You are on page 1of 7

American Economic Association

Does Aid Affect Governance?


Author(s): Raghuram Rajan and Arvind Subramanian
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 97, No. 2 (May, 2007), pp. 322-327
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/30034469
Accessed: 30-11-2015 16:34 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The American Economic
Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
Does AidAffectGovernance?

By RAGHURAMRAJAN AND ARVIND SUBRAMANIAN*

I. ChannelsfromAid to Growth Without further analysis, we do not know if


this relationshipis causal. If causal, this figure
Why is there little robust evidence that for- offers a proximateexplanationfor why aid may
eign aid significantly enhances the economic not have led to substantialgrowth. As pointed
growth of poor countries?1The search for an out by Simon Johnson, Jonathan Ostry, and
explanation is becoming immensely impor- Subramanian(2007); and BenjaminF.Jonesand
tant as industrial countries are being exhorted Benjamin A. Olken (2005), virtually all coun-
to increase their aid budgets in order to help tries that have had a sustainedperiod of growth
developing countries achieve the Millennium in the postwarperiod have seen a large increase
Development Goals. in their share of manufacturingproductionand
Perhapsone should not expect an impact on manufacturingexports.
growthfromthe mere infusion of additionalcap- But what is the deep underlying cause?
ital into a country. But, perhaps,any beneficial Manufacturingis more complex than agricul-
effects are offset by adverse spillover effects, ture or mining in that it requires many more
and academic focus should shift to determining transactions between unrelated parties. Thus,
what these are and how to mitigatethem. In this manufacturingis likely to be moredependenton
regard, Figure 1 is suggestive. We plot the log a good-governanceenvironmentthat can foster
of the manufacturingto gross domestic product multiple transactions.Here is where aid could
(GDP) ratio in a country against the log of the hurt. By expanding a government's resource
ratio of aid received to GDP for that country envelope, aid reduces the need for govern-
for two separate time periods (the late 1990s ments to explain their actions to citizens, which
and the early 1980s), conditional on a number may reduce its need to govern well (Deborah
of variables. As the figure suggests, the more A. Brautigam and Stephen Knack 2004). In
aid a country has received, the smaller its share particular, the government could falter in its
of manufacturing.The coefficient estimate sug- responsibilityto maintain rule of law, ensure a
gests that a 1 percentage point increase in the predictablejudiciary and contractenforcement,
ratio of aid to GDP is associated with a reduced and limit corruption. In a companion paper
share of manufacturingin total GDP of about (Rajan and Subramanian2005b), we examine
0.2 to 0.3 percentagepoints.2 anotherchannelthroughwhich poor governance
could affect manufacturing-the mismanage-
ment of the real exchangerate.
We use the methodology in Rajanand Luigi
Zingales (1998) to test the hypothesis that aid
*Rajan: Graduate School of Business, University of might reduce the quality of governance.They
Chicago, 5807 S. Woodlawn, Chicago IL 60637 (e-mail:
rajan@chicagogsb.edu); Subramanian:InternationalMone- suggest thatone way to check whethera channel
tary Fund, 700 19thStreet, Washington,DC 20431 (e-mail: is at workis to see whetherindustriesthatmight
asubramanian@imf.org). be most affected by a channel grow differen-
1 See, for example, William Easterly (2003), Easterly, tially (faster or slower depending on the nature
Ross Levine, and David Roodman (2004), Henrik Hansen
of the effect) in countries where that channel is
and Finn Tarp (2001), Roodman (2004), and Rajan and
Subramanian(2005a). likely to be more operative.The industrychar-
2 The
conditioning variables include a country's per acteristic we are interested in is the degree to
capita purchasingpower parity (PPP) GDP, per capita PPP which an industry depends on governance
GDP squared,and country and time fixed effects. Because
we include fixed effects, the association between aid and
(hereafterreferredto as "governance"sensitiv-
manufacturing depicted in the chart is a temporal one, ity or dependence).The channelis the quality of
that is, within countries over time ratherthan one between governance,and countriesthat get more aid are
countries. likely to be the ones where the channel is most
322

