You are on page 1of 55

Journal of Economic PerspectivesVolume 14, Number 3Summer 2000 Pages 159 181

Fairness and Retaliation:


The Economics of Reciprocity
Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

long-standing tradition in economics views human beings as exclusively


self-interested. In most economic accounts of individual behavior and
aggregate social phenomena, the vast forces of greed (Arrow, 1980) are
put at the center of the explanation. In economic models human actors are
typically portrayed as self-interest seeking with guile (which) includes . . . more
blatant forms, such as lying, stealing, and cheating . . . (but) more often involves
subtle forms of deceit (Williamson, 1985).
However, as we will document below, many people deviate from purely selfinterested behavior in a reciprocal manner. Reciprocity means that in response to
friendly actions, people are frequently much nicer and much more cooperative
than predicted by the self-interest model; conversely, in response to hostile actions
they are frequently much more nasty and even brutal. The Edda, a 13th century
collection of Norse epic verses, gives a succinct description of reciprocity: A man
ought to be a friend to his friend and repay gift with gift. People should meet smiles
with smiles and lies with treachery. There is considerable evidence that a substantial fraction of people behave according to this dictum: People repay gifts and take
revenge even in interactions with complete strangers and even if it is costly for them
and yields neither present nor future material rewards. Our notion of reciprocity is thus
very different from kind or hostile responses in repeated interactions that are solely
motivated by future material gains.

y Ernst Fehr is Professor of Economics and a Core Member of the MacArthur Foundation Network on Economic Environments and the Evolution of Individual Preferences
and Social Norms, while Simon Gachter is Assistant Professor of Economics, both at
the University of Zurich, Institute for Empirical Economic Research, Zurich, Switzerland.
Their web page is http://www.unizh.ch/iew/grp/fehr/index.html. Their e-mail addresses are
efehr@iew.unizh.ch and gaechter@iew.unizh.ch, respectively.

160

Journal of Economic Perspectives

We term the cooperative reciprocal tendencies positive reciprocity while the


retaliatory aspects are called negative reciprocity. In this paper, we first offer a
brief overview of the evidence for reciprocal actions in relatively abstract one-shot
games. Then, we show that reciprocity has powerful implications for many important economic domains. George Stigler (1981) wrote that when self-interest and
ethical values with wide verbal allegiance are in conflict, much of the time, most of
the time in fact, self-interest-theory . . . will win. Our evidence indicates that Stiglers position is often not valid. When the world is made up of self-interested types
and reciprocal types, interacting with each other, the reciprocal types dominate the
aggregate outcome in certain circumstances, while the self-interested types will
dominate the aggregate outcome in other circumstances. We will provide evidence
that there are important conditions in which the self-interest theory is unambiguously refuted. For example, in competitive markets with incomplete contracts, the
reciprocal types dominate the aggregate results. Similarly, when people face strong
material incentives to free ride, the self-interest model predicts no cooperation at
all. However, if there are individual opportunities to punish others, then the
reciprocal types vigorously punish free riders even when the punishment is costly
for the punisher. As a consequence of the punishing behavior of the reciprocal
types, a very high level of cooperation can in fact be achieved. Indeed, the power
to enhance collective actions and to enforce social norms is probably one of the
most important consequences of reciprocity.
This line of thought brings out another important implication of the presence
of reciprocal types: Details of the institutional environment, like the presence of
incomplete contracts or of costly individual punishment opportunities, determine
whether the reciprocal or the selfish types are pivotal. Institutional features like this
may thus have a tremendous impact on patterns of aggregate behavior that are
neglected by the self-interest model. As a consequence, economic predictions
regarding the impact of different institutions will be questionable if they do not
take into account the presence of reciprocal types. Moreover, it turns out that the
existence of reciprocal types may actually give rise to a world of incomplete
contracts, so that reciprocity helps to generate those conditions under which it can
flourish.

Positive and Negative Reciprocity: Some Evidence


Reciprocity is fundamentally different from cooperative or retaliatory behavior in repeated interactions. These behaviors arise because actors expect future
material benefits from their actions; in the case of reciprocity, the actor is responding
to friendly or hostile actions even if no material gains can be expected. Reciprocity
is also fundamentally different from altruism. Altruism is a form of unconditional
kindness; that is, altruism given does not emerge as a response to altruism received.
Again, reciprocity is an in-kind response to beneficial or harmful acts.
Examples of retaliatory behavior abound. Many wars and gang crimes fit well

Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

161

into this category. A vivid example is provided by the recent events in Kosovo when
many Albanian refugees took bloody revenge after the victory of NATO over
Serbian forces. Other examples are given by the rise in employees theft rates after
firms have cut employees wages (Giacalone and Greenberg, 1997) or by the social
ostracism exercised by coworkers against strikebreakers during and after industrial
disputes.
Likewise, positive reciprocity is deeply embedded in many social interactions.
Psychological studies show, for example, that smiling waitresses get tipped much
more than less friendly ones (Tidd and Lochard, 1978). Calls for contributions to
charities are often accompanied by small gifts. Apparently, charities believe that this
raises the propensity to donate. Uninvited favors, in general, are likely to create
feelings of indebtedness obliging many people to repay the psychological debt. A
particularly powerful example of this is the use of free samples as a sales technique
(Cialdini, 1993). In supermarkets, customers are frequently given small amounts of
a certain product for free. For many people it seems to be very difficult to accept
samples from a smiling attendant without actually buying anything. Some people
even buy the product although they do not like it very much. The normative power
of reciprocity is also likely to have an important impact on social policy issues
(Bowles and Gintis, 1998b). Social policies are much less likely to be endorsed by
public opinion when they reward people independent of whether and how much
they contribute to society.
Since in real world interactions, it is very difficult to rule out with certainty
that an actor derives a future material benefit from a reciprocal response, we
provide in the following discussion evidence on reciprocity from controlled
laboratory experiments. In these experiments, real subjects interact anonymously and face real, and sometimes rather high, material costs of reciprocal
actions, in a context where it can be precluded that reciprocal responses will
lead to future material rewards.
Perhaps the most vivid game to demonstrate negatively reciprocal behavior is
the ultimatum bargaining experiment. In this game, two subjects have to agree on
the division of a fixed sum of money. Person A, the Proposer, can make exactly one
proposal of how to divide the amount. Person B, the Responder, can accept or
reject the proposed division. In the case of rejection, both receive nothing; in the
case of acceptance, the proposal is implemented. A robust result in this experiment, across hundreds of trials, is that Proposers who offer the Responder less than
30 percent of the available sum are rejected with a very high probability (for
example, see Guth, Schmittberger and Schwarze, 1982; Camerer and Thaler, 1995;
Roth, 1995, and the references therein). Apparently, Responders do not behave in
a self-interest maximizing manner. In general, the motive indicated for the rejection of positive, yet low, offers is that subjects view them as unfair.
Negative reciprocity in an ultimatum game has been observed in many countries, including Indonesia, Israel, Japan, many European countries, Russia and the
United States (for example, see Roth, Prasnikar, Okuno-Fujiwara and Zamir,

162

Journal of Economic Perspectives

1991).1 Moreover, rather high monetary stakes do not change or have only a minor
impact on these experimental results. In the study of Cameron (1999), the amount
to be divided represented the income of three months for the subjects. Other
studies with relatively high stakes have involved college students dividing amounts
of $100 or more (Hoffman, McCabe and Smith, 1995; Henrich, forthcoming;
Slonim and Roth, 1998).
Positive reciprocity has been documented in many trust or gift exchange
games (for example, Fehr, Kirchsteiger and Riedl, 1993; Berg, Dickhaut and
McCabe, 1995; McCabe, Rassenti and Smith, 1996). In a trust game, for example,
a Proposer receives an amount of money x from the experimenter, and then can
send between zero and x to the Responder. The experimenter then triples the
amount sent, which we term y, so that the Responder has 3y. The Responder is then
free to return anything between zero and 3y to the Proposer. It turns out that many
Proposers send money and that many Responders give back some money. Moreover, there is frequently a positive correlation between y and the amount sent back
at the individual as well as at the aggregate level. Again, positive reciprocity does not
appear to diminish even if the monetary stake size is rather high; for example, Fehr
and Tougareva (1995) found strong positive reciprocity in experiments conducted
in Moscow, where their subjects earned on average the monetary income of ten
weeks in an experiment that lasted for two hours.
The fraction of subjects who show a concern for fairness and behave reciprocally in one-shot situations is relatively high. Many studies have carried out detailed
analyses of individual decisions and found that the fraction of subjects exhibiting
reciprocal choices is between 40 and 66 percent (Gachter and Falk, 1999; Berg,
Dickhaut and McCabe, 1995; Fehr and Falk, 1999; Abbink, Irlenbusch and Renner,
forthcoming). However, these same studies also find that between 20 and 30
percent of the subjects do not reciprocate and behave completely selfishly. Thus, a
nontrivial minority of subjects exhibits selfish behavior. Burnham (1998) found
that male behavior in the ultimatum game is systematically linked to testosterone
levels. Males who reject unfair offers have higher testosterone levels than males who
accept unfair offers. This is interesting because testosterone levels are thought to be
important mediators of male willingness to engage in aggressive behavior.
There is now little disagreement among experimental researchers about the
facts indicating reciprocal behavior. There also seems to be an emerging consensus
that the propensity to punish harmful behavior is stronger than the propensity to
reward friendly behavior (Offerman, 1999; Charness and Rabin, 2000). There
is, however, disagreement regarding the main sources of reciprocal behavior.
Some believe that the desire to maintain equity is most important (Bolton and
Ockenfels, forthcoming). Others emphasize that the desire to punish hostile
intentions and to reward kind intentions is also important (Rabin, 1993; Blount, 1995;
Dufwenberg and Kirchsteiger, 1999; Falk and Fischbacher, 1999). A third possibility
1

The only exception is the study of Henrich (forthcoming) among the Machiguenga in the Peruvian
Amazon. Machiguengas exhibit very low rejection rates.

Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity

163

is that people do not respond to the intention but to the type of person they face
(Levine, 1998). A fourth group of researchers, in contrast, views the reciprocal
actions in laboratory experiments as a form of boundedly rational behavior (Gale,
Binmore and Samuelson, 1995; Roth and Erev, 1995). However, differences in
interpretation notwithstanding, many researchers now agree that reciprocity is a
rather stable behavioral response by a nonnegligible fraction of the people that can
be reliably elicited under appropriate circumstances.2
In our view, this stability and reliability renders reciprocity important for
economics and raises exciting questions: How do reciprocal types change the
nature of collective action problems that permeate peoples interactions in firms,
public bureaucracies, markets and the political sphere? To what extent can reciprocal people constrain the opportunistic tendencies of selfish people? Which
institutions render the reciprocal types decisive in shaping aggregate social phenomena and when are the selfish types pivotal? How does the presence of reciprocal types change organizational outcomes, contractual and institutional choices,
and the interactions in competitive markets? How do explicit economic incentives
affect the propensity for voluntary cooperation among the reciprocal people? Do
explicit incentives crowd out or enhance voluntary cooperation? In the rest of this
paper, we offer answers to these questions.

Public Goods
Many societies face the problem of how to provide public goods. For a group
of self-interested agents, of course, public goods present the difficulty that since all
agents will want to be free riders on the efforts of others, no agent will contribute
willingly to the public good.
To take a specific example of this situation, consider the basic structure of a
public good experiment run by Fehr and Gachter (forthcoming). In this experiment, there are four group members who are each given 20 tokens. All four
subjects decide simultaneously how many tokens to keep for themselves and how
many tokens to invest in a common public good project. For each token that is
privately kept by a subject, that subject earns exactly one token. For each token a
subject invests into the project each of the four subjects, whether they have invested
in the public good or not, earns .4 tokens. Thus, the private return for investing one
additional token into the public good is .4 tokens while the social return is 1.6
tokens. Since the cost of investing one token is exactly one token while the private
return is only .4 tokens, it is always in the material self-interest of a subject to keep
all tokens. Yet, if all group members keep all tokens privately, each subject earns
only 20 tokens, while if all invest their total endowment in the public good, each
2

The stability of reciprocal behavior suggests that it has deep evolutionary roots. For evolutionary
explanations see Guth and Yaari (1992); Bowles and Gintis (1999); Sethi and Somananthan (2000); and
Gintis (forthcoming).

164

Journal of Economic Perspectives

subject earns 32 tokens. Thus, in this simple example, the highest level of social
welfare would be achieved if everyone contributed all of their assets to the public
good, but it is in the self-interest of each individual to free ride, regardless of what
others contribute, and to contribute nothing.3
To what extent can reciprocity provide the basis for agents deciding to make
at least some contribution to the public good? Positive reciprocity implies that
subjects are willing to contribute something to the public good if others are also
willing to contribute, because a contribution to the public good represents a kind
action, which induces reciprocally motivated people to contribute, too (Sugden,
1984; Keser and van Winden, forthcoming). However, to sustain contributing to the
public good as a stable behavioral regularity, a sufficiently high proportion of the
agents in the game have to be reciprocally motivated. Since we know that a
nonnegligible minority of subjects is motivated by pure self-interest, not reciprocity,
it is unlikely that a positive level of contributions to the public good can be
sustained as an equilibrium.
Up to this point, negative reciprocity has not played a role, because in the
game as described there are no opportunities for direct retaliation in response to
observed free riding. However, negative reciprocity can play the role that if subjects
expect that others free ride, and if they interpret that as a hostile act, then they can
punish others by free riding, too. The result is likely to be that self-interested types
choose to free ride because they are self-interested, and reciprocal types free ride
because they observe others free riding. Although the motivation to free ride is
different for the reciprocal type, in the end the behavior of the selfish and the
reciprocal type is indistinguishable. This public good game provides, therefore, an
example where selfish types can induce reciprocal types to make selfish choices.4
However, the impact of negative reciprocity changes radically if subjects are
given the opportunity to observe the contributions of others, and to punish those
who do not contribute. Suppose, for example, that each subject in a group has the
opportunity to reduce the income of each other subject in the group. Suppose
further, that a reduction of the income of one other group member by x tokens
costs the punisher (1/3)x tokens. It is important that punishment be costly to the
agent who imposes it. After all, if punishing is costly for the punisher, selfish
subjects will never punish. Hence, if all subjects were purely self-interested, contribution decisions would be unaffected by the punishment opportunity. However,
negatively reciprocal subjects, who are willing to pay a price to act reciprocally, will
use the costly punishment opportunity to punish free riders. This, in turn, will
induce self-interested subjects to contribute to avoid the punishment. The public
good game with direct punishment opportunities provides, therefore, an example
where the reciprocal types can induce the selfish types to make cooperative

For a survey on public goods experiments, see Ledyard (1995).


Fehr and Schmidt (1999, Proposition 4) provide a formal proof of these arguments. They show that
even a small minority of purely selfish subjects can induce the reciprocal subjects to behave selfishly
in this game.
4

Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

165

choices. Fehr and Schmidt (1999, Proposition 5) show theoretically that even a
minority of reciprocal subjects is capable of inducing a majority of selfish subjects to
cooperate in these circumstances.
Fehr and Gachter (forthcoming) have conducted a variety of public good
experiments with and without punishment opportunities, using the basic structure
of the four-person, 20-token public good game just described.5 The experiment was
conducted in two versions: a Perfect Stranger version and a Partner version. In an
experimental session of the Perfect Stranger version, 24 subjects formed six groups
with four members in each group. The public good games were repeated for six
periods and in each period completely new groups were formed so that nobody met
another group member more than once. The Perfect Stranger version ensures that
the actions in a particular period have no rewards in future periods. In contrast, in
the Partner version the same four members played ten times.6 In this version there
are possible strategic spillovers across periods so that present actions can have
future returns. However, as in the Perfect Stranger version, all subjects knew the
total number of periods in advance.
Figure 1 shows how much a subject is punished for a given negative
deviation from the average contribution of other members in the group. The
punishment is measured by the average percentage reduction in the incomes of
the punished subject. It turns out that the negative deviation from others
average contributions to the public good is a strong determinant of punishment. The more a subject free rides relative to the others the more it gets
punished. Moreover, this pattern is almost the same in the two versions of the
game: Free riders are punished irrespective of whether there are future rewards
for the punisher. Questionnaire evidence that elicits subjects motives and
emotions indicates that the deviation from the norm of cooperation causes
resentment and the impulse to punish.7
The heavy punishment of free riders, in turn, has a large disciplining effect on
subjects cooperation behavior, as indicated in Figure 2. This figure compares the
time paths of the average contributions in the two versions of the public good
game. The first observation is that in the absence of a punishment opportunity,
average cooperation converges to very low levels in the later periods. For instance,
in period six of the Perfect Stranger version, 79 percent of the subjects free ride
completely and the rest contributes little. This high defection rate stands in sharp
contrast to the contribution behavior in the games with a punishment opportunity:
When subjects are perfect strangers they can at least stabilize contributions at

For an exciting experiment with punishment opportunities in a common pool resource context, see
Ostrom, Walker and Gardner (1992).
6
In the Partner and the Perfect Stranger version, experiments with and without the punishment
opportunity were conducted and all interactions were completely anonymous. In the presence of the
punishment opportunity, subjects could punish in each period after they observed others contributions
in this period.
7
On the role of emotions in similar contexts, see also the experimental study by Bosman and van
Winden (1999).

166

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 1
Mean Income Reduction for a Given Negative Deviation from the Mean Contribution of Other Group Members

Source: Fehr and Gachter (forthcoming).

relatively high levels. In the Partner version they almost converge to the maximum
level of contributions. It is particularly remarkable that in the final period of the
Partner version subjects still contribute 90 percent of the endowment (of 20
tokens), indicating the disciplining force of the punishment opportunity.

From Public Goods to Social Norms


The problem of public goods may seem a rather limited economic application,
and it may seem farfetched to link the experiment here to government spending on
basic research and development or national defense. While we believe that such
links can be made, we readily concede that the most important applications of this
line of thought are not found in government budget decisions. Instead, we believe
that the analytical structure of the public good problem is a good approximation to
the question of how social norms are established and maintained.
At this point, it is useful to define a social norm more precisely. It is: 1) a
behavioral regularity; that is 2) based on a socially shared belief of how one ought to
behave; which triggers 3) the enforcement of the prescribed behavior by informal
social sanctions. Thus, a social norm can be thought of as a sort of behavioral public
good, in which everybody should make a positive contributionthat is, follow the
social normand also where individuals must be willing to enforce the social norm
with informal social sanctions, even at some immediate cost to themselves.
Casual evidence and daily experience suggests that social norms are pervasive
in social and economic life. The large majority of interactions in peoples lives take

Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity

167

Figure 2
Evolution of Average Contributions with and without the Punishment Option in the
Partner and the Perfect Stranger Condition

Source: Fehr and Gachter (forthcoming).

place in the family, in residential neighborhoods, in formal or informal clubs and


at peoples workplaces. Typically, these interactions are not regulated by explicit
contracts but by informal social norms.
For example, it has been observed in many studies that social norms influence
work morale and behavior against rate busters (Roethlisberger and Dickson,
1947). Social sanctions by peer members are probably a very important determinant of effort behavior in work relations. It has often been observed that consumption and savings decisions are to a large degree affected by social norms that
determine what others regard as appropriate consumption. Norm-governed attitudes, social interactions and conformism among peers, relatives, and in neighborhoods may have important consequences for human capital decisions, for the
decision to take part in elections, and for criminal activities. Social norms also often
regulate the use of common pool resources (Ostrom, 1998) and the ways landowners settle disputes (Ellickson, 1994). There is a huge literature that argues that in
collective action problems and in the provision of public goods, social norms play
a decisive role (Elster, 1989; Ostrom, 1998). There is also reason to believe that
social norms are relevant for the amount of tax evasion and the abuse of welfare
payments, and for attitudes towards the welfare state in general. Social norms also
constitute perhaps one of the most important elements of what recently has been
termed social capitalthe informal cooperative infrastructure of our societies.
Finally, there are powerful arguments that social norms also have a decisive impact
on the functioning of markets. Solow (1990), for instance, has argued that they can
lead to involuntary unemployment. The above examples also indicate that social

168

Journal of Economic Perspectives

norms are not necessarily beneficial for society. Depending on the specific context
of the norm, norms may deter or encourage socially beneficial behavior.
In our view, there can be little doubt that human behavior is shaped by social
norms. They constitute constraints on individual behavior beyond the legal, information and budget constraints usually considered by economists. In view of the fact
that most social relations in neighborhoods, families and work places are not
governed by explicit agreements but by social norms, the role of reciprocity as a
norm enforcement device is perhaps its most important function.

Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device


Real-world contracts are often highly incomplete, which gives rise to strong
incentives to shirk (Williamson, 1985). Economic historians like North (1990) have
argued that differences in societies contract enforcement capabilities are probably
a major reason for differences in economic growth and human welfare.
The employment relationship, in particular, is characterized by incomplete
contracts. Labor contracts often take the form of a fixed wage contract without
explicit performance incentives and in which workers have a considerable degree
of discretion over effort levels. In such a situation, a workers general job attitude,
loyalty (Simon, 1991), or what Williamson (1985) called consummate cooperation, which is an affirmative job attitude whereby gaps are filled, initiative is taken,
and judgment is exercised in an instrumental way, becomes important. Under a
complete labor contract, of course, a generally cooperative job attitude would be
superfluous, because all relevant actions would be unambiguously described and
enforceable. But how can any explicit contract unambiguously describe, assess, and
enforce terms like initiative, good judgment and potentially arising gaps?
The requirement of a generally cooperative job attitude renders reciprocal
motivations potentially very important in the labor process. If a substantial fraction
of the work force is motivated by reciprocity considerations, employers can affect
the degree of cooperativeness of workers by varying the generosity of the compensation package even without offering explicit performance incentives.
The conjecture that reciprocity plays a role in the choice of effort has been
investigated in several tightly controlled laboratory experiments. For example, in Fehr,
Gachter and Kirchsteiger (1997), experimental employers could offer a wage contract
that stipulated a binding wage w and a desired effort level e. If an experimental worker
accepted this offer, the worker was free to choose the actual effort level e between a
minimum and a maximum level. The employer always had to pay the offered wage
irrespective of the actual effort level. In this experiment effort is represented by a
number e between 1 and 10. Higher numbers represent higher effort levels and,
hence, a higher profit for the employer and higher effort costs c(e) for the worker.
The effort cost for e 1 was zero. The profit from the employment of a worker
was given by 10e w and the monetary payoff for the experimental worker was
u w c(e). In each experimental session there were eight workers and six

Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

169

employers, who could employ at most one worker. All participants knew the excess
supply of workers. It ensured that a workers reservation wage, if the worker is purely
selfish, was zero so that employers could, in principle, enforce very low wages. The
crucial point in this experiment is that selfish workers have no incentives to provide
effort above the minimum level e 1. The question, therefore, is to what extent
experimental employers do appeal to workers reciprocity by offering generous compensation packages and to what extent workers honor generous offers.
It turns out that many employers indeed make quite generous offers. On
average, the offered contracts stipulate a desired effort of e 7 and the offered
wage implied that the worker receives 44 percent of the total surplus u .
Interestingly, many workers honor this generosity somewhat but not fully. The
actual average effort is given by e 4.4, which was substantially above the selfish
choice of e 1. However, only in 14 percent of all cases workers abide by the
terms of the contract, while in 83 percent of all cases they shirk. Still, in 74 percent
of all instances of shirking they do not shirk fully. Thus, although shirking is still
quite prevalent in this situation the evidence suggests that in response to generous
job offers, people are on average willing to put forward extra effort above what is
implied by purely pecuniary considerations.
A large interview study conducted by Bewley (1995, 1999) provides field
evidence supporting this view. The managers who were interviewed stress that
workers have so many opportunities to take advantage of employers that it is not
wise to depend on coercion and financial incentives alone as motivators. . . . Employers believe that other motivators are necessary, which are best thought of as
having to do with generosity (Bewley, 1995, p. 252).
In the situation described above, only workers can react reciprocally while
employers cannot. Employers can only try to elicit reciprocal effort choices from
the workers. Yet, what happens if employers can also respond reciprocally by
rewarding or punishing workers after they observe actual effort choices? This
question is examined as well in Fehr, Gachter and Kirchsteiger (1997). In this
experiment everything is kept identical to the previous experiment, except that
employers could now reward or punish the workers after the effort decision is
revealed. For every token spent on rewards they could raise the workers monetary
income by 2.5 tokens (reflecting the possible higher marginal utility of income for
workers in reality). Likewise, for every token spent on punishment, they could
reduce the workers income by 2.5 tokens. Since rewarding and punishing is costly,
a selfish employer will never reward or punish. Hence, the reward and punishment
opportunity is irrelevant according to the self-interest model.
If workers shirked in the experiments, however, employers punished in 68
percent of these cases. If there was overprovision, employers rewarded in 70
percent of these cases. If workers exactly met the desired effort, employers still
rewarded in 41 percent of the cases. As a consequence, workers chose much
higher effort levels when employers have a reward/punishment opportunity. Indeed,
although in these experiments the average desired effort level is slightly higher than in
the previous experiment, the shirking rate declined from 83 percent to 26 percent. In

170

Journal of Economic Perspectives

38 percent of the cases, workers even provided a higher effort than requested. An
important consequence of this increase in average effort was that the aggregate
monetary payoff increased by 40 percent even if one takes the payoff reductions that
result from actual punishments into account.
This evidence strongly suggests that reciprocity substantially contributes to the
enforcement of contracts. The power of reciprocity derives from the fact that it
provides incentives for the potential cheaters to behave cooperatively or at least to
limit their degree of noncooperation. In the above experiments, for example, even
purely selfish employers have an incentive to make a generous job offer, if they
expect sufficiently many workers to behave in a reciprocal manner. Similarly, even
purely selfish workers have an incentive to provide a high effort in case of a
reward/punishment opportunity, if they expect that sufficiently many employers
respond reciprocally to their effort choices.

Work Motivation and Performance Incentives


The previous experiments focus on fairness and reciprocity as a means to enforce
contracts. In reality, material incentives are, of course, also used to mitigate the
enforcement problem. The question, therefore, arises, how explicit material incentives
to abide by the terms of the contract interact with motivations of fairness and reciprocity. One possibility is that reciprocity gives rise to extra effort on top of what is enforced
by material incentives alone. However, it is also possible that explicit incentives may
cause a hostile atmosphere of threat and distrust, which reduces any reciprocity-based
extra effort. Bewley (1995, p. 252), for example, reports that many managers stress that
explicit punishment should be rarely used as a way to obtain co-operation because of
the negative effects on work atmosphere.
In a new series of experiments, Fehr and Gachter (2000) examine this possibility. They implement a control treatment that is identical to the previous contract
enforcement experiment without reward and punishment opportunities. Remember that in this treatment there are no material incentives. In addition, they also
implement a treatment with explicit performance incentives. This treatment keeps
everything constant relative to the control treatment, except that employers now
have the possibility to stipulate a fine, to be paid by the worker to the employer in
case of verified shirking. The probability of verification is .33 and the fine is
restricted to an interval between zero and a maximal fine. The maximal fine is fixed
at a level such that a selfish risk-neutral worker will choose an effort level of 4 when
faced with this fine.8
The line with the black dots in Figure 3 shows workers effort behavior in the
control treatment. It depicts the average effort on the vertical axis as a function of
8

To prevent hostility from being introduced merely by the use of value-laden terms we avoided terms
like fine, performance, and so on. Instead we used a rather neutral language like, for example, price
deduction.

Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity

171

Figure 3
Actual Effort-Rent Relation in the Absence and Presence of Explicit Performance
Incentives

Source: Fehr and Gachter (forthcoming).

the rent offered to the workers. The offered rent is implied by the original contract
offer; it is defined as the wage minus the cost of providing the desired effort level.
Due to the presence of many reciprocal workers, the average effort level is strongly
increasing in the offered rent and rises far above the selfish level of e 1. The line
with the white dots in Figure 3 shows the relationship of rent to effort in the
presence of the explicit performance incentive. Except at the low rent levels, the
average effort is lower in the presence of the explicit incentives!
This result suggests that reciprocity-based effort elicitation and explicit performance incentives may indeed be in conflict with each other. In particular, explicit
incentives may crowd out reciprocal effort choices. In the experiments of Fehr
and Gachter (2000), the average effort taken over all trades and, hence, the
aggregate monetary surplus, is lower in the incentive treatment than in the control
treatment. However, employers profits are higher because in the incentive treatment they rely much less on the carrot of generous wage offers. Instead, they
threaten the maximal fine in most cases. For the employers, the savings in wage
costs more than offset the reductions in revenues that are caused by the lower effort
in the incentive treatment. However, while the wage savings merely represent a
transfer from the workers to the firms, the reduction in effort levels reduces the
aggregate surplus. This shows that, in the presence of reciprocal types, efficiency
questions and questions of distribution are inseparable. Since the perceived fairness of the distribution of the gains from trade affects the effort behavior of the
reciprocal types, different distributions are associated with different levels of the
aggregate gains. Thus, lump-sum transfers between trading parties have allocative
consequences.
Our crowding out result may seem counterintuitive, since it is almost axiom-

172

Journal of Economic Perspectives

atic to some economists that material incentives should produce a better outcome.
However, this position neglects the existence of reciprocity-based voluntary cooperation. Similar problems with explicit incentives are obtained in the experiments
of Gneezy and Rustichini (forthcoming) and Bohnet, Frey and Huck (1999)
explicit material incentives may have counterproductive effects. These results, of
course, do not provide a general case against the use of explicit incentives.9 In some
cases, there is evidence that explicit incentives can leave voluntary cooperation
intact (for example, Guth, Klose, Konigstein and Schwalbach, 1998). In particular,
notice that the incentive devices discussed here involved punishments and it may
well be that reward-based explicit incentives do not destroy reciprocal inclinations,
or may even strengthen them. However, the results do indicate that in the presence
of reciprocity-based voluntary cooperation, the task of providing explicit incentives
is considerably more complicated than envisaged by standard principal-agent theory.

Wage Rigidity, Rent-Sharing and Competition


In a seminal paper, Akerlof (1982) argued that labor markets are characterized
by considerations of gift exchange, by which he meant that employers offer a gift
of pay which is more than labors opportunity cost and employees offer a gift of
more than minimal effort. This exchange may explain why employers are reluctant
to cut wages in a recession, as found by many researchers (see Bewley, 1999, and the
references therein). The reason is that wage cuts may decrease productivity. In
addition, the gift exchange notion implies that, ceteris paribus, more profitable
firms pay on average higher wages. Higher profitability is likely to be associated with
a higher marginal product of effort. Therefore, the return of a given effort increase
is higher and employers have an incentive to pay higher wages.
The fact that the presence of reciprocal types in the labor market gives rise to
downward wage rigidity has been demonstrated in a number of experiments. In the
following we draw on Fehr and Falk (1999), because they confirmed the existence
of downward wage rigidity in a version of the most competitive environmentthe
competitive double auction. In this environment, both experimental firms and
workers can make wage bids. A large body of research has shown the striking
competitive properties of experimental double auctions. In hundreds of such
experiments, prices and quantities quickly converged to the competitive equilibrium predicted by standard self-interest theory (Holt, 1995, presents a survey of
important results). Therefore, showing that reciprocity causes wage rigidity in a
double auction provides a strong piece of evidence in favor of the importance of
reciprocity in markets.

There exists a large psychological literature on the crowding out of intrinsic motivation by explicit
rewards (Deci and Ryan, 1985). For applications of intrinsic motivation theory to economics, see Frey
(1997). There are, however, considerable differences between the literature discussed above and the
psychological studies on crowding out (Fehr and Gachter, 2000).

Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

173

Fehr and Falk (1999) carried out a series of double auction experiments set in
the context of a labor market. Both experimental firms and experimental workers
could make wage bids. If a bid was accepted, a labor contract was concluded. There
were eight firms and twelve workers and each firm could employ at most one
worker. A worker who concluded a contract had costs of 20. Therefore, due to the
excess supply of labor, the competitive wage level was 20. Within this broader
context, Fehr and Falk (1999) considered two treatment conditions: one condition
in which the labor contract was complete because the experimenter enforced a
given effort level; and one where the labor contract was incomplete because
employees could choose an effort level between a minimum and maximum after
the wage contract was concluded, and the employers could neither stipulate nor
enforce an effort level above the minimum level.10
The time path of the average wage in a typical double auction with incomplete
contracts is shown in Figure 4a. Figure 4b shows average wages in a typical double
auction with complete contracts. In addition, both figures show workers wage bids.
Clearly, wage levels are radically different in the two conditions. In the market with
complete contracts, employers take full advantage of the low wage offers made by
the workers and, as a consequence, wages are close to the competitive level in this
market. In contrast, in the market with incomplete contracts employers are very
reluctant to accept workers underbidding of prevailing wages. From period 4
onwards, wages move even further away from the competitive level despite fierce
competition among workers for scarce jobs. The data analysis in Fehr and Falk
(1999) shows that employers high wage policy in the market with incomplete
contracts was quite rational, because in this way they could sustain higher effort
levels and increase profits relative to a low wage policy.
The big difference in the impact of reciprocity on wage formation in markets
with complete and incomplete contracts illustrates again the importance of institutional details. In the incomplete contracts condition, a reciprocal worker can
punish the firm by choosing a low effort level after the labor contract has been
concluded. Since firms anticipate this possibility, they have a reason to pay generous wages. In contrast, in the complete contracts condition, the only method for a
worker to punish a firm who offers a low wage is to reject such an offer. However,
due to the presence of a certain proportion of purely self-interested workers, the
reciprocal worker knows that others will accept low wage offers. Thus, reciprocal
workers have, in fact, no possibility to punish firmswhich induces them to accept
low wage offers, too. Since firms anticipate or notice this willingness to accept low
offers, they have no reason to offer generous wages. Thus, the ability to punish is

10

One double auction lasted for ten periods and a period lasted for three minutes. In each period the
same stationary situation was implemented; that is, there were twelve workers, eight firms, and each
workers reservation wage was 20. In a given period, employers and workers could make as many wage
bids as they liked, as long as they had not yet concluded a contract. In the condition with incomplete
contracts, workers had to choose an effort between a minimum and a maximum level after they had
concluded a contract.

174

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 4a
Workers Offers and Mean Contract Wages in the Double Auction Market with
Incomplete Contracts

Figure 4b
Workers Offers and Mean Contract Wages in the Double Auction Market with
Complete Contracts

Source: Fehr and Falk (1999).

Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity

175

an institutional detail that means that reciprocity will have a very different impact
on wage formation in the two conditions. Fehr and Schmidt (1999) provide a
rigorous derivation of this argument.
A variety of studies have found that one major reason why managers are
reluctant to cut wages in a recession is the fear that wage cuts may inhibit work
performance. Among others, Bewley (1999) reports that managers are afraid that
pay cuts express hostility to the work force and will be interpreted as an insult.
A comparison of wage levels in Figure 4a and 4b shows that workers earn rents
in the market with incomplete contracts. The existence of rents is also indicated by
the many wage bids below the prevailing wage level in Figure 4a. This raises two
questions: 1) Does reciprocity also cause a reduction in employment if employers
can hire more than one worker? 2) Do the rents vary systematically with firms
profitability? In a recent paper, Falk and Fehr (2000) addressed the first question.
They show that firms indeed reduce employment in response to workers reciprocity. The second question is examined in Fehr, Gachter and Kirchsteiger (1996) who
conducted competitive market experiments in which experimental firms differed
according to their profit opportunities. They found a clear positive correlation
between firms profit opportunities and the rents paid to workers.
This result is compatible with empirical evidence on rent-sharing in real
companies. For example, Blanchflower, Oswald and Sanfey (1996) show that there
is a positive relation between long-run wages and the profitability of nonunionized
companies or nonunionized industries, respectively. Also, Krueger and Summers
(1987), for instance, have shown that estimated industry wage differentials are
positively correlated in a cross section with industry profitability. Such findings are
not consistent with competitive theories of the labor market, because in those
theories, firms should pay no more than the opportunity cost of wages, and there
is no reason that the profit opportunities of a certain firm should affect those
market-determined opportunity costs. However, this finding is predicted by rentsharing theories of the labor market based on the presence of reciprocal agents in
the market.
The combination of the findings of laboratory studies on rent-sharing and the
field evidence on rent-sharing suggests that rent-sharing theories have explanatory
power. The laboratory results have the advantage that they unambiguously show the
existence of profit-related job rents, due to their ability to control fully for other
factors like unobservable heterogeneity in working conditions or skill levels. Such
factors can create havoc in interpreting the results of real world studies of wage
differentials (for example, Gibbons and Katz, 1992). In addition, the laboratory
approach allows for the isolation of the gift-exchange mechanism as a cause for
noncompensating wage differentials. The disadvantage of the laboratory data is
that further assumptions are necessary to render the results relevant for real labor
markets. This comparison illustrates that field and laboratory studies should be
viewed as complementary methods of economic exploration.

176

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Foundations of Incomplete Contracts


Standard principal-agent models predict that contracts should be made contingent on all verifiable measures that are informative with regard to the agents
effort. But in reality, we often observe highly incomplete contracts. For example, as
noted earlier, wages are often paid without explicit performance incentives. To this
point, the discussion has focused on demonstrating that reciprocity has powerful
economic effects in situations where contracts are incomplete.
This section seeks to explore the underlying causes for the prevalence of
incomplete contracts in the first place. One common explanation for the absence
of explicit incentives is that when employees are expected to carry out multiple
tasks or when the measures of effort and performance are distorted in some way,
providing powerful incentives will induce agents to focus too much on what is being
measured and not enough on the other dimensions and tasks of the job (Holmstrom and Milgrom, 1991). This line of explanation certainly has some truth in it.
However, our aim here is to show that the presence of reciprocal types is an
independent source of the absence of explicit incentives.
To study the impact of reciprocity on contractual choices, Fehr, Klein and
Schmidt (2000) conducted an experiment in which principals had the choice
between an explicit contract and an implicit, less complete, contract. In a typical
session of this experiment, there are 12 principals and 12 agents who play for ten
periods. In each of the ten periods, an employer faces a different principal, which
ensures that all matches are one-shot. A period consists of three stages. At stage one
of a period, the principal has to decide whether to offer the agent an implicit or an
explicit contract. The implicit contract specifies a fixed wage and a desired effort
level (where effort choices can range from one to ten). In addition, the principal
can promise a bonus that may be paid after actual effort has been observed. In the
implicit contract, there is no contractual obligation to pay the announced bonus,
nor is the agent obliged to choose the desired effort level. The principal is,
however, committed to pay the wage. An explicit contract also specifies a binding
fixed wage and a desired effort level between one and ten. Here, however, the
principal can impose a fine on the agent that has to be paid to the principal in case
of verifiable shirking. Except for one detail, the explicit contract is identical to the
performance contract discussed above in the context of crowding out of reciprocity. The difference concerns the fact that the choice of the explicit contract
involves fixed verification cost. This reflects the fact that the verification of effort is,
in general, costly. Note that the implicit contract does not require third-party
verification of effort. It is only necessary that effort is observable by the principal.11
The explicit contract is more complete than the implicit contract, because in the
explicit contract the employer conditions the fine on the actual effort level in a

11

Employers are, in general, not free to cut a workers wage for shirking but they have little legal
problem when they refuse to pay a promised bonus.

Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

177

credible manner, while in the implicit contract, no such credible commitments are
possible.
At stage two, the agent observes which contract has been offered and decides
whether to accept or reject the offer. If the agent rejects the offer, the game ends
and both parties get a payoff of zero. If the agent accepts, the next step is for the
agent to choose an actual level of effort between one and ten.
At stage three, the principal observes the actual effort level. If the principal has
offered an implicit contract, the next decision is whether to award the bonus
payment to the agent. If the principal offered an explicit contract and if the agents
effort falls short of the agreed effort, a random draw decides with probability of
one-third whether shirking is verifiable, in which case the agent has to pay the fine.
If all players have purely selfish preferences, the analysis of this game is
straightforward. A selfish principal would never pay a bonus. Anticipating this,
there is no incentive for the agent to spend more than the minimum effort. If the
principal chooses the explicit contract, the principal should go for the maximum
punishment because this is the best deterrence for potential shirkers. The parameters of the experiment are chosen such that a risk-neutral and selfish agent
maximizes expected utility by choosing an effort level of four if faced with the
maximum fine. Since the enforceable effort level is four under the explicit contract
while it is only one under an implicit contract, the self-interest model predicts that
principals prefer the explicit contract.
The experimental evidence is completely at odds with these predictions. In
total, the implicit contract was chosen in 88 percent of the cases. In view of the
relative profitability of the different contracts, the popularity of the implicit contract is not surprising. Those principals who chose the explicit contract made an
average loss of nine tokens per contract, while those who chose the implicit
contract made an average profit of 26 tokens per contract. Since the fixed verification cost in the explicit contract was ten tokens, the explicit contract would have
been much less profitable even in the absence of these costs. For both contracts, the
average income of the agents was roughly 18 tokens. Implicit contracts were more
profitable because contrary to the standard predictionthey induced much
higher effort levels. The effort level in the implicit contract was 5.2 on average (on
a scale of one to ten), while the effort level in the explicit contract was 2.1 on
average.
How did implicit contracts induce effort levels so much higher than expected?
A major reason is that in the presence of reciprocal principals, the promised bonus
does not merely represent cheap talk, because reciprocal principals canand
actually do condition the bonus payment on the effort level. The average data
clearly reflect this impact of the reciprocal types because the actual average bonus
rises steeply with the actual effort level. The principals capability to commit to
paying a conditional bonus is based on their reciprocal inclinations. Conditional
bonus payments, in turn, provide a strong pecuniary incentive for the agents to
perform as desired by the principals. Why did explicit contracts induce effort levels
lower than expected? A likely reason is that these contracts crowd out positive

178

Journal of Economic Perspectives

reciprocity, and perhaps even induce negative reciprocity, as shown in the section
on work motivation above.
One also might conjecture that the preference for implicit contracts in this
particular experiment is caused by the fact that the explicit contract involves a
punishment while the implicit contract involves a reward. However, further experiments in Fehr, Klein and Schmidt (2000) cast doubt on this explanation. If the
above-described implicit contract competes with a piece rate contract, the vast
majority of principals still prefer the implicit contract.
The endogenous formation of incomplete contracts through reciprocal
choices shows that reciprocity may not only cause substantial changes in the
functioning of given economic institutions but that it also may have a powerful
impact on the selection and formation of institutions. To provide a further example: The present theory of property rights predicts that joint ownership will in
general severely inhibit relation-specific investments, so that it emerges only under
very restrictive conditions (Hart, 1995). This may no longer be true in the presence
of reciprocal actors who are willing to cooperate if they expect the trading partner
to cooperate as well, and who are willing to punish even at a cost to themselves.

