You are on page 1of 31

MARKETS: HOW THEY WORK?

Positive and normative thinking


Positive economics deals with what is; normative thinking deals with what ought to be and is value-laden. All sciences and fields
of learning try to be positive and deal with facts and models based on facts. You should try to be positive i.e. scientific in your
statements, especially when writing essays and in the exam room.
Words like "ought", or "should" or as a nation we must are all normative statements and you should do your best to avoid them.
Try not to say things like It would be better if,or the government should. it would be a good thing for X to do Y. Many
policy prescriptions you might wish to make are normative, e.g., The economy would be better off if we. and it can raise an
examiners hackles. You might get away with a general statement such as Some advocate, It has been suggested that or
Many believe that. as these are positive statements and sound less normative. Note that the words used in an otherwise
scientific study can themselves carry a normative feeling, e.g. "freedom", "democracy", "efficiency", or "welfare" may all seem to
be good words to many people; whereas words such as inequitable, exploitation, "unsound", "interference", "fascist", or
"police state" seem "bad" to many people.

Opportunity cost
We live in a world of scarcity, in the sense that we can never have everything that we might like. As a result we must make
choices, for instance whether to buy this or that, whether to eat this or that, whether to walk in the park or go to a movie, or
whether to produce this or that. Every time we make a choice to do some- thing we automatically exclude something else that we
did not do we have given it up. We call this the opportunity cost.
Definition Opportunity cost is the best forgone alternative
i.e. it is what we gave up to get what we did. The opportunity cost of buying new pair of shoes might be a lunch forgone.
The opportunity cost of buying a new shirt might be not going to the cinema.
The opportunity cost of taking a part-time job might be not being able to hang out in the mall with your friends.
For a producer
The opportunity cost of buying plastic packaging material might be the cardboard he did not buy.
NB there can be many alternatives foregone, but only one will be the opportunity cost you cannot add them up and say they are
all the opportunity cost, because it must be a choice between them.
Opportunity cost can be thought of as:
1. The cost in pounds (represents a real thing given up); or
2. The cost in time.
Opportunity cost is important
1. We use it whenever we are deciding what to do, for example shall we hire a couple of videos or buy a piz- za instead.
2. It always arises with budget allocations. At some point in your life you may have to draw up a budget and allocate money for
different purposes. You will be forced to weigh up what is really needed in your tennis club, computer society, your country or
whatever.
3. It lies behind the cost curves that we draw. How does this work?
Consider two producers, A and B. Producer A might have to pay 20 a ton to get the iron ore to make into motor cars. Producer A
sees the cost as 20, but we see it as the way of making sure he gets the resources, rather than letting B get them! So the
opportunity cost really does stand behind the cost curves we draw.
Similarly in consumption: if something costs 10, you have to pay 10 to buy it. That 10 is not only the price of the object, it is
also the amount you have to pay to get the resources, raw materials, labour etc. that went into making it. This prevented these
resources from going into making something else.

After you buy the item it will be reordered by the shopkeeper and replaced on the shelf. S/he orders from a wholesaler who in turn
orders more from the producer. The producer then buys the raw materials etc. to make another of whatever you bought! In this
way, resources keep on going into making whatever people demand.
4. This is how the price mechanism really works that is, how it allocates resources to wherever the de- mand is the greatest
The production frontier or production possibility curve
What is it?
It shows us the maximum that a country can produce. There is clearly a limit to this at any one time just like there is a limit to the
weight that you can lift over your head or eat at any time. We assume two goods (I will use apples and bananas as these easily
can be represented by A and B) for ease of explanation but it is true of any number of goods.
Drawing the diagram we start with the maximum amount of good A we can produce if all our resources are devoted to
producing A which gives us a point on the vertical axis; then we do the same for the case if we only produce B to give us a point
on the horizontal axis. Then we join the two positions with a straight line. Once we have drawn the line, we do not have to have
all apples or all bananas but we can chose some- where along it. Any point on it represents a mix of the two goods that people
wish to buy. At the point se- lected above, people consume 0A1 apples and 0B1 Bananas.

[DIGRESSION: DRAWING THE CURVES


You should practise drawing all the diagrams regularly several times each day is a good idea. In the end, they need to be
second nature to you so that you can recall and correctly draw the appropriate diagram whenever you want. It is most important
to be able to this so that you can quickly gain good marks. The wrong diagram, a mislabelled one, or one lacking labels, more or
less dooms you to fail. It shows that you do not really understand what you are saying and examiners hate that. Labels, by the
way, are the words on the diagram, like apples, bananas or ppc 1 in this diagram.
When tutoring, I would draw each diagram again in front of the student, and explain the importance of get- ting it right (and
remind them of this now and then later). It is important to see how a diagram is built up as they are really easy to do, but to be
suddenly presented with a complicated finished product can be a bit daunting. For this reason, I have put in a sensible order of
drawing the diagram for the first few times I present them. It is just about impossible to get a good mark in economics without
drawing diagrams, so start practicing without delay!
Warning! It may seem easy, but it helps you much less if you download diagrams from the Internet and paste them into essays. It
is more valuable for you to draw them, and learn them, for yourself. END OF DIGRESSION]
The way the diagram of the production possibility curve is drawn.

We usually draw the production function curved , to reflect the law of diminishing returns. Some factors of production are better at
producing A and not as good at B, as you might imagine. Some land is simply bet- ter at growing bananas than apples, just as
some of your friends are better at doing maths, swimming or playing the guitar than others. So as we move down the production
possibility curve and get more bananas, we can expect to get a few less bananas than we might expect; perhaps we used to give
up 5 apples to get 5 more bananas, but as we slide down the curve we will get, say, only 4 more bananas, then only 3 more, or 2
more, as we keep sliding down.
The line curves in at each end to show this as in the diagram below.