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL.97 NO. 2 DOES AID AFFECT GOVERNANCE? 323

adversely affected. The estimation strategy is II. Sensitivityto Governance


then to run regressionsof the form
Details on data sources are availablefrom the
(1) Growthij= Constant authors,while summary statistics and detailed
tables with robustness checks are available
+ Indicators in a longer version of this paper available at
(*1.....m*Country
Rajan'sWeb site (http://faculty.chicagogsb.edu/
+ ,m+1....n*IndustryIndicators raghuram.rajan/research/).The sample com-
prises all developing countries in the United
+ yn+,* (Industryi's share of Nations Industrial Development Organization
manufacturingin countryj (UNIDO) database(see the Web version of this
in the initial period) paperfor a list of countriesin the sample).
Clearly, the success of our method depends
+ a (Aid to countryj* Sensitivityof on whetherwe have a plausiblemeasurefor the
industryi to governance) dependence of an industry on the governance
environment. Olivier Blanchard and Michael
+ Eij, Kremer(1997) develop such a measure.Broadly
speaking, the fewer other industries an indus-
where Growthijis the annual average rate of try buys from-that is, the more concentrated
growth of value addedof industryi in countryj its purchases-the more possibility it has of
over the ten-yearperiod 1981-1990, obtainedby regulating transactionsvia long-term,repeated
normalizingthe growthin nominal value added relationships or vertical integration, and less
by the GDP deflator; 1.....m are the coefficients possibility of its need to rely on explicit gover-
of the country fixed effects; are the coef- nance by the courts or regulatory authorities.
ficients of the industry fixedm+m1....n
effects;3 and yn+1 If the country has little governance capacity,
is the coefficient of the initial period share industries that depend on contracts or arm's-
of industry i in total value added in countryj length transactions(that is, score lower on the
(which controls for convergence-type effects). concentrationindex) are likely to either have to
Aid to countryj is the averageaid-to-GDPratio distorttheir organizationalstructureor transact
for that country over the sample period. The less, both of which will affect their growth.
coefficient of interestfor us is a. It capturesan The governance-dependencemeasure (from
interactionbetween a country-specificaid vari- Andre A. Levchenko 2006), which is based on
able and an industry'ssensitivityto governance. Blanchardand Kremer (1997), is calculated as
We posit countries that receive more aid should follows from US input-outputdata. For each
see a more negative impact in industrialsectors manufacturingindustry i, we obtained its inter-
that are more governance sensitive. The chief mediate goods purchases from other industries
advantageof this strategyis that by controlling k. The Herfindahlindex for each sector i is cal-
for country and industryfixed effects, the prob- culated as the sum of the squaresof the sharesof
lem of omitted variablesbias or model specifi- the purchasesof each input k in total input pur-
cation, which seriously afflicts cross-country chases of i. We multiplythe Herfindahlindex by
regressions,is diminished.4 -1 to get the HERF measure,where a value of
zero indicates an industrythat is highly depen-
dent on public institutionsto govern its transac-
tions, while a value of -1 denotes an industry
3 We focus on the 1980s because of the large sample
that transacts fairly narrowly,and thus is less
size. For the 1990s, data are available for only 15 develop-
ing countries. dependenton public institutions.
4 Essentially, we are
making predictions about within- Ideally, we would like to measure the num-
country differences between industries based on an inter- ber of outside transactionswith different firms
action between a country and industry characteristic.
Moreover,because we focus on differences between manu-
facturing industries (ratherthan between, say, manufactur-
ing and services industries), we can rule out factors that of our results-for these factors should not affect the differ-
would keep manufacturingunderdevelopedas explanations ences between manufacturingindustries.

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
324 AEA PAPERSAND PROCEEDINGS MAY2007

TABLE 1--THE GOVERNANCE-DEPENDENCE INDEX, THE IMPACT OF AID ON INSTITUTIONS, AND ROBUSTNESS CHECKS
(Dependentvariable is the annual averagerate of growthof value addedof industry(i) in country(j)for the 1980s)