Concluding Remarks
The assumption that economic agents make their decisions based on pure
self-interest has served economists well in many areas. In situations where contracts
are reasonably complete, the underlying assumption of self-interest should continue to be especially important. However, the self-interest model has also failed to
give satisfactory explanations for a wide variety of questions of interest to economists, including questions about labor market interactions, public goods, and social
norms. We believe that for important questions in these areas, progress will not
come from additional tweaking of a pure self-interest model, but rather from
recognizing that a sizeable proportion of economic actors act on considerations of
reciprocity.
In view of the powerful implications of reciprocity, it is also important to know
why a sizeable fraction of the people have reciprocal inclinations. Which factors in
the evolution of the human species have contributed to this? Which social and
economic conditions produce the propensity to reciprocate? There are now several
evolutionary models (see footnote 3) that provide answers to this question. At the
empirical level, however, little is known.

y This paper is part of the MacArthur Foundation Network on Economic Environments and
the Evolution of Individual Preferences and Social Norms. Some research reported in this paper
has also been funded by the EU-TMR research network ENDEAR (FMRX-CT98-0238). We
are grateful for helpful comments by Alan Krueger, Timothy Taylor and J. Bradford De Long,
as well as by Ken Binmore, Iris Bohnet, Terence Burnham, Colin Camerer, Gary Charness,
Jim Cox, Vince Crawford, Armin Falk, Urs Fischbacher, Diego Gambetta, Robert Gibbons,

Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity

179

Herbert Gintis, Felix Oberholzer, Larry Samuelson, Rajiv Sethi, Herbert Simon, Vernon Smith
and Frans van Winden. We regret thatin view of the very large number of comments we
receivedwe could not do justice to all of them.

References
Abbink, Klaus, Bernd Irlenbusch and Elke
Renner. 2000. The Moonlighting Game. An Experimental Study on Reciprocity and Retribution. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 42:2, pp. 265-77.
Akerlof, George. 1982. Labor Contracts as
Partial Gift Exchange. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 97, pp. 543-69.
Arrow, Kenneth. 1980. Discrimination in the
Labour Market, in J.E. King, ed. Readings in
Labour Economics. Oxford: Oxford University
Press.
Berg, Joyce, John Dickhaut and Kevin McCabe. 1995. Trust, Reciprocity and Social History. Games and Economic Behavior. 10, pp. 12242.
Bewley, Truman. 1995. A Depressed Labor
Market as Explained by Participants. American
Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings. 85, pp.
250-54.
Bewley, Truman. 2000. Why Wages Dont Fall
During a Recession. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Blanchflower, David, Andrew Oswald and Peter Sanfey. 1996. Wages, Profits, and Rent-Sharing. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 111:2, pp.
227-52.
Blount, Sally. 1995. When Social Outcomes
arent Fair: The Effect of Causal Attributions on
Preferences. Organizational Behavior and Human
Decision Processes. 63, pp. 131-44.
Bohnet, Iris, Bruno Frey and Steffen Huck.
1999. More Order with Less Law: On Contract
Enforcement, Trust, and Crowding, mimeo,
Harvard University.
Bolton, Gary and Axel Ockenfels. Forthcoming. ERC - A Theory of Equity, Reciprocity, and
Competition. American Economic Review.
Bosman, Ronald and Frans van Winden. 1999.
The Behavioral Impact of Emotions in a Powerto-Take Game: An Experimental Study,
CREED/Tinbergen Institute working paper,
Amsterdam.

Bowles, Samuel and Herbert Gintis. 1998. Is


Equality Passe? Boston Review. December/January, 23:6.
Bowles, Samuel and Herbert Gintis. 1999.
The Evolution of Strong Reciprocity, mimeo,
University of Massachusetts.
Burnham, Terence. 1999. Testosterone and
Negotiations, mimeo, John F. Kennedy School
of Government, Harvard University.
Camerer, Colin and Richard Thaler. 1995.
Anomalies: Ultimatums, Dictators and Manners. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 9:2, pp. 20919.
Cameron, Lisa. 1999. Raising the Stakes in the
Ultimatum Game: Experimental Evidence from
Indonesia. Economic Inquiry. 37:1, pp. 47-59.
Charness, Gary and Matthew Rabin. 2000. Social Preferences: Some Simple Tests and a New
Model, mimeo, University of Berkeley.
Cialdini, Robert. 1993. InfluenceThe Psychology
of Persuasion. New York: Quill William Morrow.
Deci, Edward and Richard Ryan. 1985. Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behavior. New York and London: Plenum Press.
Dufwenberg, Martin and Georg Kirchsteiger.
1998. A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity,
mimeo, CentER Tilburg.
Ellickson, Robert. 1994. Order without Law
How Neighbors Settle Disputes. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.
Elster, Jon. 1989. The Cement of SocietyA Study
of Social Order. Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press.
Falk, Armin and Ernst Fehr. 2000. Fair Wages
and Unemployment, mimeo, University of Zurich.
Falk, Armin and Urs Fischbacher. 1999. A
Theory of Reciprocity, Working paper No. 6,
Institute for Empirical Research in Economics,
University of Zurich.
Fehr, Ernst and Armin Falk. 1999. Wage Rigidity in a Competitive Incomplete Contract Market.
Journal of Political Economy. 107, pp. 106-34.

180

Journal of Economic Perspectives

Fehr, Ernst and Simon Gachter. Forthcoming.


Cooperation and Punishment in Public Goods
Experiments. American Economic Review.
Fehr, Ernst and Simon Gachter. 2000. Do Incentive Contracts Crowd-Out Voluntary Cooperation? Working paper No 34, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich.
Fehr, Ernst and Klaus Schmidt. 1999. A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation.
Quarterly Journal of Economics. 114, pp. 817-68.
Fehr, Ernst and Elena Tougareva. 1995. Do
High Stakes Remove Reciprocal FairnessEvidence from Russia, discussion paper, University
of Zurich.
Fehr, Ernst, Simon Gachter and Georg Kirchsteiger. 1996. Reciprocal Fairness and Noncompensating Wage Differentials. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. 152:4, pp. 608-40.
Fehr, Ernst, Simon Gachter and Georg Kirchsteiger. 1997. Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device. Econometrica. 65:4, pp. 833-60.
Fehr, Ernst, Georg Kirchsteiger and Arno
Riedl. 1993. Does Fairness Prevent Market
Clearing? An Experimental Investigation. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108:2, pp. 437-60.
Fehr, Ernst, Alexander Klein and Klaus
Schmidt. 2000. Endogenous Incomplete Contracts, mimeo, University of Munich.
Frey, Bruno. 1997. Not Just For the MoneyAn
Economic Theory of Personal Motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Gachter, Simon and Armin Falk. 1999. Reputation or Reciprocity? Working paper No. 19,
Institute for Empirical Research in Economics,
University of Zurich.
Gale, John, Ken Binmore and Larry Samuelson. 1995. Learning to Be Imperfect: The Ultimatum Game. Games and Economic Behavior. 8,
pp. 56-90.
Giacalone, Robert and Jerald Greenberg.
1997. Antisocial Behavior in Organizations. Thousand Oaks: Sage Publications.
Gibbons, Robert and Lawrence Katz. 1992.
Does Unmeasured Ability Explain Inter-Industry Wage Differentials? Review of Economic Studies. 59, p. 515-35.
Gintis, Herbert. Forthcoming. Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality. Journal of Theoretical Biology.
Gneezy, Uri and Aldo Rustichini. Forthcoming. A Fine is a Price. Journal of Legal Studies.
Guth, Werner and Menachem Yaari. 1992.
Explaining Reciprocal Behavior in Simple Strategic Games: An Evolutionary Approach, in Ulrich Witt, ed. Explaining Process and Change: Approaches to Evolutionary Economics. Ann Arbor:
University of Michigan Press.

Guth, Werner, Rolf Schmittberger and Bernd


Schwarze. 1982. An Experimental Analysis of
Ultimatum Bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization. 3:3, pp. 367-88.
Guth, Werner, Wolfgang Klose, Manfred
Konigstein and Joachim Schwalbach. 1998. An
Experimental Study of a Dynamic PrincipalAgent Relationship. Managerial and Decision Economics. 19, pp. 327-41.
Hart, Oliver. 1995. Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Henrich, Joe. Forthcoming. Does Culture
Matter in Economic Behavior? Ultimatum Game
Bargaining among the Machiguenga of the Peruvian Amazon. American Economic Review.
Hoffman, Elizabeth, Kevin McCabe and Vernon Smith. 1996. On Expectations and Monetary Stakes in Ultimatum Games. International
Journal of Game Theory. 25, pp. 289-301.
Holmstrom, Bengt and Paul Milgrom. 1991.
Multi-Task Principal-Agent Analyses: Incentive
Contracts, Asset Ownership and Job-Design. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization. 7, pp. 24-52.
Holt, Charles. 1995. Industrial Organization:
A Survey of Laboratory Research, in Alvin Roth
and John Kagel, eds. Handbook of Experimental
Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Keser, Claudia and Frans van Winden. Forthcoming. Conditional Cooperation and Voluntary Contributions to Public Goods. Scandinavian Journal of Economics.
Krueger, Alan and Lawrence Summers. 1987.
Reflections on the Inter-Industry Wage Structure, in Kevin Lang and Jonathan Leonhard,
eds. Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Markets. New York: Basil Blackwell.
Ledyard, John. 1995. Public Goods: A Survey
of Experimental Research, in Alvin Roth and
John Kagel, eds. Handbook of Experimental Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Levine, David. 1998. Modeling Altruism and
Spitefulness in Experiments. Review of Economic
Dynamics. 1, pp. 593-622.
Lindbeck, Assar, Sten Nyberg and Jorgen
Weibull. 1999. Social Norms and Economic Incentives in the Welfare State. Quarterly Journal of
Economics. 116:1, pp. 1-35.
McCabe, Kevin, Stephen Rassenti and Vernon
Smith. 1996. Game Theory and Reciprocity in
Some Extensive Form Experimental Games.
Proceedings National Academy of Science. 93, pp.
13,421-13,428.
North, Douglass. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Offerman, Theo. 1999. Hurting Hurts More
than Helping Helps: The Role of the Self-Serv-

Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter

ing Bias, mimeo, CREED, University of Amsterdam.


Ostrom, Elinor, James Walker and Roy Gardner. 1992. Covenants with and without a Sword:
Self-Governance is Possible. American Political
Science Review. 86, pp. 404-17.
Ostrom, Elinor. 1998. A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action. American Political Science Review. 92,
pp. 1-22.
Rabin, Matthew. 1993. Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics. American Economic Review. 83:5, pp. 1,281-1,302.
Roethlisberger, F. J. and W. J. Dickson. 1947.
Management and the Worker: An Account of a Research Program Conducted by the Western Electric
Company, Hawthorne Works, Chicago. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press.
Roth, Alvin. 1995. Bargaining Experiments,
in Alvin Roth and John Kagel, eds. Handbook of
Experimental Economics. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Roth, Alvin and Ido Erev. 1995. Learning in
Extensive-Form Games: Experimental Data and
Simple Dynamic Models in the Intermediate
Term. Games and Economic Behavior. 8, pp. 164212.
Roth, Alvin, Vesna Prasnikar, Masahiro
Okuno-Fujiwara and Shmuel Zamir. 1991. Bar-

181

gaining and Market Behavior in Jerusalem,


Ljubljana, Pittsburgh, and Tokyo: An Experimental Study. American Economic Review. 81, pp.
1,068-1,095.
Sethi, Rajiv and E. Somanathan. 2000. Preference Evolution and Reciprocity, mimeo, Columbia University.
Simon, Herbert. 1991. Organizations and
Markets. Journal of Economic Perspectives. Spring,
5:2, pp. 25-44.
Slonim, Robert and Alvin Roth. 1998. Financial Incentives and Learning in Ultimatum and
Market Games: An Experiment in the Slovak
Republic. Econometrica. 66, pp. 569-96.
Solow, Robert. 1990. The Labor Market as a
Social Institution. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
Stigler, George. 1981. Economics or Ethics?
In S. McMurrin, ed. Tanner Lectures on Human
Values. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Sugden, Robert. 1984. Reciprocity: The Supply of Public Goods through Voluntary Contributions. Economic Journal. 84, pp. 772-87.
Tidd, K.L and J.S. Lochard. 1978. Monetary
Significance of the Affiliative Smile: A Case for
Reciprocal Altruism. Bull. Psychonom. Soc. 11,
pp. 344-46.
Williamson, Oliver. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.

182

Journal of Economic Perspectives

This article has been cited by:


1. Akinori Tomohara, Akihiko Ohno. 2016. Domains of reciprocity beyond monetary compensation:
How do non-pecuniary factors affect effort and shirking?. Cogent Economics & Finance 4:1. .
[CrossRef]
2. Niels Vermeer, Mauro Mastrogiacomo, Arthur Van Soest. 2016. Demanding occupations and the
retirement age. Labour Economics 43, 159-170. [CrossRef]
3. Pradeep Kumar, Shashi Kant. 2016. Revealed social preferences and joint forest management
outcomes. Forest Policy and Economics 72, 37-45. [CrossRef]
4. Daphna Motro, Tamar Kugler, Terry Connolly. 2016. Back to the basics: how feelings of anger affect
cooperation. International Journal of Conflict Management 27:4, 523-546. [CrossRef]
5. Chunyan Zhang, Zengqiang Chen. 2016. The public goods game with a new form of shared reward.
Journal of Statistical Mechanics: Theory and Experiment 2016:10, 103201. [CrossRef]
6. Eilidh Cage, Geoffrey Bird, Elizabeth Pellicano. 2016. Reputation Management in Children on the
Autism Spectrum. Journal of Autism and Developmental Disorders . [CrossRef]
7. Stephanie Jimenez, Cynthia Pietras. 2016. A Risk-Reduction Model of Sharing: Role of Social Stimuli
and Inequity. The Psychological Record . [CrossRef]
8. Tone Ognedal. 2016. Morality in the market. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 129,
100-115. [CrossRef]
9. Duncan S. Gilchrist, Michael Luca, Deepak Malhotra. 2016. When 3 + 1 > 4: Gift Structure and
Reciprocity in the Field. Management Science 62:9, 2639-2650. [CrossRef]
10. Lan Guo, Theresa Libby, Xiaotao Kelvin Liu. 2016. The Effects of Vertical Pay Dispersion:
Experimental Evidence in a Budget Setting. Contemporary Accounting Research . [CrossRef]
11. Douglas A. Marshall. 2016. The Moral Origins of God: Darwin, Durkheim, and the Homo Duplex
Theory of Theogenesis. Frontiers in Sociology 1. . [CrossRef]
12. Kun Zhao, Eamonn Ferguson, Luke D. Smillie. 2016. Prosocial Personality Traits Differentially
Predict Egalitarianism, Generosity, and Reciprocity in Economic Games. Frontiers in Psychology 7. .
[CrossRef]
13. Mehmet Ferhat zbek, Mohammad Asif Yoldash, Thomas Li-Ping Tang. 2016. Theory of Justice,
OCB, and Individualism: Kyrgyz Citizens. Journal of Business Ethics 137:2, 365-382. [CrossRef]
14. Carolin Decker. 2016. Stakeholders' Impact on Turnaround Performance: The Case of German
Savings Banks. Journal of Small Business Management . [CrossRef]
15. Jacob Dijkstra, Dieko M. Bakker. 2016. Relative power: Material and contextual elements of efficacy
in social dilemmas. Social Science Research . [CrossRef]
16. Christoph Engel, Sebastian J. Goerg, Gaoneng Yu. 2016. Symmetric vs. Asymmetric Punishment
Regimes for Collusive Bribery. American Law and Economics Review ahw005. [CrossRef]
17. Talai Osmonbekov, Brian Gregory, Christian Chelariu, Wesley J. Johnston. 2016. The impact of social
and contractual enforcement on reseller performance: the mediating role of coordination and inequity
during adoption of a new technology. Journal of Business & Industrial Marketing 31:6, 808-818.
[CrossRef]
18. Michel Dion. 2016. Agency theory and financial crime: the paradox of the opportunistic executive.
Journal of Financial Crime 23:3, 574-587. [CrossRef]
19. Haukur Freyr Gylfason, Freyr Halldorsson, Kari Kristinsson. 2016. Personality in Gneezy's cheap talk
game: The interaction between Honesty-Humility and Extraversion in predicting deceptive behavior.
Personality and Individual Differences 96, 222-226. [CrossRef]

20. Gregory E. Kersten, Tomasz Wachowicz, Margaret Kersten. 2016. Competition, Transparency, and
Reciprocity: A Comparative Study of Auctions and Negotiations. Group Decision and Negotiation 25:4,
693-722. [CrossRef]
21. Sverker C. Jagers, Stefan Linde, Johan Martinsson, Simon Matti. 2016. Testing the Importance of
Individuals Motives for Explaining Environmentally Significant Behavior*. Social Science Quarterly
. [CrossRef]
22. Friedrich Heinemann, Theocharis Grigoriadis. 2016. Origins of reform resistance and the Southern
European regime. Empirica . [CrossRef]
23. Chu Chen, Giorgio Gotti, Tony Kang, Michael C. Wolfe. 2016. Corporate Codes of Ethics, National
Culture, and Earnings Discretion: International Evidence. Journal of Business Ethics . [CrossRef]
24. Joan Luft. 2016. Cooperation and competition among employees: Experimental evidence on the role
of management control systems. Management Accounting Research 31, 75-85. [CrossRef]
25. Fuhai Hong, Wooyoung Lim. 2016. Voluntary participation in public goods provision with Coasian
bargaining. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 126, 102-119. [CrossRef]
26. Haoran He, Keyu Wu. 2016. Choice set, relative income, and inequity aversion: An experimental
investigation. Journal of Economic Psychology 54, 177-193. [CrossRef]
27. Erik O. Kimbrough, Alexander Vostroknutov. 2016. NORMS MAKE PREFERENCES SOCIAL.
Journal of the European Economic Association 14:3, 608-638. [CrossRef]
28. Russell Golman. 2016. Good manners: signaling social preferences. Theory and Decision 81:1, 73-88.
[CrossRef]
29. Daniel L. Chen, John J. Horton. 2016. Research NoteAre Online Labor Markets Spot Markets for
Tasks? A Field Experiment on the Behavioral Response to Wage Cuts. Information Systems Research
27:2, 403-423. [CrossRef]
30. Marianna Bicskei, Matthias Lankau, Kilian Bizer. 2016. Negative reciprocity and its relation to angerlike emotions in identity-homogeneous and -heterogeneous groups. Journal of Economic Psychology
54, 17-34. [CrossRef]
31. Li Yan, Xianchen ZhuImpact of HorizontalVertical social norms on performance behavior: Based
on a Simplified Trust Experiment 1-4. [CrossRef]
32. Lu Xiaohan, Liu YucanStudy on underwriting network and its role in IPO underpricing 1-6.
[CrossRef]
33. Erin L. Krupka, Stephen Leider, Ming Jiang. 2016. A Meeting of the Minds: Informal Agreements
and Social Norms. Management Science . [CrossRef]
34. Daniela Rabellino, Rosalba Morese, Angela Ciaramidaro, Bruno G. Bara, Francesca M. Bosco. 2016.
Third-party punishment: altruistic and anti-social behaviours in in-group and out-group settings.
Journal of Cognitive Psychology 28:4, 486-495. [CrossRef]
35. Niels Geiger. 2016. Psychological elements in business cycle theories: old approaches and new
insights. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 23:3, 478-507. [CrossRef]
36. Kristin L. Leimgruber, Alexandra G. Rosati, Laurie R. Santos. 2016. Capuchin monkeys punish those
who have more. Evolution and Human Behavior 37:3, 236-244. [CrossRef]
37. Martin Dufwenberg, Gunnar Khlin, Peter Martinsson, Haileselassie Medhin. 2016. Thanks but no
thanks: A new policy to reduce land conflict. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management
77, 31-50. [CrossRef]
38. Ibrahim Abosag, Dorothy A. Yen, Bradley R. Barnes. 2016. What is dark about the dark-side of
business relationships?. Industrial Marketing Management 55, 5-9. [CrossRef]