[Digression. It is unlikely in my view that you will be asked why the production frontier is curved as op- posed to a straight line, but
if you do, the reasoning above and the diagram explains it. In the diagram you can easily see that if we had a straight line
production possibility curve (like AB) we could produce the max- imum amount of apples at the end of it, that is, at A, and have no
bananas at all. But as diminishing returns do exist, we are actually on the curved A2B2. The maximum apples possible are at A2
(not A which we could reach if we were on the straight line ppc ). As diminishing returns put us on the curve not the straight, the
difference between A2 and A is the quantity of apples lost because of diminishing returns, End of digres- sion]
It is common to use straight line production frontiers in text books because they are easier to draw and ma- nipulate, so they
often look like the diagram below.

What happens if we swivel the curve? If society learns to get better at producing Apples alone, it would swivel the curve out along
the vertical axis of apples. This reflects the fact that we can get more output from the resources and factors of production that we
have. The swivel that gives us more apples reflects a productivity increase in apples, but not in bananas.

After the productivity increase in the apple growing industry, withe same quantity and quality of factors of production, society can
increase the output of apples from 0A1 to 0A2, that is, by the distance A1 to A2.
If we swivel it the other way, and push out B , we would get a productivity increase in bananas, but not in apples.
What if we move the whole curve out? If a country has learned to get better at producing every- thing, this would physically move
the production frontier upwards and outward, which is economic growth.

We return to the subject of economic growth in the unit Managing the economy.

Specialisation and foreign trade


If people specialise they are more productive if you are like me, you probably could not make a good pair of shoes, do brain
surgery or advise on investing for pensions! We tend to do what we are best at. Imagine the result if we did what we are worst at!
Countries are the same if they concentrate on what they are best at, they produce more and better goods or services. As a rule
of thumb, countries that follow a protectionist policy (protecting their industries from foreign competition) are trying to do what they
are worst at, or at least not trying to do what they could be best at. Most economists would probably think that protectionism is not
exactly a good idea.
Two concepts of advantage

Absolute advantage this means a country can produce more of almost everything than another, i.e., it is a wealthy country.
The USA can produce more than Egypt for instance clearly, the USA has an absolute advantage over Egypt. It is of no
particular interest as an idea: the rich are just rich!

Comparative advantage this means that a country is better at producing something, but not necessarily everything, than
another. For instance, Sweden is better at making marine engines than the UK, but we are better at organising financial markets
and insurance. All countries are better at doing a few things more than others.
Comparative advantage is the one that matters in economics and it is the main reason why countries trade with each other. We
do not simply buy pineapples from tropical countries because it is too cold to grow them here. We could in fact grow them under
glass and with heating, but we clearly lack a comparative ad- vantage in the pineapple producing business. Hawaii on the other
hand has a strong comparative advantage in that area.
The gains from trade
If a country tries to produce everything for itself, it will stay poor. Examples: China under Mao Zedong and Russia under Stalin
both followed such a policy and the people suffered a very low standard of living as a result. The message is that trade helps the
people in a country to gain wealth!
The gains from trade consist of:
Comparative advantage we do what we are best at and thus produce more. We then exchange our surplus with other
countries for something we are less good at. Both the other countries and our country do better and enjoy higher living standards
as a result.
Economies of scale if we specialise we can follow a system of mass production, and lower our costs. We can then exchange
the surplus with other countries. Economies of scale are examined in Unit 2.
We can gain wider consumer choice e.g., we can drive Volvos, Renaults or BMWs, as well as lo- cally-made Fords!
Demand and supply: An introduction
(Abbreviations: S = supply; D = demand; Y = income; r = rate of interest)
At the equilibrium price, the quantity demanded just equals the quantity supplied. There are unsatisfied con- sumers who could
not buy at that price even though they were willing. What do we mean by equilibrium? Equilibrium is the state of affairs in which
there is no tendency to change. How do we show this equilibrium price? We use demand and supply curves.
Demand
What is the demand curve? It is a curve showing the quantity that will be bought on the market at different prices.
The lower the price, the more will be demanded; the higher the price the less will be demanded. Think! If all Nike trainers were 2
a pair, would you buy more than if they were 200 a pair? It seems probable!

In economics, demand means demand is backed by money it is not just a need or a desire, but people do have the money to
buy and are prepared to buy.
Supply
What is the supply curve? The supply curve is a curve showing the quantity that will be offered on the mar- ket at different prices.
We believe that higher prices cause more people to sell. Imagine: in your classroom,
if I offer to buy each T shirt for 500, almost everyone will sell to me; but if I offer 1 each, probably few if any would be willing If
however I were to offer 7, more would sell but probably not everyone. That is why the supply curve slopes upward.

Lets put both the demand and supply curves on the same diagram .

Guess where the equilibrium price will be? Right! Where the two curves cross! As said earlier, at the equi- librium price, the
quantity demanded just equals the quantity supplied. There are no unsatisfied consumers who could not buy at that price even
though they were willing and everyone who wanted to sell at that price could do so. This happy situation happens at the
intersection of D and S with price P and quantity Q.
When I started in economics, I had to chant along with the rest of the class: "price is determined by supply and demand! It
certainly made it stick in my mind and might help you too!
Let us return and look at demand in more detail (Well look at supply later too)
What determines the D curve?i.e., why is it where it is and not somewhere else?