1 2 3 4 5 6
Estimation method OLS OLS IV IV IV IV
Initial industry share (ij) -0.370*** -0.452*** -0.509*** -0.494*** -0.416*** -0.366***
[0.069] [0.068] [0.074] [0.070] [0.068] [0.080]
Investmentprotection (j)* 1.194***
Governance-dependence(i) (Herfindahl)
[0.336]
Aid/GDP(j)* -2.126* -9.902*** -9.684** -8.583**
Governance-dependence(i) (Herfindahl) [1.146] [3.778] [4.066] [3.832]
Technical aid/GDP (j)* -41.831**
Governance-dependence(i) (Herfindahl) [16.791]
Initial income (j)* -0.231**
Governance-dependence(i) (Herfindahl) [0.092]
Aid/GDP (j) -1.395**
[0.592]
Initial income 1980s -0.007
[0.006]
SW trade policy index 0.059***
[0.007]
Observations 811 809 809 809 758 758
R-squared 0.46 0.46 0.43 0.44 0.45 0.13
Notes: All standarderrors reportedbelow the coefficient estimates are robust. All regressions include country and indus-
try effects, not reported above for presentationalsimplicity. Governance-dependence(Herfindahl)(i) is the negative of the
Herfindahlindex of concentrationof outside purchases for industry (i), calculated as the sum of the squareof the shares of
purchases of each input on the total input purchases. It ranges between 0 (institutions-intensive)and -1 (not institutions-
intensive). Initial industry share (ij) is the initial shareof the value added of industry(i) in the total value added of all manu-
facturing sectors in country (j). Investmentprotection(j) is the ICRGmeasureof investmentprofile in country(j) thatrelies
on risk assessments regardingcontractviability/expropriation,profitrepatriation,and paymentdelays. We use a normalized
0 to 1 version of the original 1 to 12 ICRGmeasure (averageover the decade for countryj). Aid to GDP in country(j) is the
average over the decade of the ratio of aid to GDP for that country. Technical aid to GDP is the respective measurefor the
technical component of aid to country (j). Initial income is measuredby the log of the initial level of per capitaPPP GDP,as
reportedin the Penn WorldTablesdatabase.SW tradepolicy index is the Sachs and Warnermeasure; see Sachs and Warner
(1995). In regressions (2) to (6), the dependentand independentvariables are winsorized at 5 percent and 95 percentof their
sample distributions.In the IV estimations, we use fitted aid to GDP, or fitted technical aid to GDP, as an instrumentfor the
respective variables, or its interactions,as in Rajan and Subramanian(2005a).
*** Significant at or below 1 percent.
** Significant at or below 5 percent.
* Significant at or below 10 percent.

at the firm level, whereas our measure is at the the growth of governance-dependentindus-
industry level. Also, ours is a measure of con- tries, then it must be the case that in countries
centrationof outside purchases,which does not that have better governance,industriesthat are
account for the fact that the fraction of outside more governance-dependentshould grow faster
purchasesin total output can vary. Finally, our relative to sectors that are less governance-
measure is derived from US data which raises dependent.This is a hypothesisthatwe can test.
questions about its applicability to developing In Table 1, column 1, we regress the growth
countries, where, for example, patternsof verti- rate of industry i in country j on a country-
cal integrationcould be very differentfrom that specific measure of governance quality and
in the United States (though,clearly, that adap- the industry-specific measure of governance-
tation is part of the channel throughwhich poor dependence, after controlling for country and
governanceinstitutionswill affect growth). industry fixed effects. The country measure
One way of validating our measure is the of governance quality is investment protec-
following. If good governanceis necessary for tion from the InternationalCountryRisk Guide

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL.97 NO. 2 DOESAID AFFECTGOVERNANCE? 325