39. Cheryl Long, Jin Yang. 2016. What Explains Chinese Private Entrepreneurs' Charitable Behaviors?
A Story of Dynamic Reciprocal Relationship between Firms and the Government. China Economic
Review . [CrossRef]
40. Geoffrey M. Hodgson. 2016. Karl Polanyi on economy and society: a critical analysis of core concepts.
Review of Social Economy 1-25. [CrossRef]
41. Florian Englmaier, Thomas Kolaska, Stephen Leider. 2016. Reciprocity in Organizations: Evidence
from the UK. CESifo Economic Studies ifw006. [CrossRef]
42. Jared Rubin, Roman Sheremeta. 2016. PrincipalAgent Settings with Random Shocks. Management
Science 62:4, 985-999. [CrossRef]
43. Armin W. Schulz. 2016. Altruism, egoism, or neither: A cognitive-efficiency-based evolutionary
biological perspective on helping behavior. Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part C: Studies
in History and Philosophy of Biological and Biomedical Sciences 56, 15-23. [CrossRef]
44. Yan Zhang, Juan Li, Qinglong Gou. 2016. An allocation game model with reciprocal behavior and its
applications in supply chain pricing decisions. Annals of Operations Research . [CrossRef]
45. Rudolf Vetschera. 2016. Concessions Dynamics in Electronic Negotiations: A Cross-Lagged
Regression Analysis. Group Decision and Negotiation 25:2, 245-265. [CrossRef]
46. Linda Marshall, Vreda Pieterse, Lisa Thompson, Dina M. Venter. 2016. Exploration of Participation
in Student Software Engineering Teams. ACM Transactions on Computing Education 16:2, 1-38.
[CrossRef]
47. Annarita Colasante, Alberto Russo. 2016. Voting for the distribution rule in a Public Good Game
with heterogeneous endowments. Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination . [CrossRef]
48. Ori Weisel, Roi Zultan. 2016. Social motives in intergroup conflict: Group identity and perceived
target of threat. European Economic Review . [CrossRef]
49. Giacomo Degli Antoni, Gianluca Grimalda. 2016. Groups and trust: Experimental evidence on the
Olson and Putnam hypotheses. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics . [CrossRef]
50. Yanwen Wang, Michael Lewis, Cynthia Cryder, Jim Sprigg. 2016. Enduring Effects of Goal
Achievement and Failure Within Customer Loyalty Programs: A Large-Scale Field Experiment.
Marketing Science . [CrossRef]
51. Kristin M. Brethel-Haurwitz, Sarah A. Stoycos, Elise M. Cardinale, Bryce Huebner, Abigail A. Marsh.
2016. Is costly punishment altruistic? Exploring rejection of unfair offers in the Ultimatum Game in
real-world altruists. Scientific Reports 6, 18974. [CrossRef]
52. Rafi Amir-ud-Din, Asad Zaman. 2016. Failures of the Invisible Hand. Forum for Social Economics
45:1, 41-60. [CrossRef]
53. Subhajit Bhattachary, Anurag Singh. 2016. Achieving distribution equity through emotional
functionalities and value-based bonding: An analysis with structural equation modeling. Journal of
Global Scholars of Marketing Science 26:1, 66-88. [CrossRef]
54. Bart S. Vanneste. 2016. From interpersonal to interorganisational trust: The role of indirect
reciprocity. Journal of Trust Research 6:1, 7-36. [CrossRef]
55. David A. Savage. 2016. Surviving the Storm: Behavioural Economics in the Conflict Environment.
Peace Economics, Peace Science and Public Policy 22:2. . [CrossRef]
56. Erin L. Krupka, Rachel T.A. Croson. 2016. The Differential Impact of Social Norms Cues on
Charitable Contributions. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization . [CrossRef]
57. Johannes Siegrist, Morten WahrendorfFailed Social Reciprocity Beyond the Work Role 275-291.
[CrossRef]
58. Edward ShizhaAfrican Indigenous Perspectives on Technology 47-62. [CrossRef]

59. Maik Bieleke, Peter M. Gollwitzer, Gabriele Oettingen, Urs Fischbacher. 2016. Social Value
Orientation Moderates the Effects of Intuition versus Reflection on Responses to Unfair Ultimatum
Offers. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making . [CrossRef]
60. Namjoo Choi, Indushobha Chengalur-Smith. 2016. Characteristics of Open Source Software Projects
for the General Population: Reciprocity and Network Effects. Journal of Computer Information Systems
56:1, 22-30. [CrossRef]
61. John Knight, Ramani Gunatilaka. 2016. Is Happiness Infectious?. Scottish Journal of Political Economy
n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
62. Emanuela Ghignoni, Giuseppe Croce, Andrea Ricci. 2016. Fixed term contracts and employers' human
capital: The role of educational spillovers. Papers in Regional Science . [CrossRef]
63. . 2016. Equality or Equity? Distributive Justice Perceptions in Different Work Contexts. Advances
in Psychology 06:08, 923-931. [CrossRef]
64. Kyle Nash, Daria KnochIndividual Differences in Decision-Making: A Neural Trait Approach to
Study Sources of Behavioral Heterogeneity 191-209. [CrossRef]
65. T. Strombach, S. Strang, S.Q. Park, P. KenningCommon and distinctive approaches to motivation
in different disciplines . [CrossRef]
66. Qingyu Yang, Dou An, Wei Yu, Xinyu Yang, Xinwen FuOn stochastic optimal bidding strategy for
microgrids 1-8. [CrossRef]
67. Joseph G. Fisher, Sean A. Peffer, Geoffrey B. Sprinkle, Michael G. Williamson. 2015. Performance
Target Levels and Effort: Reciprocity across Single- and Repeated-Interaction Settings. Journal of
Management Accounting Research 27:2, 145-164. [CrossRef]
68. Gilles Grolleau, Naoufel Mzoughi, Sanja Pekovic. 2015. Work Recognition and Labor Productivity:
Evidence from French Data. Managerial and Decision Economics 36:8, 508-516. [CrossRef]
69. Heather Schofield, George Loewenstein, Jessica Kopsic, Kevin G. Volpp. 2015. Comparing the
effectiveness of individualistic, altruistic, and competitive incentives in motivating completion of
mental exercises. Journal of Health Economics 44, 286-299. [CrossRef]
70. Tobias Brndle. 2015. Productivity Signalling and Further Training. Evidence on Absence Behaviour,
Presenteeism and Overtime Hours of German Employees. Schmollers Jahrbuch 135:4, 499-535.
[CrossRef]
71. Estelle Midler, Unai Pascual, Adam G. Drucker, Ulf Narloch, Jos Luis Soto. 2015. Unraveling the
effects of payments for ecosystem services on motivations for collective action. Ecological Economics
120, 394-405. [CrossRef]
72. Thomas Bernauer, Robert Gampfer. 2015. How robust is public support for unilateral climate policy?.
Environmental Science & Policy 54, 316-330. [CrossRef]
73. Leda Cosmides, John ToobyAdaptations for Reasoning About Social Exchange 1-44. [CrossRef]
74. Andrea Szab, Gergely Ujhelyi. 2015. Reducing nonpayment for public utilities: Experimental evidence
from South Africa. Journal of Development Economics 117, 20-31. [CrossRef]
75. Bianca A. C. Groen, Celeste P. M. Wilderom, Marc J. F. Wouters. 2015. High Job Performance
Through Co-Developing Performance Measures With Employees. Human Resource Management n/
a-n/a. [CrossRef]
76. Nils Hesse, Mara Fernanda Rivas. 2015. DOES MANAGERIAL COMPENSATION AFFECT
WORKERS' EFFORT?. Journal of Applied Economics 18:2, 297-323. [CrossRef]
77. Mireia Las Heras, Maria Jos Bosch, Anneloes M.L. Raes. 2015. Sequential mediation among family
friendly culture and outcomes. Journal of Business Research 68:11, 2366-2373. [CrossRef]

78. Tobias Hahn, Nol Albert. 2015. Strong Reciprocity in Consumer Boycotts. Journal of Business Ethics
. [CrossRef]
79. Estelle Midler, Charles Figuires, Marc Willinger. 2015. Choice overload, coordination and inequality:
three hurdles to the effectiveness of the compensation mechanism?. Social Choice and Welfare 45:3,
513-535. [CrossRef]
80. Michalis Drouvelis, Nattavudh Powdthavee. 2015. Are happier people less judgmental of other people's
selfish behaviors? Experimental survey evidence from trust and gift exchange games. Journal of
Behavioral and Experimental Economics 58, 111-123. [CrossRef]
81. Lucas Ronconi, Rodrigo Zarazaga S.J.. 2015. Labor Exclusion and the Erosion of Citizenship
Responsibilities. World Development 74, 453-461. [CrossRef]
82. Claude Obadia, Daniel C Bello, David I Gilliland. 2015. Effect of exporters incentives on foreign
distributors role performance. Journal of International Business Studies 46:8, 960-983. [CrossRef]
83. yvind Nystad Handberg, Arild Angelsen. 2015. Experimental tests of tropical forest conservation
measures. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 118, 346-359. [CrossRef]
84. References 327-362. [CrossRef]
85. Milan Zafirovski. 2015. Toward Economic Sociology/Socio-Economics? Sociological Components in
Contemporary Economics and Implications for Sociology. The American Sociologist . [CrossRef]
86. Robert Kurzban, Steven NeubergManaging Ingroup and Outgroup Relationships 653-675. [CrossRef]
87. Leda Cosmides, John ToobyNeurocognitive Adaptations Designed for Social Exchange 584-627.
[CrossRef]
88. Bikramjit Singh, Konstantinos Koufos, Olav Tirkkonen, Riku JanttiRepeated spectrum sharing games
in multi-operator heterogeneous networks 221-228. [CrossRef]
89. Donna Harris, Benedikt Herrmann, Andreas Kontoleon, Jonathan Newton. 2015. Is it a norm to
favour your own group?. Experimental Economics 18:3, 491-521. [CrossRef]
90. Lus Cabral, Lingfang (Ivy) Li. 2015. A Dollar for Your Thoughts: Feedback-Conditional Rebates
on eBay. Management Science 61:9, 2052-2063. [CrossRef]
91. Karen Hauge, Ole Rogeberg. 2015. Representing Others in a Public Good Game. Games 6:3, 381-393.
[CrossRef]
92. Maarten Lindeboom, Bas van der Klaauw, Sandra Vriend. 2015. Audit rates and compliance: A field
experiment in care provision. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization . [CrossRef]
93. References 177-189. [CrossRef]
94. Raymond Montizaan, Andries de Grip, Frank Crvers, Thomas Dohmen. 2015. The Impact of
Negatively Reciprocal Inclinations on Worker Behavior: Evidence from a Retrenchment of Pension
Rights. Management Science 150817104623005. [CrossRef]
95. Yves Balasko. 2015. Wealth concerns and equilibrium. Journal of Mathematical Economics 59, 92-101.
[CrossRef]
96. Fernando P. Santos, Francisco C. Santos, Ana Paiva, Jorge M. Pacheco. 2015. Evolutionary dynamics
of group fairness. Journal of Theoretical Biology 378, 96-102. [CrossRef]
97. Jean Dellemotte, Benot Walraevens. 2015. Adam Smith on the subordination of wage-earners in
the commercial society. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22:4, 692-727.
[CrossRef]
98. Florin Popa. 2015. Motivations to Contribute to Public Goods: Beyond rational choice economics.
Environmental Policy and Governance 25:4, 230-242. [CrossRef]

99. Silvia Angerer, Daniela Gltzle-Rtzler, Philipp Lergetporer, Matthias Sutter. 2015. Donations, risk
attitudes and time preferences: A study on altruism in primary school children. Journal of Economic
Behavior & Organization 115, 67-74. [CrossRef]
100. Arthur Schram, Gary Charness. 2015. Inducing Social Norms in Laboratory Allocation Choices.
Management Science 61:7, 1531-1546. [CrossRef]
101. Dimitri Landa, Dominik Duell. 2015. Social Identity and Electoral Accountability. American Journal
of Political Science 59:3, 671-689. [CrossRef]
102. Pablo Guillen, Danielle Merrett, Robert Slonim. 2015. A New Solution for the Moral Hazard Problem
in Team Production. Management Science 61:7, 1514-1530. [CrossRef]
103. Guy Hochman, Shahar Ayal, Dan Ariely. 2015. Fairness requires deliberation: the primacy of
economic over social considerations. Frontiers in Psychology 6. . [CrossRef]
104. Qian Weng, Fredrik Carlsson. 2015. Cooperation in teams: The role of identity, punishment, and
endowment distribution. Journal of Public Economics 126, 25-38. [CrossRef]
105. P Read Montague, Terry Lohrenz, Peter Dayan. 2015. The three R's of trust. Current Opinion in
Behavioral Sciences 3, 102-106. [CrossRef]
106. Jordan Levine, Kai M.A. Chan, Terre Satterfield. 2015. From rational actor to efficient complexity
manager: Exorcising the ghost of Homo economicus with a unified synthesis of cognition research.
Ecological Economics 114, 22-32. [CrossRef]
107. Belma Ozturkkal. 2015. Profit sharing between managers and investors: An experimental
investigation. Borsa Istanbul Review 15:2, 106-114. [CrossRef]
108. Arleta Rasmuen. 2015. Reporting behavior: a literature review of experimental studies. Central
European Journal of Operations Research 23:2, 283-311. [CrossRef]
109. Uwe Jirjahn, Vanessa Lange. 2015. Reciprocity and Workers Tastes for Representation. Journal of
Labor Research 36:2, 188-209. [CrossRef]
110. Patrick Kampktter, Kathrin Marggraf. 2015. Do employees reciprocate to intra-firm trainings? An
analysis of absenteeism and turnover rates. The International Journal of Human Resource Management
1-20. [CrossRef]
111. Sefa Hayibor. 2015. Is Fair Treatment Enough? Augmenting the Fairness-Based Perspective on
Stakeholder Behaviour. Journal of Business Ethics . [CrossRef]
112. Jennifer A. Whitson, Cynthia S. Wang, Ya Hui Michelle See, Wayne E. Baker, J. Keith Murnighan.
2015. How, when, and why recipients and observers reward good deeds and punish bad deeds.
Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 128, 84-95. [CrossRef]
113. Annabeth Aagaard, Pernille Eskerod, Erik Skov Madsen. 2015. Key drivers for informal project
coordination among sub-contractors. International Journal of Managing Projects in Business 8:2,
222-240. [CrossRef]
114. Espen Bratberg, Karin Monstad. 2015. Worried sick? Worker responses to a financial shock. Labour
Economics 33, 111-120. [CrossRef]
115. Kirsten Thommes, Jana Vyrastekova, Agnes Akkerman. 2015. Behavioral spillovers from freeriding
in multilevel interactions. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics . [CrossRef]
116. Marcus Dittrich. 2015. Gender differences in trust and reciprocity: evidence from a large-scale
experiment with heterogeneous subjects. Applied Economics 1-14. [CrossRef]
117. Gjalt De Jong. 2015. The impact of social and human capital on individual cooperative behaviour.
Critical perspectives on international business 11:1, 4-29. [CrossRef]

118. Dimitris Georgarakos, Sven Frth. 2015. Household repayment behavior: The role of social capital
and institutional, political, and religious beliefs. European Journal of Political Economy 37, 249-265.
[CrossRef]
119. Ling Yu, Sheryl Ball, Christine Blinn, Klaus Moeltner, Seth Peery, Valerie Thomas, Randolph Wynne.
2015. Cloud-Sourcing: Using an Online Labor Force to Detect Clouds and Cloud Shadows in Landsat
Images. Remote Sensing 7:3, 2334-2351. [CrossRef]
120. Jeremy D. Douthit, Douglas E. Stevens. 2015. The Robustness of Honesty Effects on Budget
Proposals when the Superior has Rejection Authority. The Accounting Review 90:2, 467-493.
[CrossRef]
121. Ben Lowe, David Lynch, Julian Lowe. 2015. Reducing household water consumption: a social
marketing approach. Journal of Marketing Management 31:3-4, 378-408. [CrossRef]
122. Silvia Sacchetti. 2015. Inclusive and Exclusive Social Preferences: A Deweyan Framework to Explain
Governance Heterogeneity. Journal of Business Ethics 126:3, 473-485. [CrossRef]
123. Michael Lynn. 2015. Service gratuities and tipping: A motivational framework. Journal of Economic
Psychology 46, 74-88. [CrossRef]
124. Tuugi Chuluun. 2015. The role of underwriter peer networks in IPOs. Journal of Banking & Finance
51, 62-78. [CrossRef]
125. Barry T. Hirsch, Julia ManzellaWho Cares and Does it Matter? Measuring Wage Penalties for
Caring Work 213-275. [CrossRef]
126. Catherine Driscoll. 2015. Neither Adaptive Thinking nor Reverse Engineering: methods in the
evolutionary social sciences. Biology & Philosophy 30:1, 59. [CrossRef]
127. Christian PapilloudGift: History of the Concept 139-143. [CrossRef]
128. Rudolf Kerschbamer. 2015. The geometry of distributional preferences and a non-parametric
identification approach: The Equality Equivalence Test. European Economic Review 76, 85. [CrossRef]
129. Steven T. Schwartz, Eric E. Spires, David E. Wallin, Richard A. Young. 2015. The Role of
Commitment Devices in Budgeting. Managerial and Decision Economics 36:6, 345. [CrossRef]
130. Richard W. TreschBehavioral Public Sector Economics 417-431. [CrossRef]
131. Luise Grges. 2015. The power of love: A subtle driving force for unegalitarian labor division?. Review
of Economics of the Household 13:1, 163. [CrossRef]
132. Bjrn Hartig, Bernd Irlenbusch, Felix Klle. 2015. Conditioning on what? Heterogeneous
contributions and conditional cooperation. Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics 55, 48.
[CrossRef]
133. Rodolfo Cortes Barragan, Carol S. Dweck. 2014. Rethinking natural altruism: Simple reciprocal
interactions trigger childrens benevolence: Fig. 1. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences
111:48, 17071-17074. [CrossRef]
134. Milan Zafirovski. 2014. Rational Choice Requiem: The Decline of an Economic Paradigm and its
Implications for Sociology. The American Sociologist 45:4, 432-452. [CrossRef]
135. Susanne Neckermann, Reto Cueni, Bruno S. Frey. 2014. Awards at work. Labour Economics 31,
205-217. [CrossRef]
136. Mehran Nejati, Azlan Amran, Noor Hazlina Ahmad. 2014. Examining stakeholders influence
on environmental responsibility of micro, small and medium-sized enterprises and its outcomes.
Management Decision 52:10, 2021-2043. [CrossRef]
137. Kun Chen, Gang Kou, Jennifer Shang. 2014. An analytic decision making framework to evaluate
multiple marketing channels. Industrial Marketing Management 43:8, 1420-1434. [CrossRef]

138. Jeffrey M. Pollack, Douglas A. Bosse. 2014. When do investors forgive entrepreneurs for lying?.
Journal of Business Venturing 29:6, 741-754. [CrossRef]
139. Gesa Sophie Holst, Oliver Musshoff, Till Doerschner. 2014. Policy impact analysis of penalty and
reward scenarios to promote flowering cover crops using a business simulation game. Biomass and
Bioenergy 70, 196-206. [CrossRef]
140. Grazia Cecere, Susanna Mancinelli, Massimiliano Mazzanti. 2014. Waste prevention and social
preferences: the role of intrinsic and extrinsic motivations. Ecological Economics 107, 163-176.
[CrossRef]
141. Jeffrey Hales, Laura W. Wang, Michael G. Williamson. 2014. Selection Benefits of Stock-Based
Compensation for the Rank-and-File. The Accounting Review 141231102216001. [CrossRef]
142. Johnny JiungYee Lee, Michael L. Capella, Charles R. Taylor, Mi (Meg) Luo, Colin B. Gabler. 2014.
The financial impact of loyalty programs in the hotel industry: A social exchange theory perspective.
Journal of Business Research 67:10, 2139-2146. [CrossRef]
143. Will W.K. Ma, Albert Chan. 2014. Knowledge sharing and social media: Altruism, perceived online
attachment motivation, and perceived online relationship commitment. Computers in Human Behavior
39, 51-58. [CrossRef]
144. Thomas Dohmen. 2014. Behavioral labor economics: Advances and future directions. Labour
Economics 30, 71-85. [CrossRef]
145. Edward N. Okeke, Susan Godlonton. 2014. Doing wrong to do right? Social preferences and dishonest
behavior. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 106, 124-139. [CrossRef]
146. Ulrike Denker, Steven Schwartz, Christopher Ward, Richard Young. 2014. Voluntary disclosure in a
bargaining setting: A research note. Management Accounting Research 25:3, 223-229. [CrossRef]
147. Richard Povey. 2014. Punishment and the potency of group selection. Journal of Evolutionary
Economics 24:4, 799-816. [CrossRef]
148. Fredrik Carlsson, Olof Johansson-Stenman, Pham Khanh Nam. 2014. Social preferences are stable
over long periods of time. Journal of Public Economics 117, 104-114. [CrossRef]
149. Jol J. van der Weele, Julija Kulisa, Michael Kosfeld, Guido Friebel. 2014. Resisting Moral Wiggle
Room: How Robust Is Reciprocal Behavior?. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6:3,
256-264. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
150. Matthias Wrede. 2014. Fair inheritance taxation in the presence of tax planning. Journal of Behavioral
and Experimental Economics 51, 12-18. [CrossRef]
151. Ulrike Malmendier, Vera L. te Velde, Roberto A. Weber. 2014. Rethinking Reciprocity. Annual Review
of Economics 6:1, 849-874. [CrossRef]
152. Thomas de Hoop, Luuk van Kempen, Rik Linssen, Anouka van Eerdewijk. 2014. Women's
Autonomy and Subjective Well-Being: How Gender Norms Shape the Impact of Self-Help Groups
in Odisha, India. Feminist Economics 20:3, 103-135. [CrossRef]
153. Sebastian Galiani, Gustavo Torrens, Maria Lucia Yanguas. 2014. The Political Coase Theorem:
Experimental evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 103, 17-38. [CrossRef]
154. Frank van Erp, Niels Vermeer, Daniel van Vuuren. 2014. Non-financial Determinants of Retirement:
A Literature Review. De Economist 162:2, 167-191. [CrossRef]
155. Hui-Min Lai, Tsung Teng Chen. 2014. Knowledge sharing in interest online communities: A
comparison of posters and lurkers. Computers in Human Behavior 35, 295-306. [CrossRef]
156. Luis Alejandro Palacio Garca, Daniel Felipe Parra Carreo. 2014. El dilema de la contribucin
voluntaria a bienes pblicos: una revisin de trabajos experimentales. Cuadernos de Economa 33:62,
123-144. [CrossRef]