1. There are four main personal determinants of demand


Income
Taste
Prices of other goods or service
Expectations about future prices of this good or service
2. AND several other market determinants
Income distribution - if you think of all the other people in your house and you as you are now, then if you suddenly got all the
total income and savings and the others had none, there would be a dif- ferent pattern of demand from what it is now. They
probably do not eat lunch every day if they have no money. It is the same in society in general: change the income distribution
and a new pattern of demand curves follows.
Wealth distribution (as opposed to income distribution). If 10% of the population have 90% of the wealth, probably more Porsche
motor cars will be demanded than if we all have the same rather lowish amount!

Population size - the larger the population, the bigger the demand, ceteris paribus. That is a Lat- in tag meaning all other
things remaining the same and you might come across it in a lot of eco- nomics books.
Population age distribution - if there are many old people, important demands in society will be for medicines, hip replacement
operations and Zimmer frames but fewer Beastie Boys CDs, or prams.
The interest rate. This is especially important for house purchases, motor cars, long-life consumer goods often on a credit card,
or hire purchase generally. A higher rate of interest means more to re- pay, so people tend to borrow less.
What can cause a shift in the demand curve? (= a new curve)
A change in any of the above determinants of demand will do it!
If demand increases, overall, more of the good/service is bought at any unchanged (the same) price. You can see this in the
diagram below, where at P1 an amount OQ1 is demanded, but after demand increases to D2,
at the same price an large amount is demanded, i.e., OQ2. It is easy to remember what an increase in de- mand means; there
must be a new curve and it will move upwards and to the right.

The effects of an increase in demand are usually analysed using the equilibrium positions determined by the intersection of
demand and supply.

You can see that the increase in demand means we move from the equilibrium position P1Q1 to the new equilibrium position
P2Q2. More is demanded - we shift from the position Q1 to the position Q2, so the dif- ference (OQ2 minus OQ1) is Q1Q2.
The way the diagram of a shift in demand is drawn,(shown not moving to the new equilibrium, so you can see that more is
demanded at the same price)

The way the diagrams are built up should be reasonably clear by now. If you have any worries,
check back and examine those supplied earlier. The general principles are:
1. Draw the axes and label them immediately (one axis, two axes).
2. Put in the first curve and label it.
3. Add the second curve and label it.
4. Draw the equilibrium position preferably using dotted lines.
5. Make the necessary changes, such as shift a curve inwards or outwards by drawing a new
curve and la- belling it.
6. Draw the new equilibrium position preferably using dotted lines.
7. And finally you compare the new equilibrium position with the first one, using your own words
but trying to get in the necessary jargon phrases such as increase in demand, or economic
growth, whatever is relevant to the question you are tackling.
Henceforth I shall not be supplying the series of pictures showing how the diagrams are built up,
as you should be able to follow the above principles for yourself. Before long, it will become
second nature to ex-amine a finished diagram and work out how it was built up.
If demand decreases, the demand curve shifts the other way, downward and to the left. Again we have a new curve, as in the
diagram below.

You will notice that less is bought at any given price, such as P.
Again, a decrease in demand is usually analysed by determining the new equilibrium position and the com- paring it with the
original one. For this we need to put the supply curve in.

As you can see, if demand decreases, then less is bought (as you might imagine!) and the quantity demanded falls from Q2 to
Q1; price also falls, in this case from P1 to P2
Let us look at supply in more detail
What determines the supply curve, i.e. why is it where it is and not somewhere else?

The answer is, the price, quantity, and quality of inputs used. These consist of things like machinery, equipment, staff and
workers, raw materials, and fuel. These are collectively known as the factors of production, and are often summarised as land,
(L) labour (N) and capital (K) plus a remainder term, R.
Land - is what it says but can include things like diamonds or oil that are found there.
Labour mostly means workers, but also includes managers.
Capital means machinery and equipment. A subset of this issocial overhead capital - like roads, bridges and docks.

[Digression: The whole production of the nation can be summed up as: O = f(L, N, K) + R
or put into words, output is a function of (= is in some as yet undefined way caused by) land,
labour, capi- tal, and a few other things. You will need this later; I am just sowing a few seeds.]
The remainder term R, which covers things in both labour and capital is the really interesting one
The labour component of R. This consists of things like entrepreneurial ability, the managerial methods in use, labour motivation
and how good it is, labour skills, the strength of the trade union and its attitudes, the bonus and other incentive systems in force,
the quality of the education system, and the retraining facilities available in society.
The capital component of R. This consists of things like:

The level of technology, knowledge about what technology is available, the adequacy of factory organi- sation, and economies of
scale. They can obviously affect the supply curve, or the output possible, if they are good or bad.
Maybe the weather, e.g. floods can destroy crops, effect transport, reduce supply, and raise price.
Joint supply - if we increase the number of sheep to supply an increased demand for mutton, it auto- matically increases the
wool supply. So the price of related good can be a determinant of supply. Examiners like questions on joint supply,

but it is not often encountered in the world in which we live.


The productivity of the factors of production this is closely related to technology; but it can also be how hard workers are
prepared to work, motivation, and incentives systems etc. (it too can appear separately, or be included in the remainder term, R,
as above).
The size and number of firms in the industry, including the marketing conditions.
War and social unrest.
What can cause an increase or decrease in supply?(a shift in the curve)
Like demand, it needs a change in one or more of the determinants. For supply these include things like:
A change in the price of a factor of production.
A change in the productivity of a factor.
New technology invented.
The discovery of a new raw material or fuel.
More worker enthusiasm. This occurs often in war time, because of patriotism.
An increase in supply = the curve shifts downward and to the right (more is supplied at the unchanged price) - e.g., if labour
productivity increases or someone finds a new cheap source of materials.

