You are on page 1of 20

Article

Journal of Planning Literature


1-20
Modes of Informal Urban Development: ª The Author(s) 2017
Reprints and permission:
sagepub.com/journalsPermissions.nav
A Global Phenomenon DOI: 10.1177/0885412217737340
journals.sagepub.com/home/jpl

Richard Harris1

Abstract
The concept of informality has often been misunderstood. Its, especially, urban character is rarely appreciated. With respect to
urban development, it was once thought to distinguish the Global South, a view that is changing, but an alternative has not been
systematically articulated. Based on an extensive survey of literatures, this article clarifies the urban character of informality,
articulates its global relevance, and proposes a framework for understanding its major modes: latent, diffuse, embedded, overt,
and dominant. Their relative frequency distinguishes cities, regions, and nations while their identification facilitates the
comparison of places.

Keywords
housing, international planning and development, planning law, planning, theory, real estate, urban history, economic development

Many of those who have written about urban planning have Scope and Definition
treated informal development as a black hole: something that
First, it must be said that the concept of informality has been
exists but which can be observed only indirectly and which for
much abused and misunderstood. It has been defined narrowly,
most purposes can be ignored. North American textbooks have
loosely, and in various ways. It has been applied to the econ-
routinely ignored the topic (e.g., Cullingworth and Caves
omy as a whole, and also to the specific process of urban
2014). So, too, did a recent award-winning survey of Planning
Ideas that Matter (Sanyal, Vale, and Rosan 2012). Even a development, but rarely by the same people or in the same
breath. Arguably, its especially urban character has been too
forthcoming Handbook on Planning History barely touches the
rarely appreciated. With respect to urban development, it was
issue, although its global scope embraces world regions where
once supposed to distinguish the global South. Neuwirth (2006)
informality is still the norm (Hein 2018). Implicitly, many
suggested that there were a billion squatters worldwide, but
writers have assumed that informality represents the failure,
none of the contemporary places that he featured were in the
or the limitations, of planning, and lies beyond its scope.
North; Connolly (2009, 20) has shown that “irregular” settle-
This view is not ubiquitous. Some urbanists have pointed
ment, defined broadly, accounts for half of all dwellings in
out that it is not only planners who execute plans: developers
frame subdivisions, owner builders frame houses, and all of Mexico City, but no one has made comparable calculations for
London, England, or my hometown, Hamilton, Ontario. That
them plan. This assertion can obscure the distinction between
said, opinion is changing: more writers recognize that inform-
what is legal and what is not, a difference that always matters,
ality takes many forms and exists everywhere, but a consistent
but it is not mere pedantry: students and practitioners of plan-
method of comparing cities has not been articulated. Based on
ning should remember that rational, considered action with
an extensive survey of literatures, this article clarifies the urban
respect to the built environment is not their sole preserve.
character of informality, articulates its relevance to all societ-
Building on this understanding, many have argued that the
ies, and proposes a conceptual framework within which the
boundaries between formal and informal are usually blurred.
The two coexist and are interdependent, while “insurgent” experience of particular cities and nations can be compared.
Following Feige (1990, 990), I understand informality to be
planning can incorporate informal practices and so render them
“those actions of economic agents that fail to adhere to the
legitimate (Briassoulis 1997; Chalana and Hou 2016; Dupont
et al. 2016; Miraftab 2009). At the extreme, informality
becomes so widespread that it defines the entire planning
regime (Roy 2009). Indeed, an extensive body of work on 1
School of Geography and Earth Sciences, McMaster University, Ontario,
informal urban development in the global South has empha- Canada
sized its ubiquity while noting wide local and regional varia-
Corresponding Author:
tions. The purpose of this article is to take stock of and Richard Harris, School of Geography and Earth Sciences, McMaster University,
reinterpret this work, concluding with some suggestions as to Hamilton, Ontario, Canada L8S 4K1.
how we can come to terms with that diversity within ubiquity. Email: harrisr@mcmaster.ca
2 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