157. Roger A. McCain. 2014. Why Need is A Word We Cannot Do Without in Economics. Forum for
Social Economics 43:2, 181-196. [CrossRef]
158. Shaofu Du, Tengfei Nie, Chengbin Chu, Yugang Yu. 2014. Reciprocal supply chain with intention.
European Journal of Operational Research . [CrossRef]
159. Jodie L. Ferguson, Pam Scholder Ellen, William O. Bearden. 2014. Procedural and Distributive
Fairness: Determinants of Overall Price Fairness. Journal of Business Ethics 121:2, 217-231. [CrossRef]
160. Arshad Ali Javed, Patrick T.I. Lam, Albert P.C. Chan. 2014. Change negotiation in public-private
partnership projects through output specifications: an experimental approach based on game theory.
Construction Management and Economics 32:4, 323-348. [CrossRef]
161. Abiodun Egbetokun, Ivan Savin. 2014. Absorptive capacity and innovation: when is it better to
cooperate?. Journal of Evolutionary Economics 24:2, 399-420. [CrossRef]
162. Akinori Tomohara, Akihiko Ohno. 2014. Valuing non-pecuniary instruments of human resource
management. International Review of Economics 61:1, 1-11. [CrossRef]
163. ROMAN M. SHEREMETA, JINGJING ZHANG. 2014. THREE-PLAYER TRUST GAME
WITH INSIDER COMMUNICATION. Economic Inquiry 52:2, 576-591. [CrossRef]
164. Elia Morgulev, Ofer H. Azar, Ronnie Lidor, Eran Sabag, Michael Bar-Eli. 2014. Deception and
decision making in professional basketball: Is it beneficial to flop?. Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization . [CrossRef]
165. Ruud Gerards, Andries de Grip, Maaike Witlox. 2014. Employability-miles and worker employability
awareness. Applied Economics 46:9, 952-965. [CrossRef]
166. Lingfang (Ivy) Li, Erte Xiao. 2014. Money Talks: Rebate Mechanisms in Reputation System Design.
Management Science 140312101306006. [CrossRef]
167. David M. Carballo, Paul Roscoe, Gary M. Feinman. 2014. Cooperation and Collective Action in the
Cultural Evolution of Complex Societies. Journal of Archaeological Method and Theory 21:1, 98-133.
[CrossRef]
168. Mirella Damiani, Andrea Ricci. 2014. Managers education and the choice of different variable pay
schemes: Evidence from Italian firms. European Management Journal . [CrossRef]
169. Randle D. Raggio, Anna M. Walz, Mousumi Bose Godbole, Judith Anne Garretson Folse. 2014.
Gratitude in relationship marketing. European Journal of Marketing 48:1/2, 2-24. [CrossRef]
170. Gabriele Camera, Marco Casari. 2014. The Coordination Value of Monetary Exchange: Experimental
Evidence. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 6:1, 290-314. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
171. Uri Gneezy, Pedro Rey-Biel. 2014. ON THE RELATIVE EFFICIENCY OF PERFORMANCE
PAY AND NONCONTINGENT INCENTIVES. Journal of the European Economic Association 12:1,
62-72. [CrossRef]
172. Ernst Fehr, Ian KrajbichSocial Preferences and the Brain 193-218. [CrossRef]
173. Denisa Kera, Nur Liyana Sulaiman. 2014. FridgeMatch: Design probe into the future of urban food
commensality. Futures 62, 194. [CrossRef]
174. Elisabeth Fischer, Matin Qaim. 2014. Smallholder Farmers and Collective Action: What Determines
the Intensity of Participation?. Journal of Agricultural Economics n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
175. Patrick Yuan, Michael G Bare, Mallory O Johnson, Parya Saberi. 2014. Using Online Social Media
for Recruitment of Human Immunodeficiency Virus-Positive Participants: A Cross-Sectional Survey.
Journal of Medical Internet Research 16:5, e117. [CrossRef]
176. Geoffrey M. Hodgson. 2014. The evolution of morality and the end of economic man. Journal of
Evolutionary Economics 24:1, 83-106. [CrossRef]

177. Tania Singer, Anita TuscheUnderstanding Others 513-532. [CrossRef]


178. Sami Al-Suwailem. 2014. Complexity and endogenous instability. Research in International Business
and Finance 30, 393-410. [CrossRef]
179. Ola Kvaly, Miguel Luzuriaga. 2013. Playing the trust game with other peoples money. Experimental
Economics . [CrossRef]
180. David I. Gilliland, Stephen K. Kim. 2013. When do incentives work in channels of distribution?.
Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science . [CrossRef]
181. Andrew Christopher Godley. 2013. Entrepreneurial Opportunities, Implicit Contracts, and Market
Making for Complex Consumer Goods. Strategic Entrepreneurship Journal 7:4, 273-287. [CrossRef]
182. Mehmet Y. Gurdal, Joshua B. Miller, Aldo Rustichini. 2013. Why Blame?. Journal of Political Economy
121:6, 1205-1247. [CrossRef]
183. Subhajit Datta, A.S.M. Sajeev, Santonu Sarkar, Nishant KumarFactors Influencing Research
Contributions and Researcher Interactions in Software Engineering: An Empirical Study 34-41.
[CrossRef]
184. Margaret H. Christ. 2013. An Experimental Investigation of the Interactions among Intentions,
Reciprocity, and Control. Journal of Management Accounting Research 25:1, 169-197. [CrossRef]
185. David I. Gilliland, John M. Rudd. 2013. Control of electronic channel affiliates: An exploratory study
and research propositions. Journal of Business Research 66:12, 2650-2656. [CrossRef]
186. Urs Fischbacher, Ralph Hertwig, Adrian Bruhin. 2013. How to Model Heterogeneity in Costly
Punishment: Insights from Responders' Response Times. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 26:5,
462-476. [CrossRef]
187. Jrgen Flei, Stefan Palan. 2013. Of Coordinators and Dictators: A Public Goods Experiment. Games
4:4, 584-607. [CrossRef]
188. Seongmin A. Park, Soyeong Jeong, Jaeseung Jeong. 2013. TV programs that denounce unfair
advantage impact womens sensitivity to defection in the public goods game. Social Neuroscience 8:6,
568-582. [CrossRef]
189. Ana Cordeiro Santos, Joo Rodrigues. 2013. Neoliberalism in the Laboratory? Experimental
Economics on Markets and their Limits. New Political Economy 1-27. [CrossRef]
190. Julia Blasch, Mehdi Farsi. 2013. Context effects and heterogeneity in voluntary carbon offsetting a
choice experiment in Switzerland. Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy 1-24. [CrossRef]
191. Thomas Zeitzoff. 2013. Anger, Exposure to Violence, and Intragroup Conflict: A Lab in the Field
Experiment in Southern Israel. Political Psychology n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
192. Patrik Hesselius, Per Johansson, Johan Vikstrm. 2013. Social Behaviour in Work Absence*. The
Scandinavian Journal of Economics 115:4, 995-1019. [CrossRef]
193. Nikolaus Franke, Peter Keinz, Katharina Klausberger. 2013. Does This Sound Like a Fair Deal?:
Antecedents and Consequences of Fairness Expectations in the Individuals Decision to Participate in
Firm Innovation. Organization Science 24:5, 1495-1516. [CrossRef]
194. Lana Friesen, Lata Gangadharan. 2013. Designing self-reporting regimes to encourage truth telling:
An experimental study. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 94, 90-102. [CrossRef]
195. Laurence Fiddick, Denise Dellarosa Cummins, Maria Janicki, Sean Lee, Nicole Erlich. 2013. A CrossCultural Study of Noblesse Oblige in Economic Decision-Making. Human Nature 24:3, 318-335.
[CrossRef]
196. Ryan Bubb, Alex Kaufman. 2013. Consumer biases and mutual ownership. Journal of Public Economics
105, 39-57. [CrossRef]

197. Elisa Giuliani. 2013. Network dynamics in regional clusters: Evidence from Chile. Research Policy
42:8, 1406-1419. [CrossRef]
198. Donghee Yvette Wohn, Yu-Hao Lee. 2013. Players of facebook games and how they play.
Entertainment Computing 4:3, 171-178. [CrossRef]
199. Yingda Lu, Kinshuk Jerath, Param Vir Singh. 2013. The Emergence of Opinion Leaders in a
Networked Online Community: A Dyadic Model with Time Dynamics and a Heuristic for Fast
Estimation. Management Science 59:8, 1783-1799. [CrossRef]
200. Joseph P. Gaspar, Maurice E. Schweitzer. 2013. The Emotion Deception Model: A Review of
Deception in Negotiation and the Role of Emotion in Deception. Negotiation and Conflict Management
Research 6:3, 160-179. [CrossRef]
201. Randolph B. Cooper, Norman A. Johnson. 2013. So close yet no agreement: The effects of threats to
self-esteem when using instant messaging and audio during sellerbuyer negotiations. Decision Support
Systems . [CrossRef]
202. Philip Fei Wu, Nikolaos Korfiatis. 2013. You scratch someone's back and we'll scratch yours: Collective
reciprocity in social Q&A communities. Journal of the American Society for Information Science and
Technology n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
203. Peter A. Corning. 2013. Rotating the Necker cube: A bioeconomic approach to cooperation and the
causal role of synergy in evolution. Journal of Bioeconomics 15:2, 171-193. [CrossRef]
204. Jee-Hae Lim, Theophanis C. Stratopoulos, Tony S. Wirjanto. 2013. Sustainability of a Firm's
Reputation for Information Technology Capability: The Role of Senior IT Executives. Journal of
Management Information Systems 30:1, 57-96. [CrossRef]
205. Georgios A. Panos, Ioannis Theodossiou. 2013. Reciprocal Loyalty and Union Mediation. Industrial
Relations: A Journal of Economy and Society 52:3, 645-676. [CrossRef]
206. Florian Englmaier, Sebastian Strasser, Joachim Winter. 2013. Worker characteristics and wage
differentials: Evidence from a gift-exchange experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
. [CrossRef]
207. Gianna Lotito, Matteo Migheli, Guido Ortona. 2013. Is cooperation instinctive? Evidence from the
response times in a public goods game. Journal of Bioeconomics 15:2, 123-133. [CrossRef]
208. Vincent P. Crawford. 2013. Boundedly Rational versus Optimization-Based Models of Strategic
Thinking and Learning in Games. Journal of Economic Literature 51:2, 512-527. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
209. Erin L. Krupka, Roberto A. Weber. 2013. IDENTIFYING SOCIAL NORMS USING
COORDINATION GAMES: WHY DOES DICTATOR GAME SHARING VARY?. Journal of the
European Economic Association 11:3, 495-524. [CrossRef]
210. Ulrich Witt, Georg Schwesinger. 2013. Phylogenetic footprints in organizational behavior. Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization 90, S33-S44. [CrossRef]
211. Rudolf Vetschera. 2013. Negotiation processes: an integrated perspective. EURO Journal on Decision
Processes 1:1-2, 135-164. [CrossRef]
212. Mark Cecchini, Robert Leitch, Caroline Strobel. 2013. Multinational transfer pricing: A transaction
cost and resource based view. Journal of Accounting Literature . [CrossRef]
213. Robert J. Oxoby. 2013. Paretian dictators: constraining choice in a voluntary contribution game.
Constitutional Political Economy 24:2, 125-138. [CrossRef]
214. Daniel A. Mullins, Harvey Whitehouse, Quentin D. Atkinson. 2013. The role of writing and
recordkeeping in the cultural evolution of human cooperation. Journal of Economic Behavior &
Organization 90, S141-S151. [CrossRef]

215. Robert J. Shiller. 2013. Reflections on Finance and the Good Society. American Economic Review
103:3, 402-405. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
216. Atila Abdulkadirolu,, Kyle Bagwell. 2013. Trust, Reciprocity, and Favors in Cooperative
Relationships. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 5:2, 213-259. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
217. Markus Gbel, Rick Vogel, Christiana Weber. 2013. Management Research on Reciprocity: A Review
of the Literature. Business Research 6:1, 34-53. [CrossRef]
218. Akinori Tomohara, Akihiko Ohno. 2013. What are Relevant Work Incentive Models? Shirking
Model, Gift Exchange Model, or Reciprocity Model. Journal of Labor Research . [CrossRef]
219. Haukur Freyr Gylfason, Audur Arna Arnardottir, Kari Kristinsson. 2013. More on gender differences
in lying. Economics Letters 119:1, 94-96. [CrossRef]
220. Friedrich Heinemann, Martin G. Kocher. 2013. Tax compliance under tax regime changes.
International Tax and Public Finance 20:2, 225-246. [CrossRef]
221. Karen Pittel, Dirk Rbbelke. 2013. International Climate Finance and Its Influence on Fairness and
Policy. The World Economy 36:4, 419-436. [CrossRef]
222. Brigitte Geenen, Karin Proost, Bert Schreurs, Karen van Dam, Jasper von Grumbkow. 2013. What
friends tell you about justice: The influence of peer communication on applicant reactions. Revista de
Psicologa del Trabajo y de las Organizaciones 29:1, 37-44. [CrossRef]
223. Sascha O. Becker, Dolores Messer, Stefan C. Wolter. 2013. A Gift is Not Always a Gift: Heterogeneity
and Long-term Effects in a Gift Exchange Experiment. Economica 80:318, 345-371. [CrossRef]
224. Valerie Adams, Rhonda Sharp. 2013. Reciprocity in Caring Labor: Nurses Work in Residential Aged
Care in Australia. Feminist Economics 19:2, 100-121. [CrossRef]
225. Hendrik Thiel, Stephan L. Thomsen. 2013. Noncognitive skills in economics: Models, measurement,
and empirical evidence. Research in Economics . [CrossRef]
226. N. David Bethoney, Bradley P. Schondelmeier, Kevin D.E. Stokesbury, William S. Hoffman. 2013.
Developing a fine scale system to address river herring (Alosa pseudoharengus, A. aestivalis) and
American shad (A. sapidissima) bycatch in the U.S. Northwest Atlantic mid-water trawl fishery.
Fisheries Research 141, 79-87. [CrossRef]
227. Mirco Tonin, Michael Vlassopoulos. 2013. An experimental investigation of intrinsic motivations for
giving. Theory and Decision . [CrossRef]
228. Karl-Dieter Opp. 2013. Norms and rationality. Is moral behavior a form of rational action?. Theory
and Decision 74:3, 383-409. [CrossRef]
229. Christian Elmelund-Praestekaer, Patrick Emmenegger. 2013. Strategic Re-framing as a Vote Winner:
Why Vote-seeking Governments Pursue Unpopular Reforms. Scandinavian Political Studies 36:1,
23-42. [CrossRef]
230. Michael Ahlheim, Tobias Brger, Oliver Frr. 2013. The effects of extrinsic incentives on respondent
behaviour in contingent valuation studies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Policy 2:1, 45-70.
[CrossRef]
231. Xiaotao Kelvin Liu, Robert A. Leitch. 2013. Performance effects of setting targets and pay
performance relations before or after operations. Management Accounting Research 24:1, 64-79.
[CrossRef]
232. Susann Fiedler, Andreas Glckner, Andreas Nicklisch, Stephan Dickert. 2013. Social Value
Orientation and information search in social dilemmas: An eye-tracking analysis. Organizational
Behavior and Human Decision Processes 120:2, 272-284. [CrossRef]
233. Kirsten Bregn. 2013. Detrimental Effects of Performance-Related Pay in the Public Sector? On the
Need for a Broader Theoretical Perspective. Public Organization Review 13:1, 21-35. [CrossRef]

234. Gary Bolton, Ben Greiner, Axel Ockenfels. 2013. Engineering Trust: Reciprocity in the Production
of Reputation Information. Management Science 59:2, 265-285. [CrossRef]
235. Daniel Arnold. 2013. Benefit Morale and Cross-Country Diversity in Sick Pay Entitlements. Kyklos
66:1, 27-45. [CrossRef]
236. Richard W. Miles. 2013. The Psychophysics of Transition to Long Term Care. Journal of the American
Medical Directors Association 14:2, 85-93. [CrossRef]
237. Wei Siong Neo, Michael Yu, Roberto A. Weber, Cleotilde Gonzalez. 2013. The effects of time delay
in reciprocity games. Journal of Economic Psychology 34, 20-35. [CrossRef]
238. Yannick Gabuthy, Eve-Angline Lambert, Lionel Thomas. 2013. Severance Payment: Incentive or
Lethargy Effect?. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 60:1, 43-55. [CrossRef]
239. Tingting Wu, Yi Luo, Lucas S. Broster, Ruolei Gu, Yue-jia Luo. 2013. The impact of anxiety
on social decision-making: Behavioral and electrodermal findings. Social Neuroscience 8:1, 11-21.
[CrossRef]
240. Sandra Maximiano, Randolph Sloof, Joep Sonnemans. 2013. Gift exchange and the separation of
ownership and control. Games and Economic Behavior 77:1, 41-60. [CrossRef]
241. Ivo Bischoff,, Friedrich Heinemann,, Tanja Hennighausen,. 2013. What Makes Me See Inequality as
Just?. Schmollers Jahrbuch 133:1, 1-21. [CrossRef]
242. Marie-Laure Cabon-Dhersin, Nathalie Etchart-Vincent. 2013. COOPERATION: THE POWER
OF A SINGLE WORD? SOME EXPERIMENTAL EVIDENCE ON WORDING AND GENDER
EFFECTS IN A GAME OF CHICKEN. Bulletin of Economic Research 65:1, 43-64. [CrossRef]
243. Morris AltmanHayeks Complexity Assumption, Ecological and Bounded Rationality, and Behavioral
Economics 221-262. [CrossRef]
244. Fabienne Miller, Christine A. Denison, Linda J. Matuszewski. 2013. Modeling the Antecedents of
Preferences for Incomplete Contracts in Bilateral Trade: An Experimental Investigation. Behavioral
Research in Accounting 25:1, 135-159. [CrossRef]
245. MARTIN DUFWENBERG, ALEC SMITH, MATT VAN ESSEN. 2013. HOLD-UP: WITH A
VENGEANCE. Economic Inquiry 51:1, 896-908. [CrossRef]
246. Zhiyuan Song, Zhiyun Ouyang, Weihua Xu. 2012. The role of fairness norms the household-based
natural forest conservation: The case of Wolong, China. Ecological Economics 84, 164-171. [CrossRef]
247. Simon Gchter, Daniele Nosenzo, Martin Sefton. 2012. The Impact of Social Comparisons on
Reciprocity*. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114:4, 1346-1367. [CrossRef]
248. Andreia Tolciu, Ulrich Zierahn. 2012. Women and work: what role do social norms play?.
International Review of Applied Economics 26:6, 711-733. [CrossRef]
249. Joe Bull. 2012. Loads of green washingcan behavioural economics increase willingness-to-pay for
efficient washing machines in the UK?. Energy Policy 50, 242-252. [CrossRef]
250. WILLIAM M. SHOBE, DALLAS BURTRAW. 2012. RETHINKING ENVIRONMENTAL
FEDERALISM IN A WARMING WORLD. Climate Change Economics 03:04, 1250018. [CrossRef]
251. Jonathan Woon. 2012. Democratic Accountability and Retrospective Voting: A Laboratory
Experiment. American Journal of Political Science 56:4, 913-930. [CrossRef]
252. Stefano R. Belli, Robert D. Rogers, Jennifer Y.F. Lau. 2012. Adult and adolescent social reciprocity:
Experimental data from the Trust Game. Journal of Adolescence 35:5, 1341-1349. [CrossRef]
253. Xianghong Wang. 2012. When workers do not know The behavioral effects of minimum wage laws
revisited. Journal of Economic Psychology 33:5, 951-962. [CrossRef]

254. Leif Brandes, Egon Franck. 2012. Social preferences or personal career concerns? Field evidence on
positive and negative reciprocity in the workplace. Journal of Economic Psychology 33:5, 925-939.
[CrossRef]
255. C. Bazart, A. Bonein. 2012. Reciprocal relationships in tax compliance decisions. Journal of Economic
Psychology . [CrossRef]
256. Roberto Marchionatti. 2012. The economists and the primitive societies. The Journal of SocioEconomics 41:5, 529-540. [CrossRef]
257. Daniele Vilone, Jos J. Ramasco, Angel Snchez, Maxi San Miguel. 2012. Social and strategic
imitation: the way to consensus. Scientific Reports 2. . [CrossRef]
258. Jingnan Chen, Daniel Houser. 2012. Non-human Primate Studies Inform the Foundations of Fair
and Just Human Institutions. Social Justice Research 25:3, 277-297. [CrossRef]
259. Ethan Ligon, Laura Schechter. 2012. Motives for sharing in social networks. Journal of Development
Economics 99:1, 13-26. [CrossRef]
260. Steffen Huck, Gabriele K. Lnser, Jean-Robert Tyran. 2012. Competition fosters trust. Games and
Economic Behavior 76:1, 195-209. [CrossRef]
261. Francesca Medda, Eric Pels. 2012. Modelling public and private provision: The case of the railway
services. Papers in Regional Science 91:3, 645-657. [CrossRef]
262. Yves Fassin. 2012. Stakeholder Management, Reciprocity and Stakeholder Responsibility. Journal of
Business Ethics 109:1, 83-96. [CrossRef]
263. Sean Masaki Flynn, Michael Donnelly. 2012. Does labor contract completeness drive unionization?
Experimental evidence. The Journal of Socio-Economics 41:4, 445-454. [CrossRef]
264. ZHEN ZHANG, JIANXIN ZHANG. 2012. BELIEF IN RECIPROCITY IN A CHINESE
SAMPLE 1,2. Psychological Reports 111:1, 269-280. [CrossRef]
265. John Cullis, Philip Jones, Amal Soliman. 2012. Spite effects in tax evasion experiments. The Journal
of Socio-Economics 41:4, 418-423. [CrossRef]
266. Gran Bostedt, Runar Brnnlund. 2012. Rationality, fairness and the cost of distrust. The Journal of
Socio-Economics 41:4, 345-349. [CrossRef]
267. Yoella Bereby-Meyer, Shelly Fiks. 2012. Changes in Negative Reciprocity as a Function of Age. Journal
of Behavioral Decision Making n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
268. Morris Altman. 2012. The Living Wage, Economic Efficiency, and Socio-Economic Wellbeing in a
Competitive Market Economy. Forum for Social Economics 41:2-3, 166-186. [CrossRef]
269. Witold J. Henisz, Raymond E. Levitt, W. Richard Scott. 2012. Toward a unified theory of project
governance: economic, sociological and psychological supports for relational contracting. Engineering
Project Organization Journal 2:1-2, 37-55. [CrossRef]
270. Ral Lpez-Prez. 2012. The power of words: A model of honesty and fairness. Journal of Economic
Psychology 33:3, 642-658. [CrossRef]
271. Sven Hoeppner. 2012. The unintended consequence of doorstep consumer protection: surprise,
reciprocation, and consistency. European Journal of Law and Economics . [CrossRef]
272. Ingwer Borg, Cornelia Zuell. 2012. Writein comments in employee surveys. International Journal of
Manpower 33:2, 206-220. [CrossRef]
273. Werner Sesselmeier. 2012. Widersprche sozialer Integration in Zeiten der konomisierung sozialer
Sicherung. Sozialer Fortschritt 61:5, 104-110. [CrossRef]
274. Arjan Non. 2012. Gift-exchange, incentives, and heterogeneous workers. Games and Economic
Behavior 75:1, 319-336. [CrossRef]