You will notice that the quantity supplied at the unchanged price P1 increases - well, thats what an increase in supply does!
And if we put in a demand curve we can see both the equilibrium positions and work out that an increase in supply means a fall in
price and an increase in the quantity purchased.

Time Periods And Supply


Three time periods matter:
the very short run (VSR) (or momentary supply),
the short run (SR) , and
the long run (LR).
They have different slopes to their curves and different elasticities (more later!).
The very short run. This is defined as the time when no change can be made in any of the factors of produc- tion the supply
curve is vertical. Examples are the fruit and vegetables that appear in the wholesale market each day.
The short run.
This is defined as the period in which the variable factors can be altered but not the fixed factors, i.e. we can make some
changes.
Fixed factors = those that do not vary with output such as factory building, transport fleet, office staff, and the bill for heating and
lighting the premises.
Variable factors = those that vary directly with output such as raw materials, the energy used, the petrol in the trucks, and the
wages of some unskilled workers who might be taken on when needed, perhaps part-time.
The supply curve we usually draw is the short run one. The long run
Is defined as the period when all factors can be varied i.e., the producer can do any changes s/he wants. This means a flatter
curve, possibly even downward sloping sometimes.
How the supply curve can vary with the time period we are considering:
The flatter the curve, the more elastic it is (quantity stretches more). Producers will only make changes that help them produce
more or reduce costs.

NOTE that all the curves are drawn on the one diagram; this means the scale is the same for all; if you draw each in a separate
diagram, the flatter one (S long run) is not necessarily the most elastic, as the horizontal axis might be on a much wider scale. If
this seems incomprehensible to you, Do Not Worry! Just remember to put them all on the same diagram.

Remember that you should practise drawing the diagrams regularly!


Increases and Extensions of Supply And Demand
We know that the word "increase" means a shift of the curve but what about extensions? "Extensions" are movements along an
existing curve.
Questions are often set to see if you know the difference between an increase and an extension.

[A digression: if a line crosses two others, an increase in one curve always means an extension of
the other! The diagram here shows that.

We see two upward sloping lines that cross a single line. The upward sloping lines reflect an increase (or decrease) and we slide
down (or up) the single line.
For supply and demand:
With an increase in demand we slide up an unchanged supply curve.

NOTE that we start on demand curve D1 and supply curve S1 to ascertain the equilibrium price and quantity; then we look at D2
to get the second equilibrium position.

Reminder: In economics, at this level we always start in equilibrium, then we alter something, and
move to the new equilibrium position. We then compare the two equilibrium positions for the
analysis.
And we can see an increase in supply goes with an extension of demand, as we slide down an unchanged demand curve:

Decreases and contractions of supply and demand


A decrease means a new curve, which shifts backwards; a contraction means sliding back along an un- changed curve.
A contraction of demand following a decrease in supply :

A contraction of supply following a decrease in demand:

Here is one of the hoary old trick questions. "Demand increases, so price rises. The rise in price means fewer can afford the
good, so demand decreases and prices fall again." Do you agree with this statement?

Question: what do you think?


At first glance it might seem to make sense. But it is in fact false!
Why is it false? You draw the diagram now on a piece of paper. First increase the demand curve and you will see the price rise as
we extend up the supply curve.
Then think about the new equilibrium. Why on earth should it change? It is an equilibrium position! That was why you learned the
definition of equilibrium a little while ago - to be able to detect fallacies in argument.

This is a proposition in logic, designed to test if you really understand supply and demand. You should try to get the words
extension and increase in to show you can use them properly and you definitely need a diagram.
The elasticity of demand
ELASTICITIES
Elasticities are a sort of measure of supply and demand.
If demand increases, and we ask how much does supply extend, we need more than an answer like "quite a lot"!! Government
may be trying to raise tax to get a certain amount of revenue for instance. The question is How much will quantity change, a lot
or a little?
WE START WITH THE ELASTICITY OF DEMAND
Three broad types of elasticity of demand
1. Price elasticity = the usual one, it deals with 1 good.
2. Cross elasticity = a special one, it deals with 2 goods.
3. Income elasticity = a special one and it deals with changes in incomes.
1. Price Elasticity of Demand
Definition: "Price elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded to a small change in price".
Learn this by heart!
[In simpler terms, is the proportional change in quantity greater or lesser than the change in price?
As an example, if the price was 20 and it falls by 2, the fall is 10% (2 times 100, all divided by 20); and if quantity then increases
from 100 to 200, the increase is 100%.
We can see that the increase in Q is greater (100% compared with 10%) - i.e., it stretches out a lot - it is elastic!]
How do we actually measure price elasticity?
Price elasticity of demand is measured by the percentage change in Qd, divided by the percentage change in price:
%Qd / %P
So the price elasticity of demand is:
[Q/Q] / [P/P]
Q/Q x P/P (to divide by fraction invert and multiply)
Q/P x Q/P (gathering the change terms all on side for neatness. If this shuffling makes you unhappy, just remember that 3 x
4 is the same as 4 x 3)
In the example above, the percentage change in Q was 100 and the percentage change in price was 10 so the elasticity is 100
divided by 10 = 10.0 In the world in which we live this is actually very high! (Anything over 2 in the real world is pretty high.)
Logically the answer can have only 1 of 3 results: <1, = 1, or >1
(< stands for less than; > stands for more than; if we are looking at < left to right, the way we read, we see it goes little to big
so it is easy to remember!)
When we look at the fraction, we find that the answer is less than 1 if the top is smaller than the bottom, equal to 1 if the top and
bottom are the same, or more than 1 if the top is greater than the bottom.
What does each possible answer mean?
a] If the answer is greater than 1 (e.g., 1.62) the demand curve is elastic.