(ICRG),which is a good proxy for our notion of violating the exclusion restriction underlying
governance quality as representingthe rule of the instrumentation.In our sample, the direct
law and contract enforcement.The coefficient correlationbetween our instrumentfor aid and
on the interactiontermis positive and significant investmentprotectionis low (0.07 in magnitude)
at the 1 percentconfidencelevel, suggestingthat and not statistically significant, suggesting this
in countries that have better governance,indus- should not be a strongconcern.
tries that are more governance-dependentgrow
faster.Specifically, the annualgrowth rate of an IV. CoreResult
industrythat is one standarddeviationhigherin
governance-dependencein a country that has In column 2 of Table 1, we present the OLS
one standard deviation better governance is estimate for model 1. We present the IV esti-
0.8 percent higher, which is a sizeable magni- mate in column 3. The interactioncoefficient is
tude, given that the averageannual growth rate negative and significant at standardlevels, sug-
of industries is 2.1 percent in our sample. This gesting that in a countrythat receives more aid,
result survives various robustness checks (see governance-dependentindustriesgrowrelatively
Web version, Table2). more slowly. Specifically,using the IV estimate,
It appears then that our governance-depen- the annual growth rate of an industry that is
dence variable, postulated on theoretical con- one standarddeviation higher in governance-
siderations by Blanchard and Kremer (1997), dependence (HERF) in a country that receives
picks out industriesthat thrive (relatively)in an one standarddeviation more aid is 2.8 percent-
environment with good governance. A finding age points lower,which is a sizeable magnitude,
in our core difference-in-difference estima- given that the average annual growth rate of
tion, that aid affects the relative growth rate of industriesis 2.1 in our sample. The IV estimate
these industries,shouldthen give us more confi- remains significantwhen we clusterby country
dence (thanin a simple cross-countryregression or by industry.
between aid and institutions)that the channel One could argue that not all forms of aid are
through which the effect is transmittedis gov- equal. A number of economists try to identify
ernance quality. certain forms of aid that are likely to be "good"
or developmentoriented. Specifically, technical
III. Endogeneityof Aid assistance is geared toward building capacity
and institutions,and if the logic bears out, we
Because we examine growth differentials should expect to see a less negative interaction
between industries within countries, the results with this form of aid. This is what we check in
are less sensitive to the rationalefor why aid is the estimate reportedin column 4. It turns out
given. For example, even if aid is given only that the estimate is again negative and signifi-
to countries that display poor growth, interin- cant. Eitherit could be that all forms of aid are
dustry growth differentials should not be seri- correlatedwith one anotherso that "good' aid is
ously affected. Suppose, however, low growth hard to tell apartfrom other aid, or aid inflows
is primarily because countries have poor qual- are fungible, so it does not matter whether the
ity institutions, and aid is given systematically use of certain inflows are carefully specified or
to countries that have low growth. In this case, not, aid frees up resourceselsewhere.
we might be attributingto aid what is driven In column5, we includeaninteractionbetween
directly by governance quality. The way to initial per capita GDP and governance-depen-
address this is through instrumentation,which dence to check whetheraid is just a proxyfor the
allows us to disentanglethe direction of causal- country's per capita income. The basic interac-
ity. We instrument for aid based on strategic, tion coefficient continuesto be significant,even
historic, and cultural links between donor and with this inclusion. In the core specification of
recipient(see Rajanand Subramanian2005a for column 3, we can includean interactionbetween
details of the instrumentationprocess). governancequalityandgovernance-dependence.
One possible concern is that our instruments, If aid inflows "work" by reducing the qual-
based on strategic and colonial links, could ity of institutions, then introducing this direct
be correlated with governance quality, thus interactionshould weaken the aid governance-

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
326 AEA PAPERSAND PROCEEDINGS MAY2007

IAGO
.4

IGHA SYC
GRD OZMB
TGO 0 IDN
.2
* LSO ........ FA MRT. . . .
GDP
/ ILK, ~Aer~ CiG
BLZ
DCGV IUGA
BL
eL~w,~ CTFJI 1 GyP

0
SNGA
SNI ka-1,
SyDG
*JOR1 (R 1*Jt JOR
J ,'A N C~~~~CCCC~~~~CCCC~~
I
l
NGA
WE
' 1'BEN Bai
Manufacturing SUGA 0BLZ '\CfA YQuY
)FTJ LKA
Log
-.2
SCIV
IIDN
MRT WR TGO
LSO
COM
ZMB IGRD
SYC GHA

.4
AGO
-1 -0.5 0 0.5 1
Log Aid/GDP
coef = -0.15726536, (robust) se = 0.05571313, t = -2.82

FIGURE1. MANUFACTURING
ANDAID BETWEEN1980 AND 2000

Notes: This plot represents the conditional relationship between the change in the size of
the manufacturing sector and the change in aid in a country between 1980 and 2000. It
is based on running a panel regression where the dependent variable is log of the ratio of
the share of value added in manufacturingto GDP for a country in two time periods (the
late 1990s and the early 1980s). The explanatoryvariables are the country's per capita PPP
GDP, per capita PPP GDP squared, and fixed effects for the country and the time period.
All variables are averagesfor the period 1980-1985 and 1995-2000, respectively. To facili-
tate comparabilitywith the core results in the paper,the sample was chosen according to the
same criteria as in the core sample of the paper,namely to include countries that had an aid-
to-GDP ratio greaterthan 1 percent or are low-income countries. Data on manufacturingare
from the WorldBank's WorldDevelopmentIndicators.