275. Florian Herold. 2012. Carrot or Stick? The Evolution of Reciprocal Preferences in a Haystack Model.
American Economic Review 102:2, 914-940. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
276. PARTHA GANGOPADHYAY. 2012. ECONOMICS OF HATRED. International Journal of
Development and Conflict 02:01, 1250005. [CrossRef]
277. Wendy R. Boswell, Marla Baskerville Watkins, Mara del Carmen Triana, Asghar Zardkoohi, Run
Ren, Elizabeth E. Umphress. 2012. Second-class citizen? Contract workers' perceived status, dual
commitment and intent to quit. Journal of Vocational Behavior 80:2, 454-463. [CrossRef]
278. Attila Gulys. 2012. Fairness norms and tie strength in social networks An analytical model and
experimental results. Society and Economy 34:1, 29-49. [CrossRef]
279. CLARA XIAOLING CHEN, TATIANA SANDINO. 2012. Can Wages Buy Honesty?
The Relationship between Relative Wages and Employee Theft. Journal of Accounting Research nono. [CrossRef]
280. Christopher R. Keane, Jonathan M. Lafky, Oliver J. Board. 2012. Altruism, reciprocity and health:
A social experiment in restaurant choice. Food Policy 37:2, 143-150. [CrossRef]
281. Francesca Borgonovi. 2012. The relationship between education and levels of trust and tolerance in
Europe1. The British Journal of Sociology 63:1, 146-167. [CrossRef]
282. Aloys Wijngaards, Esther-Mirjam Sent. 2012. Meaning of Life: Exploring the Relation between
Economics and Religion. Review of Social Economy 70:1, 109-130. [CrossRef]
283. Yoella Bereby-Meyer. 2012. Reciprocity and uncertainty. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 35:01, 18-19.
[CrossRef]
284. Herbert Gintis, Ernst Fehr. 2012. The social structure of cooperation and punishment. Behavioral
and Brain Sciences 35:01, 28-29. [CrossRef]
285. Edward P. Lazear,, Ulrike Malmendier,, Roberto A. Weber. 2012. Sorting in Experiments with
Application to Social Preferences. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4:1, 136-163.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
286. Werner Gth, Lauri Sksvuori. 2012. Provision of Multilevel Public Goods by Positive Externalities:
Experimental Evidence. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 12:1. . [CrossRef]
287. Juan Miguel Bez Melin. 2012. Las preferencias y la conducta del cooperante recproco en un contexto
empresarial. Cuadernos de Economa y Direccin de la Empresa 15:1, 25-32. [CrossRef]
288. Margaretha Buurman, Robert Dur. 2012. Incentives and the Sorting of Altruistic Agents into StreetLevel Bureaucracies*. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114:4, 1318. [CrossRef]
289. S. Dhami, A. al-NowaihiBehavioral Economics 288-300. [CrossRef]
290. Martijn J. van den Assem, Dennie van Dolder, Richard H. Thaler. 2012. Split or Steal? Cooperative
Behavior When the Stakes Are Large. Management Science 58:1, 2-20. [CrossRef]
291. Leonardo Becchetti, Giuseppina Gianfreda, Noemi Pace. 2011. Human resource management and
productivity in the trust game corporation. International Review of Economics . [CrossRef]
292. Michle Belot, Jeroen van de Ven. 2011. Friendships and Favouritism on the Schoolground - A Framed
Field Experiment*. The Economic Journal 121:557, 1228-1251. [CrossRef]
293. Alex B. Markle. 2011. Dysfunctional learning in decision processes: the case of employee reciprocity.
Strategic Management Journal 32:13, 1411-1425. [CrossRef]
294. Claudia Keser, Claude Montmarquette. 2011. Voluntary versus Enforced Team Effort. Games 2:4,
277-301. [CrossRef]
295. Amelie F. Constant, Annabelle Krause, Ulf Rinne, Klaus F. Zimmermann. 2011. Economic preferences
and attitudes of the unemployed. International Journal of Manpower 32:7, 825-851. [CrossRef]

296. Axel v. Werder. 2011. Corporate Governance and Stakeholder Opportunism. Organization Science
22:5, 1345-1358. [CrossRef]
297. Jordi Blanes i Vidal, Mareike Nossol. 2011. Tournaments Without Prizes: Evidence from Personnel
Records. Management Science 57:10, 1721-1736. [CrossRef]
298. Jessica J Hoppner, David A Griffith. 2011. The Role of Reciprocity in Clarifying the Performance
Payoff of Relational Behavior. Journal of Marketing Research 48:5, 920-928. [CrossRef]
299. Davide Dragone, Luca Savorelli. 2011. Thinness and obesity: A model of food consumption, health
concerns, and social pressure. Journal of Health Economics . [CrossRef]
300. Francisco Alpzar, Peter Martinsson. 2011. Paying the price of sweetening your donation evidence from
a natural field experiment. Economics Letters . [CrossRef]
301. Richard G. Bribiescas. 2011. An evolutionary and life history perspective on the role of males on
human futures. Futures 43:8, 729-739. [CrossRef]
302. Martin Dietz,, Laura Dittrich,, Michael Stops,, Ulrich Walwei. 2011. Beschftigungssicherung durch
Arbeitskrftehorten. Sozialer Fortschritt 60:10, 221-231. [CrossRef]
303. Michael Kosfeld,, Susanne Neckermann. 2011. Getting More Work for Nothing? Symbolic Awards
and Worker Performance. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 3:3, 86-99. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
304. Meina Liu. 2011. Cultural Differences in Goal-directed Interaction Patterns in Negotiation.
Negotiation and Conflict Management Research 4:3, 178-199. [CrossRef]
305. Luca Stanca. 2011. Social science and neuroscience: how can they inform each other?. International
Review of Economics . [CrossRef]
306. LARS-ERIK CEDERMAN, NILS B. WEIDMANN, KRISTIAN SKREDE GLEDITSCH. 2011.
Horizontal Inequalities and Ethnonationalist Civil War: A Global Comparison. American Political
Science Review 1-18. [CrossRef]
307. Willem Verbeke, Frank D. Belschak, Richard P. Bagozzi, Stefan Wuyts. 2011. Gaining Access to
Intrafirm Knowledge: An Internal Market Perspective on Knowledge Sharing. Human Performance
24:3, 205-230. [CrossRef]
308. Thomas Herzfeld, Roel Jongeneel. 2011. Why do farmers behave as they do? Understanding
compliance with rural, agricultural, and food attribute standards. Land Use Policy . [CrossRef]
309. Chng Kean Siang, Till Requate, Israel Waichman. 2011. On the role of social wage comparisons in
gift-exchange experiments. Economics Letters 112:1, 75-78. [CrossRef]
310. Antti Kauhanen. 2011. The Perils of Altering Incentive Plans: A Case Study. Managerial and Decision
Economics n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
311. Rick K. Wilson. 2011. The Contribution of Behavioral Economics to Political Science. Annual Review
of Political Science 14:1, 201-223. [CrossRef]
312. Cherylynn Becker, Gregory T. Bradley, Ken Zantow. 2011. The underlying dimensions of tipping
behavior: An exploration, confirmation, and predictive model. International Journal of Hospitality
Management . [CrossRef]
313. Shin-Yuan Hung, Alexandra Durcikova, Hui-Min Lai, Wan-Mei Lin. 2011. The influence of intrinsic
and extrinsic motivation on individuals' knowledge sharing behavior. International Journal of HumanComputer Studies 69:6, 415-427. [CrossRef]
314. Elisabeth Gsottbauer, Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh. 2011. Environmental Policy Theory Given
Bounded Rationality and Other-regarding Preferences. Environmental and Resource Economics 49:2,
263-304. [CrossRef]

315. Todd R. Zenger, Teppo Felin, Lyda Bigelow. 2011. Theories of the FirmMarket Boundary. The
Academy of Management Annals 5:1, 89-133. [CrossRef]
316. Dirk T.G. Rbbelke. 2011. International support of climate change policies in developing countries:
Strategic, moral and fairness aspects. Ecological Economics 70:8, 1470-1480. [CrossRef]
317. Nick Lee, David I. Gilliland, Daniel C. Bello, Talai Osmonbekov. 2011. When electronic management
tools work and don't work in social-based distribution channels: A study of IT manufacturers
and resellers. Journal of Business Research . [CrossRef]
318. LAURENT DENANT-BOEMONT, DAVID MASCLET, CHARLES NOUSSAIR. 2011.
ANNOUNCEMENT, OBSERVATION AND HONESTY IN THE VOLUNTARY
CONTRIBUTIONS GAME. Pacific Economic Review 16:2, 207-228. [CrossRef]
319. Stephen A Samaha, Robert W Palmatier, Rajiv P Dant. 2011. Poisoning Relationships: Perceived
Unfairness in Channels of Distribution. Journal of Marketing 75:3, 99-117. [CrossRef]
320. Hui-Min Lai, Chin-Pin Chen. 2011. Factors influencing secondary school teachers adoption of
teaching blogs. Computers & Education 56:4, 948-960. [CrossRef]
321. Uwe Cantner, Andreas Meder, Tina Wolf. 2011. Success and failure of firms' innovation cooperations: The role of intermediaries and reciprocity*. Papers in Regional Science no-no. [CrossRef]
322. Johannes Abeler,, Armin Falk,, Lorenz Goette,, David Huffman. 2011. Reference Points and Effort
Provision. American Economic Review 101:2, 470-492. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
323. Thomas Dohmen,, Armin Falk. 2011. Performance Pay and Multidimensional Sorting: Productivity,
Preferences, and Gender. American Economic Review 101:2, 556-590. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
324. Stefan Grosse, Louis Putterman, Bettina Rockenbach. 2011. MONITORING IN TEAMS: USING
LABORATORY EXPERIMENTS TO STUDY A THEORY OF THE FIRM. Journal of the
European Economic Association no-no. [CrossRef]
325. Christine Harbring, Bernd Irlenbusch. 2011. Sabotage in Tournaments: Evidence from a Laboratory
Experiment. Management Science 57:4, 611-627. [CrossRef]
326. George Gotsis, Zoe Kortezi. 2011. Bounded selfinterest: a basis for constructive organizational
politics. Management Research Review 34:4, 450-476. [CrossRef]
327. Shin-Yuan Hung, Hui-Min Lai, Wen-Wen Chang. 2011. Knowledge-sharing motivations affecting
R&D employees' acceptance of electronic knowledge repository. Behaviour & Information Technology
30:2, 213-230. [CrossRef]
328. Markus C. Arnold, Robert M. Gillenkirch. 2011. Centralization versus Delegation in an Experimental
Capital Budgeting Setting. Business Research 4:1, 10-30. [CrossRef]
329. Allen Kaufman, Ernie Englander. 2011. Behavioral Economics, Federalism, and the Triumph of
Stakeholder Theory. Journal of Business Ethics . [CrossRef]
330. Martin Dufwenberg, Simon Gchter, Heike Hennig-Schmidt. 2011. The framing of games and the
psychology of play. Games and Economic Behavior . [CrossRef]
331. Farzad Sabetzadeh, Eric Tsui. 2011. Social motives polarity and its impact on knowledge sharing.
VINE 41:1, 76-88. [CrossRef]
332. Francesca Gino, Lamar Pierce. 2011. Lying to Level the Playing Field: Why People May Dishonestly
Help or Hurt Others to Create Equity. Journal of Business Ethics . [CrossRef]
333. Florian Baumann, Tim Friehe, Kristoffel Grechenig. 2011. A note on the optimality of (even more)
incomplete strict liability. International Review of Law and Economics . [CrossRef]
334. Philip Oreopoulos,, Kjell G. Salvanes. 2011. Priceless: The Nonpecuniary Benefits of Schooling.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 25:1, 159-184. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]

335. Avner Ben-Ner, Louis Putterman, Ting Ren. 2011. Lavish returns on cheap talk: Two-way
communication in trust games. The Journal of Socio-Economics 40:1, 1-13. [CrossRef]
336. Elisabetta Magnani. 2011. Environmental protection, inequality, and institutional change. Annals of
the New York Academy of Sciences 1219:1, 197-208. [CrossRef]
337. Masahiko Aoki. 2011. Institutions as cognitive media between strategic interactions and individual
beliefs. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization . [CrossRef]
338. Peter John Wood. 2011. Climate change and game theory. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences
1219:1, 153-170. [CrossRef]
339. Gary Charness, Peter KuhnLab Labor: What Can Labor Economists Learn from the Lab? 229-330.
[CrossRef]
340. Leonardo Becchetti, Noemi PaceCorporate Trust Games in Modern Knowledge Economies 353-380.
[CrossRef]
341. Akbar Zaheer, Darcy Fudge Kamal. 2011. Creating trust in piranha-infested waters: The confluence
of buyer, supplier and host country contexts. Journal of International Business Studies 42:1, 48-55.
[CrossRef]
342. William Ferguson. 2011. Curriculum for the Twenty-First Century: Recent Advances in Economic
Theory and Undergraduate Economics. The Journal of Economic Education 42:1, 31-50. [CrossRef]
343. Andreas P. Kyriacou. 2011. Rational Irrationality and Group Size: The Effect of Biased Beliefs on
Individual Contributions Towards Collective Goods. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 70:1,
109-130. [CrossRef]
344. Michal Wiktor Krawczyk. 2011. A model of procedural and distributive fairness. Theory and Decision
70:1, 111-128. [CrossRef]
345. Amitabh Chandra, David Cutler, Zirui SongWho Ordered That? The Economics of Treatment
Choices in Medical Care 397-432. [CrossRef]
346. Avner Ben-Ner, Louis PuttermanTrusting, Trustworthiness, and CSR: Some Experiments and
Implications 410-431. [CrossRef]
347. Mathilde Almlund, Angela Lee Duckworth, James Heckman, Tim KautzPersonality Psychology and
Economics 1-181. [CrossRef]
348. Allen Kaufman, Ernie EnglanderBehavioral Economics, Federalism and the Triumph of Stakeholder
Theory 73-98. [CrossRef]
349. Marie-Christine Thaize Challier. 2011. Intrinsic Motivation and Real Individual Piecewise Linear
Wages. Modern Economy 02:03, 344-353. [CrossRef]
350. Carlo Borzaga, Sara Depedri, Ermanno Tortia, Catherine Laurent. 2011. Diversits des organisations
dans les conomies de march, rle des coopratives et des entreprises sociales. Revue internationale
de l'conomie sociale: Recma :321, 32. [CrossRef]
351. Sangheon Lee, Deirdre McCannNew Directions in Labour Regulation Research 1-27. [CrossRef]
352. Benjamin Jewell, Amber WutichCharitable Christians, Punitive Neighbors: Religiosity and Economic
Norms in a Water-Scarce Environment 307-337. [CrossRef]
353. Johannes Abeler, Steffen Altmann, Sebastian Kube, Matthias Wibral. 2010. GIFT EXCHANGE
AND WORKERS' FAIRNESS CONCERNS: WHEN EQUALITY IS UNFAIR 5. Journal of the
European Economic Association 8:6, 1299-1324. [CrossRef]
354. Abhijit Ramalingam, Michael T. Rauh. 2010. The Firm as a Socialization Device. Management Science
56:12, 2191-2206. [CrossRef]
355. Chung-Cheng Lin, C.C. Yang. 2010. Reciprocity and downward wage rigidity. Journal of
Macroeconomics 32:4, 1155-1168. [CrossRef]

356. Bart Engelen. 2010. Beyond markets and states: the importance of communities. International Social
Science Journal 61:202, 489-500. [CrossRef]
357. Elinor Ostrom. 2010. Analyzing collective action. Agricultural Economics 41, 155-166. [CrossRef]
358. Alain de Janvry, Elisabeth Sadoulet, Sofia Villas-Boas. 2010. Short on shots: Are calls for cooperative
restraint effective in managing a flu vaccines shortage?. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization
76:2, 209-224. [CrossRef]
359. Erik O. Kimbrough. 2010. Learning to respect property by refashioning theft intotrade. Experimental
Economics . [CrossRef]
360. Roco del Pilar Moreno-Snchez, Jorge Higinio Maldonado. 2010. Evaluating the role of comanagement in improving governance of marine protected areas: An experimental approach in the
Colombian Caribbean. Ecological Economics 69:12, 2557-2567. [CrossRef]
361. Jean-Pierre Danthine, Andr Kurmann. 2010. The business cycle implications of reciprocity in labor
relations. Journal of Monetary Economics 57:7, 837-850. [CrossRef]
362. Michel S. Zouboulakis. 2010. Trustworthiness as a Moral Determinant of Economic Activity: Lessons
from the Classics. Forum for Social Economics 39:3, 209-221. [CrossRef]
363. LucaM. Visconti, JohnF. Sherry Jr., Stefania Borghini, Laurel Anderson. 2010. Street Art, Sweet
Art? Reclaiming the Public in Public Place. Journal of Consumer Research 37:3, 511-529. [CrossRef]
364. Andreia Tolciu. 2010. The Economics of Social Interactions: An Interdisciplinary Ground for Social
Scientists?. Forum for Social Economics 39:3, 223-242. [CrossRef]
365. Ral Lpez-Prez. 2010. Guilt and shame: an axiomatic analysis. Theory and Decision 69:4, 569-586.
[CrossRef]
366. Peter A. I. Forsyth, Christoph Hauert. 2010. Public goods games with reward in finite populations.
Journal of Mathematical Biology . [CrossRef]
367. Pedro de Faria, Wolfgang Sofka. 2010. Knowledge protection strategies of multinational firmsA
cross-country comparison. Research Policy 39:7, 956-968. [CrossRef]
368. Simon Gchter, Georg von Krogh, Stefan Haefliger. 2010. Initiating private-collective innovation:
The fragility of knowledge sharing. Research Policy 39:7, 893-906. [CrossRef]
369. R. Lynn Hannan, Frederick W. Rankin, Kristy L. Towry. 2010. Flattening the organization: the
effect of organizational reporting structure on budgeting effectiveness. Review of Accounting Studies
15:3, 503-536. [CrossRef]
370. Shih-Fen S Chen. 2010. A general TCE model of international business institutions: Market failure
and reciprocity. Journal of International Business Studies 41:6, 935-959. [CrossRef]
371. EDWARD CARTWRIGHT, AMRISH PATEL. 2010. Imitation and the Incentive to Contribute
Early in a Sequential Public Good Game. Journal of Public Economic Theory 12:4, 691-708. [CrossRef]
372. Hartmut Egger, Udo Kreickemeier. 2010. Worker-specific Effects of Globalisation. The World
Economy 33:8, 987-1005. [CrossRef]
373. David I. Gilliland, Daniel C. Bello, Gregory T. Gundlach. 2010. Control-based channel governance
and relative dependence. Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science 38:4, 441-455. [CrossRef]
374. Fekadu Beyene. 2010. Interclan Cooperation in a Risky Pastoral Ecology: Some lessons from Eastern
Ethiopia. Human Ecology 38:4, 555-565. [CrossRef]
375. Heribert Gierl, Ziyou Yang. 2010. Wie reagieren Personen in einer reziproken Situation?. der markt
. [CrossRef]
376. Marie-Laure Cabon-Dhersin, Nathalie Etchart-Vincent. 2010. The puzzle of cooperation in a game
of chicken: an experimental study. Theory and Decision . [CrossRef]

377. Thorsten Schank, Claus Schnabel, Joachim Wagner. 2010. Higher wages in exporting firms: selfselection, export effect, or both? First evidence from linked employer-employee data. Review of World
Economics 146:2, 303-322. [CrossRef]
378. Rafael Lalive, Alois Stutzer. 2010. Approval of equal rights and gender differences in well-being.
Journal of Population Economics 23:3, 933-962. [CrossRef]