It means that a small change in price led to big change in quantity (Q stretched a lot which means that it is elastic); graphically the
curve tends to look flat when compared with an inelastic curve. But remember all curves must have the same scale and axis or
else be on the same diagram.
Examples of demand curves which are price elastic:
Dell computers (one brand of many substitutes); foreign travel by cheap airlines.
b] If the answer is less than 1, e.g., 0.75, the demand curve is inelastic People do not respond so much to price cuts and although
they buy more, they do not buy a lot more.
Examples:
Salt, bread, sets of cutlery (essentials; no substitutes).
c] If the answer just happens to equal 1 it is unit elastic (unity = 1), a special case and rarely seen, except perhaps for a small
part of a large demand curve! The answer would work out at exactly 1.0 and the curve is asymptotic; this means that it
approaches more and more closely but never quite reaches the axes.
Reminder: if you draw one rather flat demand curve in one diagram, demand is actually only relatively elastic etc because we
do not know the scale - dont worry about it, its technical! Just remember to say relatively inelastic or relatively elastic in the
exam room! If you draw them on one diagram then you are on safer ground if you just say elastic.
What do the different elasticity demand curves look like?

The importance of the elasticity concept


It allows us to get precise answers, not be vague.
We need it for certain questions e.g., if a hairdresser is considering increasing her price for a basic cut from
20 to 25, will profits rise or fall?
What determines price elasticity?
The number of substitutes - the greater the substitutes, the more elastic the good - a small price rise means consumers switch
to another brand. THIS IS THE MAIN DETERMINANT!
The proportion of income - the greater the proportion of income going on good, the more elastic it tends to be. Salt is relatively
inelastic and very cheap - would you consume a 2s worth a year?
Luxuries and necessities - luxuries tend to be more elastic (airfares, foreign travel); necessities more inelastic (electricity). Some
economists do not like this luxuries point because what constitutes a luxury alters too much and in addition they can be
personal to different individuals.
Time - the longer the time, the more elastic demand tends to be, probably because
More substitutes become available , the good or service is copied by others, new manufac- turers can enter, imports be made
etc.
Habits change only slowly, so we adjust to new prices slowly.
Capital may need to wear out to make change, e.g., if the price of petrol rises, drivers have to wait until it is time to buy a new
and smaller car in order to reduce petrol consumption.

Q. For the hairdresser earlier who is considering a price rise, I asked earlier what would happen to her profit if she charged more.
Assume she is very good and her clients feel that there is no real substitute?
A. The demand curve for her services is inelastic so profit would rise!
Q. But consider what would happen if she were just another high street hair dresser? Draw the diagram for me now!
Another example of the importance of elasticity: if the government raises the tax on cigarettes, will government revenue rise or
fall? And by how much?
The government normally wishes to raise more revenue - although there are health benefits if people reduce cigarette
consumption, which saves on National Health Service expenditure too.
If the government raises tax by 5% and demand is inelastic, the quantity will fall as price rises, but it will fall by less than 5%,
so revenue will increase.
If the government imposes an indirect tax, it pushes up the supply curve by the exact amount of tax.
If the tax is absolute e.g., 1 each item, it pushes the curve up parallel. The original producer faces no change in supply
conditions, but 1 is added to each quantity.
When we draw the diagram for the imposition of indirect tax: we start at the original equilibrium, and add the tax.

When we look at the market equilibrium, we start with a supply and demand curve and see the original equilibrium. We then add
the tax, which pushes up the supply curve and look at the new equilibrium position, to see what changes the tax has made.

We can see that the original equilibrium position P1Q1 becomes P2Q2 once the tax is imposed. There is a rise in price - but by
less than the whole tax - and there is a fall in quantity.

The increase in tax per unit is AC, but the price only goes from P1 to P2 = BC; and BC is less than AC (price rises but by less
than the whole amount of tax per unit)
What about the change in government revenue? This is the quantity now sold (OQ2 at the new equilibrium position = the number
of units) times the tax per unit (AC). This is the area bounded by P2CAP3 in the diagram below.

If the indirect tax is ad valorem (proportional not absolute, e.g., 10%) it pushes up the supply curve at an increasing rate
Q. Why?
A. Because 10% of 1 is only 10P, but 10% of 10 is 1!

A subsidy is just a negative tax e.g., government gives producer some money (subsidy) rather than a producer or consumer
giving money to the government (tax).
Subsidy questions are not usually as interesting as tax ones!
Lets draw the diagram for putting on a subsidy.

We start, as ever, in the initial equilibrium position, P1Q1 on the curves S1 and D1. The subsidy goes on, the size of it is P1 to
P2, and the new supply curve is S2. You can see that the unchanged quantity, Q1, is now cheaper at price P2- but we have not
yet examined the new equilibrium position to see the results of the change.
What is the total amount of the subsidy, i.e., the cost to the government? We need to look at the new equilibrium position, which
will be at P2Q2, below.

The subsidy is AB for each unit in the diagram above. The quantity sold after the subsidy is imposed is OQ2.
So how much does the subsidy cost the government, and ultimately the tax payer?

