms-of-trade gain.

63

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application Europes CAP


The E.U.s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) provides
financial support to European farmers at a massive
scale through a variety of policy instruments.
CAP expenditures were 49.8 billion in 2006,
accounting for 48 percent (!) of the E.U.s entire budget.
The CAP began as an effort to guarantee high prices to
European farmers by having the E.U. buy agricultural
products whenever the prices fell below specified
support levels.
64

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application Europes CAP (cont.)


To prevent this policy from drawing in large quantities of
imports, it was initially backed by tariffs that offset the
difference between European and world agricultural
prices.
The result was that the E.U. found itself obliged to store
huge quantities of food. At the end of 1985, European
nations had stored 780,000 tons of beef, 1.2 million tons
of butter, and 12 million tons of wheat.

65

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application Europes CAP (cont.)


To avoid unlimited growth in these stockpiles, the E.U.
turned to a policy of subsidizing exports to dispose of
surplus production.
In view of our analysis of export subsidies above, who
gained and lost from these export subsidies, assuming
(realistically) that the E.U. is a large country?

66

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application Europes CAP (cont.)


European farmers gained, European consumers lost,
and European governments had to incur the subsidy
costs. On balance, Europe lost from these export
subsidies.
Farmers in the rest of the world lost and consumers in
the rest of the world gained. On balance, the rest of the
world gained from these export subsidies.
The negative effect on farmers in developing countries
was often criticized.
67

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Application Europes CAP (cont.)


Starting in 1992, the CAP has been reformed
substantially. It is now much less based on price
support and much more on direct payments to farmers,
which are often independent of the amount of
production.
Nevertheless, agricultural protectionism is still a highly
controversial issue in multilateral trade negotiations. In
fact, the Doha Round of trade negotiations is currently
suspended mainly because of disagreement over such
protectionism, as we will discuss in more detail next
week.
68

International Commercial Policy


Unilateral Trade Policy

Export subsidies in practice


The above analysis suggests only one motive for
governments to impose export subsidies: raising
producer surplus as discussed in the case of import
tariffs.
While this is likely to be a critical driving force of
governments trade policy decisions, other motives for
export subsidies can arise in imperfectly competitive
environments. This is also the case for import tariffs.
Some of these other motives are discussed in the two
Krugman articles on the reading list.
69

You might also like