379. Paul Bellaby. 2010. Theme 4: Trust among consumers. Energy Policy 38:6, 2653-2654. [CrossRef]
380. Gerhard Krug. 2010. Paradoxe Folgen finanzieller Anreize zur Arbeitsaufnahme fr die
Beschftigungsstabilitt. KZfSS Klner Zeitschrift fr Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 62:2, 191-217.
[CrossRef]
381. Erik Mohlin. 2010. Internalized social norms in conflicts: an evolutionary approach. Economics of
Governance 11:2, 169-181. [CrossRef]
382. Esteban F. Klor, Moses Shayo. 2010. Social identity and preferences over redistribution. Journal of
Public Economics 94:3-4, 269-278. [CrossRef]
383. HKAN EGGERT, RAZACK B. LOKINA. 2010. Regulatory compliance in Lake Victoria fisheries.
Environment and Development Economics 15:02, 197. [CrossRef]
384. Harry Clarke. 2010. Strategic issues in global climate change policy*. Australian Journal of Agricultural
and Resource Economics 54:2, 165-184. [CrossRef]
385. Christian Pfeifer. 2010. Impact of wages and job levels on worker absenteeism. International Journal
of Manpower 31:1, 59-72. [CrossRef]
386. Richard W. Miles. 2010. Cognitive Bias and Planning Error: Nullification of Evidence-Based Medicine
in the Nursing Home. Journal of the American Medical Directors Association 11:3, 194-203. [CrossRef]
387. Kirsten Bregn. 2010. The Logic of the New Pay Systems Revisited-in the Light of Experimental and
Behavioral Economics. International Journal of Public Administration 33:4, 161-168. [CrossRef]
388. Michael T. Rauh, Giulio Seccia. 2010. Agency and Anxiety. Journal of Economics & Management
Strategy 19:1, 87-116. [CrossRef]
389. Richard Fabling, Arthur Grimes. 2010. HR practices and New Zealand firm performance: what
matters and who does it?. The International Journal of Human Resource Management 21:4, 488-508.
[CrossRef]
390. JEFFREY HALES, MICHAEL G. WILLIAMSON. 2010. Implicit Employment Contracts: The
Limits of Management Reputation for Promoting Firm Productivity. Journal of Accounting Research
48:1, 147-176. [CrossRef]
391. Victor Hiller. 2010. WORKERS' BEHAVIOR AND LABOR CONTRACT: AN
EVOLUTIONARY APPROACH. Metroeconomica 61:1, 152-179. [CrossRef]
392. Bruno S. Frey. 2010. Geld oder Anerkennung? Zur konomik der Auszeichnungen. Perspektiven der
Wirtschaftspolitik 11:1, 1-15. [CrossRef]
393. Erwin Bulte, Richard D. Horan. 2010. Identities in the Commons: The Dynamics of Norms and
Social Capital. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy 10:1. . [CrossRef]
394. Robert Dur, Hein Roelfsema. 2010. Social exchange and common agency in organizations. The
Journal of Socio-Economics 39:1, 55-63. [CrossRef]
395. Fekadu Beyene. 2010. Customary Tenure and Reciprocal Grazing Arrangements in Eastern Ethiopia.
Development and Change 41:1, 107-129. [CrossRef]
396. Armin Falk, Simon Gchterexperimental labour economics 107-112. [CrossRef]
397. ELIAS L. KHALIL. 2010. ADAM SMITHS CONCEPT OF SELF-COMMAND AS A
SOLUTION TO DYNAMIC INCONSISTENCY AND THE COMMITMENT PROBLEM.
Economic Inquiry 48:1, 177-191. [CrossRef]

398. Jeffrey S. Harrison, Douglas A. Bosse, Robert A. Phillips. 2010. Managing for stakeholders,
stakeholder utility functions, and competitive advantage. Strategic Management Journal 31:1, 58-74.
[CrossRef]
399. Steven N. Durlauf, Lawrence E. BlumePsychological Games 272-278. [CrossRef]
400. Timothy Killingback, Michael Doebeli, Christoph Hauert. 2010. Diversity of Cooperation in the
Tragedy of the Commons. Biological Theory 5:1, 3-6. [CrossRef]
401. Katharina JanusManaging motivation among health care professionals 47-77. [CrossRef]
402. Ho Teck-Hua, Su Xuanming. 2009. Peer-Induced Fairness in Games. American Economic Review 99:5,
2022-2049. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
403. HELENA LOPES, ANA C. SANTOS, NUNO TELES. 2009. The motives for cooperation in work
organizations. Journal of Institutional Economics 5:03, 315. [CrossRef]
404. Joydeep Srivastava, Francine Espinoza, Alexander Fedorikhin. 2009. Coupling and decoupling of
unfairness and anger in ultimatum bargaining. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 22:5, 475-489.
[CrossRef]
405. Raul Caruso. 2009. The Basic Economics of Match Fixing in Sport Tournaments. Economic Analysis
and Policy 39:3, 355-377. [CrossRef]
406. Hartmut Egger, Udo Kreickemeier. 2009. Redistributing Gains from Globalisation*. Scandinavian
Journal of Economics 111:4, 765-788. [CrossRef]
407. Constant D. Beugr. 2009. Exploring the neural basis of fairness: A model of neuro-organizational
justice. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 110:2, 129-139. [CrossRef]
408. G. Argiolas, S. Cabras, C. Dess, M. Floris. 2009. Building innovative models of territorial governance.
Journal of Place Management and Development 2:3, 178-210. [CrossRef]
409. Astrid Hopfensitz, Ernesto Reuben. 2009. The Importance of Emotions for the Effectiveness of Social
Punishment. The Economic Journal 119:540, 1534-1559. [CrossRef]
410. Ernst Fehr, Lorenz Goette, Christian Zehnder. 2009. A Behavioral Account of the Labor Market:
The Role of Fairness Concerns. Annual Review of Economics 1:1, 355-384. [CrossRef]
411. Gottfried Koch, Julia Ostner, Marco Peisker, Oliver Schlke. 2009. Eine Analyse ultimaten Verhaltens
als Erklrungsansatz des moral hazards. Zeitschrift fr die gesamte Versicherungswissenschaft 98:3,
315-338. [CrossRef]
412. G. Siegal, N. Siegal, R. J. Bonnie. 2009. An Account of Collective Actions in Public Health. American
Journal of Public Health 99:9, 1583-1587. [CrossRef]
413. Francesca Gino, Lamar Pierce. 2009. Dishonesty in the Name of Equity. Psychological Science 20:9,
1153-1160. [CrossRef]
414. Michael Kosfeld,, Akira Okada,, Arno Riedl. 2009. Institution Formation in Public Goods Games.
American Economic Review 99:4, 1335-1355. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
415. PETER TAYLOR-GOOBY, ANDREW WALLACE. 2009. Public Values and Public Trust:
Responses to Welfare State Reform in the UK. Journal of Social Policy 38:03, 401. [CrossRef]
416. Ming-Ji James Lin, Shiu-Wan Hung, Chih-Jou Chen. 2009. Fostering the determinants of knowledge
sharing in professional virtual communities. Computers in Human Behavior 25:4, 929-939. [CrossRef]
417. Hans-Ulrich Kpper. 2009. Entscheidungsfreiheit als Grundlage wirtschaftswissenschaftlicher
Forschung Bezge zwischen Betriebswirtschaftslehre, Ethik und Neurobiologie. Zeitschrift fr
Betriebswirtschaft 79:6, 781-800. [CrossRef]
418. Erte Xiao, Daniel Houser. 2009. Avoiding the sharp tongue: Anticipated written messages promote
fair economic exchange. Journal of Economic Psychology 30:3, 393-404. [CrossRef]

419. Teppo Felin, Nicolai J. Foss. 2009. Social Reality, the Boundaries of Self-Fulfilling Prophecy, and
Economics. Organization Science 20:3, 654-668. [CrossRef]
420. Tackseung Jun, Rajiv Sethi. 2009. Reciprocity in evolving social networks. Journal of Evolutionary
Economics 19:3, 379-396. [CrossRef]
421. Dale O. Stahl, Ernan Haruvy. 2009. Testing theories of behavior for extensive-form two-player twostage games. Experimental Economics 12:2, 242-251. [CrossRef]
422. Erin Krupka, Roberto A. Weber. 2009. The focusing and informational effects of norms on pro-social
behavior. Journal of Economic Psychology 30:3, 307-320. [CrossRef]
423. Stefano DellaVigna. 2009. Psychology and Economics: Evidence from the Field. Journal of Economic
Literature 47:2, 315-372. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
424. Udo Kreickemeier. 2009. Trade, technology, and unemployment: the role of endogenous skill
formation. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'conomique 42:2, 639-664. [CrossRef]
425. Simon Gchter. 2009. Vorwort des Gastherausgebers Experimentelle konomie: Neue Wege, neue
Erkenntnisse?. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 10, 1-13. [CrossRef]
426. Cynthia S. Wang, Adam D. Galinsky, J. Keith Murnighan. 2009. Bad Drives Psychological Reactions,
but Good Propels Behavior: Responses to Honesty and Deception. Psychological Science 20:5, 634-644.
[CrossRef]
427. J. M. Pujol, A. Lopez Toledo, P. RodriguezFair Routing in Delay Tolerant Networks 837-845.
[CrossRef]
428. Douglas A. Bosse, Robert A. Phillips, Jeffrey S. Harrison. 2009. Stakeholders, reciprocity, and firm
performance. Strategic Management Journal 30:4, 447-456. [CrossRef]
429. Thomas Dohmen, Armin Falk, David Huffman, Uwe Sunde. 2009. Homo Reciprocans: Survey
Evidence on Behavioural Outcomes. The Economic Journal 119:536, 592-612. [CrossRef]
430. Henrik Andersson, Gunnar Lindberg. 2009. Benevolence and the value of road safety. Accident Analysis
& Prevention 41:2, 286-293. [CrossRef]
431. Sandeep Krishnamurthy, Arvind K. Tripathi. 2009. Monetary donations to an open source software
platform. Research Policy 38:2, 404-414. [CrossRef]
432. Hartmut Egger, Udo Kreickemeier. 2009. FIRM HETEROGENEITY AND THE LABOR
MARKET EFFECTS OF TRADE LIBERALIZATION. International Economic Review 50:1,
187-216. [CrossRef]
433. Tania SingerUnderstanding Others 251-268. [CrossRef]
434. Michael Storper. 2009. Roepke Lecture in Economic Geography-Regional Context and Global Trade.
Economic Geography 85:1, 1-21. [CrossRef]
435. Ernst FehrSocial Preferences and the Brain 215-232. [CrossRef]
436. Laura Langbein. 2009. Controlling Federal Agencies: The Contingent Impact of External Controls
on Worker Discretion and Productivity. International Public Management Journal 12:1, 82-115.
[CrossRef]
437. Lars W. Mitlacher, Christopher Paul. 2009. Performance-based pay systems for teams: explaining
the design of performance-based pay systems for teams from an expanded agency theory perspective.
International Journal of Business Performance Management 11:3, 171. [CrossRef]
438. Xiao-Yong Xiao, Bao-Lin XiangThe Impact of Minimum Wage Policy on Wages and Employment
in China 102-105. [CrossRef]
439. Jung-Kyoo Choi. 2008. Play locally, learn globally: group selection and structural basis of cooperation.
Journal of Bioeconomics 10:3, 239-257. [CrossRef]

440. Lise Lvesque, Vural Ozdemir, Batrice Godard. 2008. Socio-ethical Analysis of Equity in Access to
Nutrigenomics Interventions for Obesity Prevention: A Focus Group Study. OMICS: A Journal of
Integrative Biology 12:4, 273-278. [CrossRef]
441. Tobias Kronenberg. 2008. How does reciprocal behaviour of workers influence the wage setting of
unions?. Spanish Economic Review 10:4, 303-320. [CrossRef]
442. Mai B. Phan. 2008. We're All in This Together: Context, Contacts, and Social Trust in Canada.
Analyses of Social Issues and Public Policy 8:1, 23-51. [CrossRef]
443. Friedrich Heinemann, Michael Frg, Eva Jonas, Eva Traut-Mattausch. 2008. Psychologische
Restriktionen wirtschaftspolitischer Reformen. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 9:4, 383-404.
[CrossRef]
444. Christoph H. Loch, Yaozhong Wu. 2008. Social Preferences and Supply Chain Performance: An
Experimental Study. Management Science 54:11, 1835-1849. [CrossRef]
445. Linda Chang, Mandy Cheng, Ken T. Trotman. 2008. The effect of framing and negotiation partners
objective on judgments about negotiated transfer prices. Accounting, Organizations and Society 33:7-8,
704-717. [CrossRef]
446. Marilyne Antonetti, Alexandra Rufini. 2008. Social norms, coordination and collaboration in
heterogeneous teams. Managerial and Decision Economics 29:7, 547-554. [CrossRef]
447. Jason M Barr, Troy Tassier. 2008. Segregation and Strategic Neighborhood Interaction. Eastern
Economic Journal 34:4, 480-503. [CrossRef]
448. Ermanno C. Tortia. 2008. Worker well-being and perceived fairness: Survey-based findings from Italy.
The Journal of Socio-Economics 37:5, 2080-2094. [CrossRef]
449. Andreas Bergh. 2008. A critical note on the theory of inequity aversion. The Journal of Socio-Economics
37:5, 1789-1796. [CrossRef]
450. J BOUMA, E BULTE, D VANSOEST. 2008. Trust and cooperation: Social capital and community
resource management. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 56:2, 155-166.
[CrossRef]
451. Y. Wu, C. H. Loch, L. V. d. Heyden. 2008. A Model of Fair Process and Its Limits. Manufacturing
& Service Operations Management 10:4, 637-653. [CrossRef]
452. Andreas U. SchmidtOn the superdistribution of digital goods 1236-1243. [CrossRef]
453. Norman A Johnson, Randolph B Cooper, Wynne W Chin. 2008. The effect of flaming on computermediated negotiations. European Journal of Information Systems 17:4, 417-434. [CrossRef]
454. Maurizio Pugno. 2008. Economics and the self: A formalisation of self-determination theory. The
Journal of Socio-Economics 37:4, 1328-1346. [CrossRef]
455. Steven de Jong, Karl Tuyls, Katja Verbeeck. 2008. Fairness in multi-agent systems. The Knowledge
Engineering Review 23:02. . [CrossRef]
456. Ola Kvaly. 2008. Do norms matter for firm boundaries?. The Journal of Socio-Economics 37:3,
969-975. [CrossRef]
457. Deborah Kay Elms. 2008. New Directions for IPE: Drawing From Behavioral Economics.
International Studies Review 10:2, 239-265. [CrossRef]
458. Ian M. McDonald. 2008. Behavioural Economics. Australian Economic Review 41:2, 222-228.
[CrossRef]
459. Valeria Sodano, Martin Hingley, Adam Lindgreen. 2008. The usefulness of social capital in assessing
the welfare effects of private and thirdparty certification food safety policy standards. British Food
Journal 110:4/5, 493-513. [CrossRef]

460. Helena Lopes. 2008. From Self-Interest Motives to Justice Motives: The Challenges of Some
Experimental Results. American Journal of Economics and Sociology 67:2, 287-313. [CrossRef]
461. David Wilson, William Dixon. 2008. Reciprocity and economics in historical perspective. International
Review of Economics 55:1-2, 65-76. [CrossRef]
462. Ottorino Chillemi. 2008. Competitive versus collective incentive pay: does workers mutual concern
matter?. Economic Theory 35:1, 175-186. [CrossRef]
463. James D Westphal, Michael K Bednar. 2008. The Pacification of Institutional Investors. Administrative
Science Quarterly 53:1, 29-72. [CrossRef]
464. Chrysanthos Dellarocas, Charles A. Wood. 2008. The Sound of Silence in Online Feedback:
Estimating Trading Risks in the Presence of Reporting Bias. Management Science 54:3, 460-476.
[CrossRef]
465. Thomas Cornelien, Olaf Hbler. 2008. Downward wage rigidity and job mobility. Empirical
Economics 34:2, 205-230. [CrossRef]
466. Oliver Hart, John Moore. 2008. Contracts as Reference Points *. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123:1,
1-48. [CrossRef]
467. Jonathan H.W. Tan, Daniel John Zizzo. 2008. Groups, cooperation and conflict in games. The Journal
of Socio-Economics 37:1, 1-17. [CrossRef]
468. Philip Jones. 2008. More than the Sum of Parts': Social Policy and Expressive Collective Action.
Social Policy and Society 7:01. . [CrossRef]
469. J BIRNBERG, V HOFFMAN, S YUEN. 2008. The accountability demand for information in China
and the US A research note. Accounting, Organizations and Society 33:1, 20-32. [CrossRef]
470. James C. Cox, Daniel Friedman, Vjollca Sadiraj. 2008. Revealed Altruism. Econometrica 76:1, 31-69.
[CrossRef]
471. Samuel Bowles, Arjun JayadevThe Enforcement-Equality Trade-off 74-94. [CrossRef]
472. Charles A. Holt, Susan K. LauryChapter 90 Theoretical Explanations of Treatment Effects in
Voluntary Contributions Experiments 846-855. [CrossRef]
473. Nori Tarui, Charles F. Mason, Stephen Polasky, Greg Ellis. 2008. Cooperation in the commons with
unobservable actions. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 55:1, 37-51. [CrossRef]
474. Jens Grossklags, Alessandro AcquistiWhat Can Behavioral Economics Teach Us about Privacy?
363-377. [CrossRef]
475. References 117-131. [CrossRef]
476. Jeffrey Pfeffer. 2007. Human Resources from an Organizational Behavior Perspective: Some Paradoxes
Explained. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21:4, 115-134. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
477. Laura Schechter. 2007. Theft, Gift-Giving, and Trustworthiness: Honesty Is Its Own Reward in
Rural Paraguay. American Economic Review 97:5, 1560-1582. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
478. K SIGMUND. 2007. Punish or perish? Retaliation and collaboration among humans. Trends in
Ecology & Evolution 22:11, 593-600. [CrossRef]
479. Francesco Guala. 2007. The Philosophy of Social Science: Metaphysical and Empirical. Philosophy
Compass 2:6, 954-980. [CrossRef]
480. FREDRIK CARLSSON, OLOF JOHANSSON-STENMAN, PETER MARTINSSON. 2007. Do
You Enjoy Having More than Others? Survey Evidence of Positional Goods. Economica 74:296,
586-598. [CrossRef]
481. Performance Budgeting . [CrossRef]

482. Hugh Sibly. 2007. Loss aversion, price and quality. The Journal of Socio-Economics 36:5, 771-788.
[CrossRef]
483. Bram Tucker. 2007. Applying Behavioral Ecology and Behavioral Economics to Conservation and
Development Planning: An Example from the Mikea Forest, Madagascar. Human Nature 18:3,
190-208. [CrossRef]

484. Armin Falk. 2007. Gift Exchange in the Field. Econometrica 75:5, 1501-1511. [CrossRef]
485. Fredrik Hansen. 2007. Setting the scene with 'firms' and 'workers'. Journal of Economic Methodology
14:3, 339-352. [CrossRef]
486. Robin Boadway, Nicolas Marceau, Steeve Mongrain. 2007. Redistributive Taxation under Ethical
Behaviour. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 109:3, 505-529. [CrossRef]
487. Monique Mitchell Turner, Ron Tamborini, M. Sean Limon, Cynthia Zuckerman-Hyman. 2007.
The Moderators and Mediators of Door-in-the-Face Requests: Is it a Negotiation or a Helping
Experience?. Communication Monographs 74:3, 333-356. [CrossRef]
488. Ana C. Santos. 2007. The 'materials' of experimental economics: technological versus behavioral
experiments. Journal of Economic Methodology 14:3, 311-337. [CrossRef]
489. Sandra Maximiano, Randolph Sloof, Joep Sonnemans. 2007. Gift Exchange in a Multi-Worker Firm.
The Economic Journal 117:522, 1025-1050. [CrossRef]
490. Mary L. Rigdon, Kevin A. McCabe, Vernon L. Smith. 2007. Sustaining Cooperation in Trust Games.
The Economic Journal 117:522, 991-1007. [CrossRef]
491. Gary Charness, David I. Levine. 2007. Intention and Stochastic Outcomes: An Experimental study.
The Economic Journal 117:522, 1051-1072. [CrossRef]
492. STEPHAN KROLL, TODD L. CHERRY, JASON F. SHOGREN. 2007. VOTING,
PUNISHMENT, AND PUBLIC GOODS. Economic Inquiry 45:3, 557-570. [CrossRef]
493. Paul Sergius Koku. 2007. Some Significant Factors That Influence Tipping in Service Encounters
Outside the Restaurant Industry in the United States. Services Marketing Quarterly 29:1, 23-45.
[CrossRef]
494. Ramarao Desiraju, David E. M. Sappington. 2007. Equity and Adverse Selection. Journal of Economics
& Management Strategy 16:2, 285-318. [CrossRef]
495. Uwe Cantner, Andreas Meder. 2007. Technological proximity and the choice of cooperation partner.
Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination 2:1, 45-65. [CrossRef]
496. Petri Bckerman, Seppo Laaksonen, Jari Vainiomki. 2007. Who bears the burden of wage cuts?
Evidence from Finland during the 1990s. International Journal of Manpower 28:2, 100-121. [CrossRef]
497. Steven D. Levitt, John A. List. 2007. Viewpoint: On the generalizability of lab behaviour to the field.
Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'conomique 40:2, 347-370. [CrossRef]
498. Steven Y. Wu, Brian Roe. 2007. Contract Enforcement, Social Efficiency, and Distribution: Some
Experimental Evidence. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 89:2, 243-258. [CrossRef]
499. Michael Wright. 2007. Chapter 13. New Challenge to Inner-City Caregiving. Journal of Human
Behavior in the Social Environment 14:1, 259-274. [CrossRef]
500. Hessel Oosterbeek, Randolph Sloof, Joep Sonnemans. 2007. Who should invest in specific training?.
Journal of Population Economics 20:2, 329-357. [CrossRef]
501. Steven D. Levitt, John A. List. 2007. What Do Laboratory Experiments Measuring Social Preferences
Reveal About the Real World?. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21:2, 153-174. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
502. Ofer H. Azar. 2007. Why pay extra? Tipping and the importance of social norms and feelings in
economic theory. The Journal of Socio-Economics 36:2, 250-265. [CrossRef]