The subsidy the government pays is the new quantity sold, (0Q2) times the subsidy amount per unit of
BA.
We know that BA is the same as CD because the curve shifts parallel.
We know that the suppliers continue with curve S1, so they require price 0P3 for quantity 0Q2 (Note that the supplier works off
the original supply curve - there has been no change in the determinants of his or her supply.)
We see that consumers pay the rectangle 0Q2CP2.
We see that the government pays the rectangle P2CDP3 - this is the subsidy cost to the tax payer. And together these add up to
the total expenditure of 0Q2DP3.
Notice also that consumption rises from 0Q1 to 0Q2 - which is the point of the subsidy: more is pro- duced and consumed.
The limits of price elasticity of demand
Perfectly elastic = a horizontal line; this means that consumers will demand an infinite amount at that price! It is merely a limit and
obviously it cannot be reached.
Perfectly inelastic = vertical line; this means that consumers will pay any amount at all, such as 1, or 1 million, or 1 trillion.
to buy the good or service. Again this is unreasonable, its merely a limit. They look like this:

2. Cross Elasticity of Demand


Definition: "Cross elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded of one good or service to a
small change in price of another". Learn this! It is virtually the same as the definition of price elasticity earlier - go on, compare
them now!
Cross elasticity measures substitutes and complements (note the spelling; it is not compliments)
If the supply of beef increases so the equilibrium price falls, it may induce some people to switch from eating chicken or pork to
eating the now cheaper beef. The fall in price of beef causes a decrease in quantity demanded of chicken or pork.
%Qd of good A / %P of good B
Note the A and B difference: we are dividing the percentage change in the quantity of A by the change in the price of B.

If the price of beef fell and the quantity of chicken fell the answer will be positive, because two negatives make a positive, so any
items with a positive cross elasticity are substitutes.
If the price of heating oil falls it may induce some to install oil generated central heating in houses. We see that a fall in the price
of A means an increase in the quantity of generators, so the answer is nega- tive (one plus and one minus) so these two goods
are complements.
Cross elasticity does not seem to be used much in economics, except in exams.
3. Income Elasticity of Demand
Now this is most important! Incomes keep increasing over time, so the demand pattern for various goods and services keeps
changing. This matters for new firms looking to move into the market and produce something: the market for what goods or
services is likely to grow the fastest? Thats the area to be in! It matters for existing firms looking to diversify, or be concerned
about the prospects for the future in the area they produce and sell in.
Definition: "Income elasticity of demand is a measure of the responsiveness of the quantity demanded of a good or service to a
small change in income". Learn!
Income elastic: a given change in income leads to a greater than proportionate increase in demand for the good or service.
Examples of income elastic goods: foreign travel, good wines, smart motor cars, eating in restaurants, and currently wellregarded brands, e.g., Adidas sportswear or Rolex watches.
Income inelastic: a given change in income leads to a less than proportionate increase in demand for the good or service.
Examples: bread, staple foods generally, cheap stores, and all lowly-regarded brands. If our income happens to double (lucky
us!) we do not spend twice as much on such items.
Income neutral elastic: should it just happen that, say, a 5% increase in income leads to a 5% increase in demand for a good or
service, then it is income neutral elastic. This is not really an interesting case, merely a bit strange. Oddly enough, Pizza Hut in
Australia claimed in the 1990s that they were like this: in a recession some people stopped eating out so stopped going to Pizza
Hut, but other people switched from proper restaurants to Pizza Hut which cancelled things out, so the company did not suffer!
Income negative elastic: this is most interesting! This happens when an increase in income causes a fall in demand. Really it
indicates that we dislike this product but for some reason we must consume it at
the time. When we can afford not to consume it, then we stop buying it. Examiners like this concept!
Examples are scarce, but it is suggested that probably potatoes were like this in Ireland during the Nine- teenth century.
Currently, the demand for mealies (sweet corn) in some African countries may be in- come negative elastic. It is a rare event
anyway. Negative income elasticity means that it is an inferior good.
The elasticity of supply
Definition: the responsiveness of the quantity supplied to a small change in price. It is measured by:
%Qs / %P
The measure roughly indicates the slope of the supply curve; the steeper the more inelastic. Why is this only roughly? Because
it depends on the scale of the diagram - for instance both the diagrams below have the same elasticity, but because the
horizontal scale is not the same the slopes look differ- ent. That is why we have to draw two different elasticities on the same
diagram where the scale is the same.

BUT unit elastic supply is any straight line that cuts through the origin! (Just remember this, and do not worry! If you are a
mathematician, you may already see why.)

Supply periods and time: (covered briefly earlier)

Very short run = totally inelastic supply = fixed supply (e.g., the amount in a wholesale vegetable market delivered each morning;
all the works of dead painters or sculptors).
Short run = perhaps moderately inelastic.
Long run = more elastic; or even negative elasticity (it slopes downward).
Why is supply more elastic in the long run?
Because the company can alter both the fixed and variable factors (i.e., all the factors of production). It can also find new or
cheaper sources of raw materials; improve the training of labour; and introduce new technology or better machines. This allows
the company to obtain more output without needing much increase in price.
The downward sloping supply curve in the long run is already familiar to you: computers, scanners, TV sets, digital cameras,
DVD players and discs, CD players and discs.. Most if not all of the prod- ucts of modern hi-tech industry fall into this category.
As the years go by, they get better and a lot cheaper.
Elasticity of supply is probably a bit less interesting to economists than the elasticities of demand - and it is easier to learn as
there is less of it!
Demand and supply: Applications to any market are possible
Popular ones that examiners often like to set a question about include:
Housing