dependence interaction.It does: the magnitude V. Conclusions


on the coefficient declines substantiallyand it is
also no longer statistically significant (see Web One of the ways aid might have affected
version of this paperfor estimates). growth adverselyis by constrainingthe growth
Finally, when we include country indicators, of the manufacturingsector. A possible chan-
we cannot estimate the effects of individual nel for which we provideevidence in this paper
country-specificvariables.In column 6, we drop is that aid might be particularlyassociatedwith
the country indicators and include standard weak governance,possibly because aid inflows
explanatory variables in growth regressions. reduce the need for governmentsto tax the gov-
The direct correlation of aid inflows (which is erned or enlist theircooperation.The paperalso
instrumented)is negative, suggesting industry offers a methodological approachto checking
growth rates are lower in countries that receive whether governanceactually matters,based on
more aid.' This is consistentwith the figurewith the growth of governance-dependentindustries.
which we startedthe paper. Broadlyspeaking,the papersuggeststhateven
if the paucityof capitalis the missing ingredient
in the process of setting countries on the path
5 More robustness checks are reported in the Web ver-
to prosperity (and the jury is still out on this),
sion of this paper. the form in which the capital is received could

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
VOL.97 NO. 2 DOESAID AFFECTGOVERNANCE? 327

have adversespillovereffects thatlimit its value. Sub-SaharanAfrica."EconomicDevelopment


Indeed, if foreign aid reduces competitiveness and CulturalChange,52(2):255-85.
by inflating the exchange rate, or if foreign aid Easterly,William. 2003. "CanForeignAid Buy
reduces the efficiency of manufacturinginvest- Growth?"Journal of Economic Perspectives,
ment by adversely affecting governance, and 17(3):23-48.
thus contracting, then aid inflows may reduce Easterly,William,Ross Levine,and David Rood-
the profitabilityof investmentand limit growth, man. 2004. "Aid,Policies, and Growth:Com-
especially in export sectors that have tradition- ment." American Economic Review, 94(3):
ally provedto be the engine of growth. 774-80.
None of these effects is inevitable, though Hansen,Henrik,and Finn Tarp. 2001. "Aid and
they are not easily resolvedeither.An important GrowthRegressions."JournalofDevelopment
step for both aid givers and aid recipients is to Economics,64(2): 547-70.
recognize thataid inflowsarenot an unmitigated Johnson, Simon, Jonathan Ostry, and Arvind
blessing, and that the worst thing that can hap- Subramanian.2007. "Africa'sGrowth Pros-
pen with a greaterquantityof aid is not only that pects:Benchmarkingthe Constraints."Interna-
it will be wasted. More aid, if ineffectively used, tionalMonetaryFundWorkingPaper07/52.
can actually set back a country in its path to Jones, Benjamin F., and Benjamin A. Olken.
development.This is why it is extremelyimpor- 2005. "The Anatomy of Stop-Start Growth."
tantto examine ways of improvingaid effective- NationalBureauof EconomicResearchWork-
ness, recognizing that the state of knowledge ing Paper11528.
here is limited. Open-mindedness,allowing for Levchenko,Andrei A. "InstitutionalQuality and
various approachesto aid delivery and utiliza- InternationalTrade."Unpublished.
tion, is essential here. Rajan, RaghuramG., and Luigi Zingales. 1998.
Finally, it is importantto recognize thatwhile "FinancialDependence and Growth."Ameri-
aid is essential in situations of humanitarian can EconomicReview,88(3):559-86.
need, it is probablylikely to play a much smaller Rajan,RaghuramG., and ArvindSubramanian.
part in the process of economic growth. The 2005a. "AidandGrowth:WhatDoes the Cross-
sooner countries recognize that aid is no pana- Country Evidence Really Show?" National
cea, the less likely they are to postponedevelop- Bureauof Economic ResearchWorkingPaper
ment indefinitely. 11513.
Rajan,RaghuramG., and ArvindSubramanian.
REFERENCES 2005b. "What Undermines Aid's Impact
on Growth?"National Bureau of Economic
Blanchard,Olivier, and Michael Kremer. 1997. ResearchWorkingPaper11657.
"Disorganization."QuarterlyJournal of Eco- Roodman,David. 2004. "The Anarchyof Num-
nomics, 112(4):1091-1126. bers: Aid, Development, and Cross-Country
Brautigam,DeborahA., and StephenKnack.2004. Empirics." Center for Global Development
"ForeignAid, Institutions,and Governancein WorkingPaper32.

This content downloaded from 128.135.215.125 on Mon, 30 Nov 2015 16:34:29 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like