503. T. J. Hatton. 2007. Should we have a WTO for international migration?. Economic Policy 22:50,
340-383. [CrossRef]
504. Steffen Huck, Jean-Robert Tyran. 2007. Reciprocity, social ties, and competition in markets for
experience goods. The Journal of Socio-Economics 36:2, 191-203. [CrossRef]
505. Ivar Kolstad. 2007. The evolution of social norms: With managerial implications. The Journal of
Socio-Economics 36:1, 58-72. [CrossRef]
506. Richard J. Butler, William G. Johnson, Pierre C??t??. 2007. It Pays to be Nice: Employer-Worker
Relationships and the Management of Back Pain Claims. Journal of Occupational and Environmental
Medicine 49:2, 214-225. [CrossRef]
507. Donald Cox, Marcel FafchampsChapter 58 Extended Family and Kinship Networks: Economic
Insights and Evolutionary Directions 3711-3784. [CrossRef]
508. Maryline Meyer, Marc Ohana. 2007. Les entreprises sociales dans un monde marchand: A la recherche
d'un management efficace des hommes. Management & Avenir 11:1, 187. [CrossRef]
509. Yen-Sheng Chiang. 2007. The Evolution of Fairness in the Ultimatum Game. The Journal of
Mathematical Sociology 31:2, 175-186. [CrossRef]
510. Elisabeth Paul, Marc RobinsonPerformance Budgeting, Motivation, and Incentives 330-375.
[CrossRef]
511. Kay Axhausen. 2007. Activity Spaces, Biographies, Social Networks and their Welfare Gains and
Externalities: Some Hypotheses and Empirical Results. Mobilities 2:1, 15-36. [CrossRef]
512. Alan KirmanCourse 5 Economies with interacting agents 217-255. [CrossRef]
513. Alice SindzingreThe Multidimensionality of Poverty: An Institutionalist Perspective 52-74.
[CrossRef]
514. Jrme Gauti. 2007. L'conomie ses frontires (sociologie, psychologie). Revue conomique 58:4,
927. [CrossRef]
515. Lars-Olof Johansson, Mathias Gustafsson, Lars Olsson, Tommy Grling. 2007. Weighing third-party
fairness, efficiency, and self-interest in resource allocation decisions. Journal of Economic Psychology
28:1, 53-68. [CrossRef]
516. Eric Clemons, Jeff Grass, Steve WodabuySAFE: Creating and Profiting from the Bonded Seller^TM
Advantage 212b-212b. [CrossRef]
517. Machiko Nissanke, Alice Sindzingre. 2006. Institutional Foundations for Shared Growth in SubSaharan Africa. African Development Review 18:3, 353-391. [CrossRef]
518. KaiUwe Khn. 2006. Law, Economics and Antitrust: Towards a New Perspective20061Patrick
McNutt. Law, Economics and Antitrust: Towards a New Perspective . Edward Elgar, 2005.
International Journal of Social Economics 33:12, 860-862. [CrossRef]
519. Jan Schnellenbach. 2006. Appeasing nihilists? Some economic thoughts on reducing terrorist activity.
Public Choice 129:3-4, 301-313. [CrossRef]
520. Armin Falk, Michael Kosfeld. 2006. The Hidden Costs of Control. American Economic Review 96:5,
1611-1630. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
521. Gary Charness, Martin Dufwenberg. 2006. Promises and Partnership. Econometrica 74:6, 1579-1601.
[CrossRef]
522. James B. Wade, Charles A. O'Reilly, Timothy G. Pollock. 2006. Overpaid CEOs and Underpaid
Managers: Fairness and Executive Compensation. Organization Science 17:5, 527-544. [CrossRef]
523. James M. Acheson. 2006. Institutional Failure in Resource Management. Annual Review of
Anthropology 35:1, 117-134. [CrossRef]

524. Uri Gneezy, John A List. 2006. Putting Behavioral Economics to Work: Testing for Gift Exchange
in Labor Markets Using Field Experiments. Econometrica 74:5, 1365-1384. [CrossRef]
525. Stephen Polasky, Nori Tarui, Gregory M. Ellis, Charles F. Mason. 2006. Cooperation in the commons.
Economic Theory 29:1, 71-88. [CrossRef]
526. SHUPING CHEN, DAWN A. MATSUMOTO. 2006. Favorable versus Unfavorable
Recommendations: The Impact on Analyst Access to Management-Provided Information. Journal of
Accounting Research 44:4, 657-689. [CrossRef]
527. Gerald A. Cory. 2006. A behavioral model of the dual motive approach to behavioral economics and
social exchange. The Journal of Socio-Economics 35:4, 592-612. [CrossRef]
528. Carl Davidson, Steve Matusz, Doug Nelson. 2006. Fairness and the Political Economy of Trade. The
World Economy 29:8, 989-1004. [CrossRef]
529. Christer Berglund, Simon Matti. 2006. Citizen and consumer: the dual role of individuals in
environmental policy. Environmental Politics 15:4, 550-571. [CrossRef]
530. P. Read Montague, Brooks King-Casas, Jonathan D. Cohen. 2006. IMAGING VALUATION
MODELS IN HUMAN CHOICE. Annual Review of Neuroscience 29:1, 417-448. [CrossRef]
531. MARIASSUNTA GIANNETTI, ANDREI SIMONOV. 2006. Which Investors Fear Expropriation?
Evidence from Investors' Portfolio Choices. The Journal of Finance 61:3, 1507-1547. [CrossRef]
532. Martha Starr. 2006. Growth and conflict in the developing world: Neo-liberal narratives and socialeconomy alternatives. Review of Social Economy 64:2, 205-224. [CrossRef]
533. Juin-Kuan Chong, Colin F. Camerer, Teck H. Ho. 2006. A learning-based model of repeated games
with incomplete information. Games and Economic Behavior 55:2, 340-371. [CrossRef]
534. U CANTNER, H GRAF. 2006. The network of innovators in Jena: An application of social network
analysis. Research Policy 35:4, 463-480. [CrossRef]
535. Alan Kirman. 2006. Heterogeneity in Economics. Journal of Economic Interaction and Coordination
1:1, 89-117. [CrossRef]
536. Steven D. Levitt. 2006. White-Collar Crime Writ Small: A Case Study of Bagels, Donuts, and the
Honor System. American Economic Review 96:2, 290-294. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
537. Maureen Paul. 2006. A cross-section analysis of the fairness-of-pay perception of UK employees. The
Journal of Socio-Economics 35:2, 243-267. [CrossRef]
538. A JAYADEV, S BOWLES. 2006. Guard labor. Journal of Development Economics 79:2, 328-348.
[CrossRef]
539. Bernd Irlenbusch. 2006. Experimental perspectives on incentives in organisations. Central European
Journal of Operations Research 14:1, 1-24. [CrossRef]
540. Terence C BurnhamGames: Ultimatum . [CrossRef]
541. Mary RigdonTheory-of-Mind in Two-Person Experiments . [CrossRef]
542. C ANDERSON, L PUTTERMAN. 2006. Do non-strategic sanctions obey the law of demand? The
demand for punishment in the voluntary contribution mechanism. Games and Economic Behavior 54:1,
1-24. [CrossRef]
543. Amitava Krishna Dutt, Peter SkottChapter 6 Keynesian Theory and the ADAS Framework: A
Reconsideration 149-172. [CrossRef]
544. Erik SchokkaertChapter 2 The Empirical Analysis of Transfer Motives 127-181. [CrossRef]
545. Christina M. Fong, Samuel Bowles, Herbert GintisChapter 23 Strong reciprocity and the welfare state
1439-1464. [CrossRef]

546. Geoffrey B. Sprinkle, Michael G. WilliamsonExperimental Research in Managerial Accounting


415-444. [CrossRef]
547. Serge-Christophe KolmChapter 6 Reciprocity: Its Scope, Rationales, and Consequences 371-541.
[CrossRef]
548. Serge-Christophe KolmChapter 1 Introduction to the Economics of Giving, Altruism and Reciprocity
1-122. [CrossRef]
549. Louis PuttermanChapter 22 Reciprocity, altruism, and cooperative production 1409-1435. [CrossRef]
550. Jonathan D. Cohen. 2005. The Vulcanization of the Human Brain: A Neural Perspective on
Interactions Between Cognition and Emotion. Journal of Economic Perspectives 19:4, 3-24. [Abstract]
[View PDF article] [PDF with links]
551. Mascha van ??t Wout, Ren?? S. Kahn, Alan G. Sanfey, Andr?? Aleman. 2005. Repetitive transcranial
magnetic stimulation over the right dorsolateral prefrontal cortex affects strategic decision-making.
NeuroReport 16:16, 1849-1852. [CrossRef]
552. Terrel Gallaway. 2005. Life on the Edge: A Look at Ports of Trade and Other Ecotones. Journal of
Economic Issues 39:3, 707-726. [CrossRef]
553. Marco Herpen, Mirjam Praag, Kees Cools. 2005. The Effects of Performance Measurement and
Compensation on Motivation: An Empirical Study. De Economist 153:3, 303-329. [CrossRef]
554. Morris Altman. 2005. Behavioral Economics, Power, Rational Inefficiencies, Fuzzy Sets, and Public
Policy. Journal of Economic Issues 39:3, 683-706. [CrossRef]
555. Nava Ashraf, Colin F. Camerer, George Loewenstein. 2005. Adam Smith, Behavioral Economist.
Journal of Economic Perspectives 19:3, 131-145. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
556. Ofer H. Azar. 2005. The Social Norm of Tipping: Does it Improve Social Welfare?. Journal of
Economics - Zeitschrift fr Nationalkonomie 85:2, 141-173. [CrossRef]
557. JENNIFER C. COATS, WILLIAM S. NEILSON. 2005. BELIEFS ABOUT OTHERREGARDING PREFERENCES IN A SEQUENTIAL PUBLIC GOODS GAME. Economic Inquiry
43:3, 614-622. [CrossRef]
558. 2005. Book Review. The Economics of Transition 13:3, 569-572. [CrossRef]
559. JAMES C. COX, CARY A. DECK. 2005. ON THE NATURE OF RECIPROCAL MOTIVES.
Economic Inquiry 43:3, 623-635. [CrossRef]
560. 2005. Book Review. The Economics of Transition 13:2, 417-420. [CrossRef]
561. Joel Sobel. 2005. Interdependent Preferences and Reciprocity. Journal of Economic Literature 43:2,
392-436. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
562. Larry Samuelson. 2005. Foundations of Human Sociality: A Review Essay. Journal of Economic
Literature 43:2, 488-497. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
563. Thomas Beissinger, Chritoph Knoppik. 2005. Sind Nominallohne starr? Neuere Evidenz und
wirtschaftspolitische Implikationen. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 6:2, 171-188. [CrossRef]
564. E FEHR, L GOETTE. 2005. Robustness and real consequences of nominal wage rigidity. Journal
of Monetary Economics 52:4, 779-804. [CrossRef]
565. Tania Singer, Ernst Fehr. 2005. The Neuroeconomics of Mind Reading and Empathy. American
Economic Review 95:2, 340-345. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
566. Hakan J. Holm, Anders Danielson. 2005. Tropic Trust Versus Nordic Trust: Experimental Evidence
From Tanzania And Sweden*. The Economic Journal 115:503, 505-532. [CrossRef]
567. Gebhard Kirchgssner, Tobias Schulz. 2005. Was treibt die Stimmbrger an die Urne? Eine empirische
Untersuchung der Abstimmungsbeteiligung in der Schweiz, 1981-1999. Swiss Political Science Review
11:1, 1-56. [CrossRef]

568. Roger Berger, Katharina Schmitt. 2005. Vertrauen bei Internetauktionen und die Rolle von
Reputation, Informationen, Treuhandangebot und Preisniveau. KZfSS Klner Zeitschrift fr Soziologie
und Sozialpsychologie 57:1, 86-111. [CrossRef]
569. GAVIN A. WOOD, JOHN B. PARR. 2005. Transaction Costs, Agglomeration Economies, and
Industrial Location*. Growth and Change 36:1, 1-15. [CrossRef]
570. Edwin Leuven, Hessel Oosterbeek, Randolph Sloof, Chris van Klaveren. 2005. Worker Reciprocity
and Employer Investment in Training. Economica 72:285, 137-149. [CrossRef]
571. Vincy Fon, Francesco Parisi. 2005. The Behavioral Foundations of Retaliatory Justice. Journal of
Bioeconomics 7:1, 45-72. [CrossRef]
572. Zhanbing Huang, Difang WanReciprocity factors in relationship marketing 173-179 Vol. 1.
[CrossRef]
573. R. Lynn Hannan. 2005. The Combined Effect of Wages and Firm Profit on Employee Effort. The
Accounting Review 80:1, 167-188. [CrossRef]
574. Stephen K. Swallow, Marisa J. Mazzotta. 2004. Assessing Public Priorities for Experiment Station
Research: Contingent Value and Public Preferences for Agricultural Research. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 86:4, 975-989. [CrossRef]
575. Colin F. Camerer, George Loewenstein, Drazen Prelec. 2004. Neuroeconomics: Why Economics
Needs Brains. Scandinavian Journal of Economics 106:3, 555-579. [CrossRef]
576. Maria-Elisabeth Fischer, Bernd Irlenbusch, Abdolkarim Sadrieh. 2004. An intergenerational common
pool resource experiment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 48:2, 811-836.
[CrossRef]
577. Jeffrey P. Carpenter. 2004. When in Rome: conformity and the provision of public goods. The Journal
of Socio-Economics 33:4, 395-408. [CrossRef]
578. RAYMOND M. DUCH, HARVEY D. PALMER. 2004. It's Not Whether You Win or Lose, but
How You Play the Game: Self-Interest, Social Justice, and Mass Attitudes toward Market Transition.
American Political Science Review 98:03, 437-452. [CrossRef]
579. J. Mark Weber, Shirli Kopelman, David M. Messick. 2004. A Conceptual Review of Decision Making
in Social Dilemmas: Applying a Logic of Appropriateness. Personality and Social Psychology Review
8:3, 281-307. [CrossRef]
580. Nancy R. Buchan, Rachel T. A. Croson, Eric J. Johnson. 2004. When Do Fair Beliefs Influence
Bargaining Behavior? Experimental Bargaining in Japan and the United States. Journal of Consumer
Research 31:1, 181-190. [CrossRef]
581. Alois Stutzer, Rafael Lalive. 2004. The Role of Social Work Norms in Job Searching and Subjective
Well-Being. Journal of the European Economic Association 2:4, 696-719. [CrossRef]
582. D FRIEDMAN. 2004. Negative reciprocityThe coevolution of memes and genes. Evolution and
Human Behavior 25:3, 155-173. [CrossRef]
583. Martin Brown, Armin Falk, Ernst Fehr. 2004. Relational Contracts and the Nature of Market
Interactions. Econometrica 72:3, 747-780. [CrossRef]
584. AlanB. Krueger, Alexandre Mas. 2004. Strikes, Scabs, and Tread Separations: Labor Strife and the
Production of Defective Bridgestone/Firestone Tires. Journal of Political Economy 112:2, 253-289.
[CrossRef]
585. Bruce Shearer. 2004. Piece Rates, Fixed Wages and Incentives: Evidence from a Field Experiment.
Review of Economic Studies 71:2, 513-534. [CrossRef]
586. Bjrn Frank. 2004. Zehn Jahre empirische Korruptionsforschung. Vierteljahrshefte zur
Wirtschaftsforschung 73:2, 184-199. [CrossRef]

587. Kathleen L. McGinn, Elizabeth Long Lingo, Karin Ciano. 2004. Transitions through Out-ofKeeping Acts. Negotiation Journal 20:2, 171-184. [CrossRef]
588. Nicolai J. Foss. 2004. Cognition and Motivation in the Theory of the Firm: Interaction or "Never the
Twain Shall Meet"?. Journal des Economistes et des Etudes Humaines 14:1. . [CrossRef]
589. P.C. Ensign, L. HebertKnowledge sharing among R&D scientists 7 pp.. [CrossRef]
590. James Konow. 2003. Which Is the Fairest One of All? A Positive Analysis of Justice Theories. Journal
of Economic Literature 41:4, 1188-1239. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
591. David Genesove. 2003. The Nominal Rigidity of Apartment Rents. Review of Economics and Statistics
85:4, 844-853. [CrossRef]
592. Olaf von dem Knesebeck, Johannes Siegrist. 2003. Reported nonreciprocity of social exchange and
depressive symptoms. Journal of Psychosomatic Research 55:3, 209-214. [CrossRef]
593. Colin Camerer, Richard H. Thaler. 2003. In Honor of Matthew Rabin: Winner of the John Bates
Clark Medal. Journal of Economic Perspectives 17:3, 159-176. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF
with links]
594. Steve Onyeiwu, Robert Jones. 2003. An institutionalist perception of cooperative behavior. The
Journal of Socio-Economics 32:3, 233-248. [CrossRef]
595. Michael E. Price. 2003. Pro-community altruism and social status in a Shuar village. Human Nature
14:2, 191-195. [CrossRef]
596. C Camerer. 2003. Behavioural studies of strategic thinking in games. Trends in Cognitive Sciences 7:5,
225-231. [CrossRef]
597. Daniel Kahneman. 2003. A Psychological Perspective on Economics. American Economic Review 93:2,
162-168. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
598. G Sprinkle. 2003. Perspectives on experimental research in managerial accounting. Accounting,
Organizations and Society 28:2-3, 287-318. [CrossRef]
599. Charlotte D. Phelps. 2003. The Invisible Heart: Economics and Family Values. The Journal of SocioEconomics 32:1, 105-106. [CrossRef]
600. Armin Falk. 2003. Homo Oeconomicus versus Homo Reciprocans: Ansatze fur ein neues
Wirtschaftspolitisches Leitbild?. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik 4:1, 141-172. [CrossRef]
601. Kathleen L. McGinn, Leigh Thompson, Max H. Bazerman. 2003. Dyadic processes of disclosure
and reciprocity in bargaining with communication. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16:1, 17-34.
[CrossRef]
602. Gerald A. CoryMacleans Evolutionary Neuroscience and the Conflict Systems Neurobehavioral
Model: Some Clinical and Social Policy Implications 161-180. [CrossRef]
603. Fikret Adaman, Yahya M. Madra. 2002. Theorizing the "Third Sphere": A Critique of the Persistence
of the "Economistic Fallacy". Journal of Economic Issues 36:4, 1045-1078. [CrossRef]
604. S Bonner. 2002. The effects of monetary incentives on effort and task performance: theories, evidence,
and a framework for research. Accounting, Organizations and Society 27:4-5, 303-345. [CrossRef]
605. David Spencer. 2002. Shirking the Issue? Efficiency wages, work discipline and full employment.
Review of Political Economy 14:3, 313-327. [CrossRef]
606. M Price. 2002. Punitive sentiment as an anti-free rider psychological device. Evolution and Human
Behavior 23:3, 203-231. [CrossRef]
607. Eric J. Johnson, Colin Camerer, Sankar Sen, Talia Rymon. 2002. Detecting Failures of Backward
Induction: Monitoring Information Search in Sequential Bargaining. Journal of Economic Theory
104:1, 16-47. [CrossRef]

608. Jessica L. Cohen, William T. Dickens. 2002. A Foundation for Behavioral Economics. American
Economic Review 92:2, 335-338. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
609. A CHAUDHURI, B SOPHER, P STRAND. 2002. Cooperation in social dilemmas, trust and
reciprocity1. Journal of Economic Psychology 23:2, 231-249. [CrossRef]
610. A Kunz. 2002. Agency theory, performance evaluation, and the hypothetical construct of intrinsic
motivation. Accounting, Organizations and Society 27:3, 275-295. [CrossRef]
611. Kim Hill. 2002. Altruistic cooperation during foraging by the Ache, and the evolved human
predisposition to cooperate. Human Nature 13:1, 105-128. [CrossRef]
612. Peter Howitt. 2002. Looking Inside the Labor Market: A Review Article. Journal of Economic
Literature 40:1, 125-138. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
613. Margit Osterloh, Jetta Frost, Bruno Frey. 2002. The Dynamics of Motivation in New Organizational
Forms. International Journal of the Economics of Business 9:1, 61-77. [CrossRef]
614. Joseph Henrich,, Robert Boyd,, Samuel Bowles,, Colin Camerer,, Ernst Fehr,, Herbert Gintis,,
Richard McElreath. 2001. In Search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale
Societies. American Economic Review 91:2, 73-78. [Citation] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
615. Alessandro Ancarani, Carmela Di MauroThe Human Side of Supply Chains 1453-1476. [CrossRef]
616. R.M. Muller, M. Spiliopoulou, H.-J. LenzThe Influence of Incentives and Culture on Knowledge
Sharing 247b-247b. [CrossRef]
617. Alessandro Ancarani, Carmela Di MauroThe Human Side of Supply Chains 290-314. [CrossRef]
618. P.C. Ensign, L. HebertInformal knowledge sharing behavior of scientists: evidence of exchanging and
withholding technological information 594-598. [CrossRef]
619. Peter A. CorningThe Cooperative Gene: Evolution, Human Nature, and Politics 13-42. [CrossRef]

You might also like