Foreign exchange
Agricultural products or raw material production, like tin or coal (often inelastic S and D so fluc- tuations are common)
But the analysis is virtually identical in each case! You need to mention supply and demand very early in your answer and then
use supply and demand analysis, drawing the curves you need.
Be prepared to handle:
The concept of equilibrium
The determinants of supply and of demand
An increase in demand and a decrease in demand
An increase in supply and a decrease in supply
An extension of both demand and supply
The elasticity of demand and supply
Minimum price fixing (examined in Unit 2)
Maximum price fixing (examined in Unit 2)
Applying an indirect tax (which shifts S curve up and to right).
An example of foreign exchange
You must use a diagram or two!
The value of a currency is determined by the supply and demand for it - just like any other good or service, it is the normal
equilibrium diagram you need.
The supply of s comes from the UK importing goods and services from abroad. We pay in pounds to a bank, which uses them
to buy the US $ etc. that we need to pay the foreign supplier. If we import more, we increase the supply of pounds on the market,
thus putting pressure on the pound to fall in value. Similarly, if we export, we buy the pounds back, thereby increasing the
demand for pounds.
You could usefully practice drawing diagrams to fit these scenarios. They are the standard increase in supply and decrease in
supply diagrams, but with Quantity of on the horizontal axis and Price of in $ on the vertical one. We have to value the
pound in some other currency, such as US$.

If the UK increases its imports, this puts more pounds on the international markets as we pay for the extra imports. This means
an increase in the balance of trade deficit. This increase in supply then puts pressure on the value of the pound, which falls.

If foreign holders of pounds, largely banks but also others such as large international companies as well as international
speculators, decide the pound is overvalued and about to fall, they might sell. The results are the same: the increase in supply
reduces the value of the pound. This may be termed self justifying expectations.
An example of the labour market.
If the UK allows more migrants in, this increases the supply of labour. Because many migrants are relatively young males, they
add to the supply of labour, normally producing more than they take out in social security benefits.
The increase in the supply of labour puts pressure on to lower wages, especially for the unskilled or semi-skilled. It is difficult for
many migrants to find more professional work unless their English is good; they tend to end up in the unskilled sector, even if they
have skills and abilities, until their lan- guage skill improves sufficiently and this can take many months or years.
The result is the normal diagram for an increase in supply, in this case of labour. You need the quantity of labour on the horizontal
axis and wages on the vertical. Go on, draw it now!

Remember! You must use diagrams to answer questions about price or wages. Many markers
glance at the diagrams first and if they are correct, he or she is immediately disposed to give you
a good mark and a decent pass! If your diagrams are clear and correct, they might also give you
the benefit of the doubt if they have trouble with your handwriting or standard of grammatical
English. In the exam room in economics it is virtually impossible to get a good mark without
diagrams.
The market mechanism working
In a perfect world, a market system will give a perfect result - resources will be allocated exactly to where people need them to
produce what the people demand.
Think supply and demand curves for two goods, both in equilibrium; assume people spend all their money (as this is easier to
imagine how it works). Then increase the demand for one good (which means you must reduce demand for the other, because
they are spending all their money by assumption).
First we look at the goods market - lets assume they are bread and milk; we start in equilibrium, then we will increase the
demand for one good and see what happens.
Secondly, we examine the factor market which lies below the goods market. That consists of those resources that are used to
produce the bread and milk. We use the labour market as the factor of production.
We have simplified the model by using two goods and one factor to show the perfect workings of the market. With any number of
goods and services and more factors we can still get this perfect resource allocation.
(The whole of Unit One in this course is devoted to this market solution. Unit Two will explain why we may not in fact attain this
theoretical perfection.)
Abbreviations used: MC = marginal cost
AC = average cost
P = price
Q = quantity
MR = marginal revenue

Lab = labour
AR = average revenue
PPC = production possibility curve (production frontier)
We start with the market for goods or services (bread and milk) in equilibrium

And we can also examine the factor market for these goods; in this case we will use the people who make the bread and produce
the milk (Unit 4 covers labour markets in detail). Again we start in equilibrium. (The two diagrams below do not have to look
exactly the same as the two above; they just have to be normal supply and demand curves.)

THEN, WE CHANGE SOMETHING AND ALTER THE EQUILIBRIUM POSITIONS


lets increase the demand for bread and reduce the demand for milk. (On the assumption that all in- come is spent, if people
spend more on bread they must spend less on milk.) We start as usual in equi- librium, on the demand curve for bread, D1 and
increase it to D2. People switch to consuming more bread and away from milk, so the demand for milk falls, from D1 to D2.

You can see on the left that the price of bread rises (people demand it more) and on the right the price of milk falls (less demand).
Because of this change in the demand pattern, we get an increase in the demand for workers to produce more bread and a fall in
the demand for milk workers - and we will reach a new equilibrium in the factor market.
Again, demand increases from D to D1 for the bread workers, and falls from D to D1 for the milk workers.

You can see on the right that wages rise where demand for the product has increased (bread), and on the left they fall where the
product is less in demand than previously (milk).
We can put changes in goods/services market and factor markets together into one diagram, one directly above the other and
read it vertically to see what happens to the factors of production in both industries as demand changes.

We see, as the demand for a good or service increases (top left hand side), this sucks factors into that industry - but where do
they come from?
They come from the contracting industry, where the demand for a good or service has decreased (top right hand side) - the
factors of production (land, capital and workers) have to leave that industry (in the real world, if unemployment already existed,
some of the unemployed might be drawn into work).
Where demand for a good or service falls, the workers might simply be dismissed - which really annoys
people, upsets the trade unions, and might have a political fallout with loss of support for the government.
Or the firms may take advantage of natural wastage; that is to say that is to say, as people voluntarily leave, they are not
replaced.
Who leaves? Several groups may be involved:
old workers who are retiring because of age
those who get ill and retire
those resigning and moving to a better job as part of a career move
those who move to a new area of the country, following their spouse, to get to a better climate or school area for instance
those who migrate to a different country
those who die
Unemployed people are naturally very upset and social problems can emerge which the government may have to deal with. But
with capital, e.g., trucks, or warehousing facilities, shifting the use of these causes little upset - things have no feelings! They may
be sold or leased to other companies to use.
Land is similar to capital, it can often be transferred to several other uses fairly easily.

The above diagrams of resources moving from declining sectors to expanding ones and stopping in equilibrium demonstrate the
way the market mechanism (price mechanism) operates.
This was first spotted by Adam Smith in the Wealth of Nations as early as 1776 although the diagrams did not come until later.
Understanding how an economic system works in this fashion led to the phrase the consumer is king as the next sentence
explains.
Resources (land, labour and capital) flow from where they are not in demand, or demand is falling, to where they are in demand,
or demand is rising. So the price mechanism is well-regarded as a good (but by no means perfect) way of allocating resources to
societys demands.
Later, in Unit 2 Why markets fail you will learn what can, and actually does, go wrong with this apparently brilliant market
system.

A reminder: are you revising something and practising drawing a few diagrams each day?
Consumer and producer surplus
We know that there is an equilibrium market price at which both consumers buy and suppliers sell. But what about the consumers
and producers who are not themselves exactly at that equilibrium price? They receive a benefit.
For consumers, we can see from the demand curve that the first consumer, buying at 1 on the quantity axis, would be willing to
pay P1, which is much more than the market price he or she has to pay (P mkt). So the column above P mkt is a sort of surplus
that the first buyer enjoys!

Similarly, for the second buyer, at 2 on the quantity axis; and the same goes for the third and subsequent buyers until we get out
to Q1 and P Mkt. All these early consumers would pay more but do not have to do so - and they gain a lot of extra enjoyment as a
result. Eventually the whole triangle above P Mkt is filled in; and the filled in bit of this triangle, indicated by an arrow, is the
consumer surplus.
For producers, we have an analogous argument. Some would be willing to supply more cheaply than the equilibrium price, P Mkt.
In the diagram below, we can see from the supply curve that the supplier of the first unit would be happy to do this at a price well
below P Mkt. The column above quantity 1 up to P Mkt is again a sort of extra or surplus - which in this case belonging to the
producers.
Moving to quantity 2, again we can see a column, but a bit smaller than for quantity 1. And as we move out towards Q1, the
triangle above the supply curve but below P Mkt is filled in. The arrow again points to it. This is the producers surplus.

If we put the two diagrams together, we can see that both the triangles thus make up the total con- sumer surplus and the
producer surplus.

Use of the concept


With indirect taxation, the imposition of a tax (or if there already is such a tax, an increase or decrease in such a tax) may
impinge more on consumers than producers - or vice versa! Who gains the most (or who loses the most)? is the question. This
may be called the incidence of taxation, the tax burden, or a question may be asked, such as who bears the brunt of the tax?
The answer as to who gains or loses the most depends on the elasticities involved.
Let us assume that an indirect tax on a good increases. If demand is highly inelastic (consumers will pay almost any high price
without reducing consumption much) then the increase must largely fall on these consumers - they are simply willing to pay!
We know they are prepared to do so because the demand curve is relatively inelastic and that is what inelastic demand means.
Cigarettes probably fall into this category, as do all addictive drugs.
Think of a vertical demand curve: if we increase the tax, the supply curve just moves up; there is no change in the quantity
demanded; suppliers still receive the old price (reading off their supply curve S1; the gap between S1 and S2 is all tax and goes
to the government not to the supplier). There is clearly no loss of producer surplus as their situation has not changed at all - and
consumers pay all the difference:

It can be proved, but you can take it on trust, that if the elasticity of demand is lower than the elasticity of supply, the consumer
loses more than the supplier! In other words, it is the relative elasticities that count.
The usual supply and demand situation divides the incidence of tax (who pays it, or more of it) between suppliers and consumers
- and of course the incidence falls heavier on the side which is relatively inelastic.
You may get a question about the incidence of tax - or one about imposing (or increasing) an indirect
tax.

A reminder: in introductory economics we nearly always use static equilibrium analysis which
means we start in equilibrium, change something, and analyse the result.
Who then bears the burden of tax when an indirect tax increases? See the diagram below.

We start on the curves S1 and Demand, with the equilibrium price P1 and quantity Q1.
Then we add a tax (or increase an existing tax!) which shifts the supply curve up to S2, by the amount of the tax. Any tax per unit
shifts the supply curve up vertically; the tax is the line BD in the diagram above.
Having made our change, we look at the result: consumers pay BC of the tax, and producers pay CD of it. The distance CD is
smaller than the distance BC, the consumer pays more of the tax, and we also know that the elasticity of supply must be greater
than the elasticity of demand!
We can also look at the areas and see the changes in both surpluses: The consumer surplus reduces by ABC.
The producer surplus reduces by ACD.
In Unit, Industrial economics, we again use the concept of surpluses in our monopoly diagram. We can show the deadweight
loss of monopoly, as well as the loss of consumer surplus and the increase in the producer surplus that results from the
monopolist being able to set the quantity that he or she pro- duces which results in the most profitable price possible. More of this
later!

You might also like