established institutional rules or are denied their protection” planning and research. Having discussed a particular meaning
(cf. Portes and Haller 2005, 404). This is now a widely of the term and acknowledged its limitations (section 1), I
accepted definition. It highlights the relationship between the develop the argument that it is peculiarly urban in character
state and society, while—in principle—lending itself to precise and geographically ubiquitous (sections 2 and 3). Once we
identification: either an activity that is governed by rules con- understand why it exists (section 4), it becomes possible and
forms to regulation or it does not. In practice, its application has arguably useful to distinguish five modal forms (section 5).
been inconsistent, because writers have blurred different defi- These I label latent, diffuse, embedded, overt, and dominant.
nitions and because activities that, in one context, are illegal, or As I suggest in the conclusion, this framework helps us to make
at least “irregular” may, at another time and place, be perfectly sense of the rich body of evidence on informal urban develop-
acceptable. A common example is when residents use cast-off ment while pointing to ways in which it can be compared and
materials to erect shacks. There can be good reasons for study- consolidated.
ing all such instances, but it is also important to distinguish
those that violate regulations from those that do not.
Imprecise or inconsistent usage has blurred the fact that
The Character and Limitations of “Informal”
informality is peculiarly relevant to urban settings and notably Until at least the 1990s, most writers assumed that nations in
with respect to land development. Urban land is distinctive in the global North and South developed in different ways and
that social and economic pressures almost compel it to become that to understand them we needed different conceptual tools.
real estate—a commodity. Then, too, proximity increases the One way the South was seen to be different was in the extent of
impact of externalities, which requires the regulation of land informality. Initially, simplifying the influential arguments of
use, construction, and occupancy. Regulation requires a greater Hart, many spoke of a distinctive “informal sector” which
role for the state and, by extension, more potential informality. reformulated the old distinction between tradition and moder-
In a village, amateur builders are unexceptionable; in a city, nity (Leaf 2005, 112; cf. Hart 2010; Tabak 2000, 5). After this
they may become unacceptable. The change often begins, and view was widely critiqued (e.g., Moser 1984; Peattie 1987,
may be most apparent, in peri-urban or suburban contexts 1995), many came to see informality as any activity that chal-
where rural land is dragged, sometimes kicking and screaming, lenged or evaded state regulation and taxes (Castells and Portes
into the urban fold. 1989; Portes and Haller 2005). In a context where neoliberal
In principle, these considerations apply equally in New policies in the North were promoting deregulation, many con-
York and Kolkata, or for that matter in Eldoret, Kenya, and cluded that the concept had relevance everywhere (Gaffikin,
Hamilton. In practice, they are manifested in different ways. Perry, and Kundu 2011; Sassen 1988–1989; Tabak and
One way of putting this would be to say that there are degrees Critchlow 2000).
of informality, Kolkata having more and Hamilton less. That is This understanding—of the pervasive, global character of
a reasonable approximation, one implied by many writers (cf. informality—has not yet reshaped the way scholars think about
Van Gelder 2010). But it can be carried further and made more urban development. Most of those who have written about the
useful. In many fields of social life, including politics and the informal economy have paid “astonishingly” little attention to
economy, quantitative growth can produce qualitative change. the built environment: major surveys have ignored this topic
As a threshold is crossed, a modal shift occurs: with enough (Altroc 2012, 172; Castells and Portes 1989; Gërxhani 2004;
potential customers, a service can be provided, a large enough Lagos 1995; Losby et al. 2002; Portes and Haller 2005; but see
demonstration may topple a government, or the changing com- Hansen and Vaa 2004; McFarlane and Waibel 2012). Even
position of a neighborhood crosses a tipping point (Granovetter rarer have been attempts to comprehend the interrelation of the
1978). So it is with informality. My argument is that it is not the various types of informalities (Kudva 2009). This is curious: as
presence or even just the extent of informality that distin- Hansen and Vaa (2004, 18) note, de facto informality in urban
guishes places, but its modal mix. housing is more visible and probably better documented than
The argument can be developed in analytical terms but gains any other of its forms (Hansen and Vaa 2004, 18). But, from the
resonance when infused with historical understanding. The 1960s, those who wrote about urban development were slow to
term and concept of informality has a history that still informs adopt the language of informality. As late as 1984, Caroline
its meaning; its form is shaped by the juxtaposition of differing Moser, who had previously written about squatter settlements
systems of property, often a colonial legacy; its presence com- in Ecuador, was able to survey the literature on the “informal
monly arises because of a temporal disjuncture—regulations sector” without reference to the processes of urban develop-
may be imposed far ahead of any need— or they may lag ment. Because the most striking examples of informality take
behind dynamic urban growth. And so informality is always the form of squatting, initially in Latin America, many still
in flux, its growth or decline being generated “passively” by a treat the concept as synonymous with the unauthorized settle-
new regulation or through the actions of the regulated (Castells ment of land (e.g., Huchzermeyer and Karam 2006; Van Gelder
and Portes 1989, 298–99; Van Gelder 2013, 509). A snapshot 2013; cf. Laquian 1964; Mangin 1967; Turner 1963, 1967).
misses its causal dynamic. Others view it as a catchall for irregularity, self-help and grass-
Recognizing this dynamic, this article aims to clarify the roots spontaneity, lack of basic services, or even the absence of
global relevance of the concept of informality for urban professional design (AlSayyad 2004; Berner 2012; Birch,
Harris 3

Chattaraj, and Wachter 2016; Gouverneur 2015; Hernández, is one of six features that enabled the rise of the West, one
Kellett, and Allen 2010). And so Klaufus and Lindert (2012, which was indissolubly linked to the rise of capitalism. Waller-
70) speak of it as a “container notion,” while Fischer, stein (2012, 7) has claimed that establishing “a systematic legal
McCann, and Auyeroo (2014, 1) use it to refer to basis for what it called title to land” was “the single most
“underserviced, poor, [or] legally precarious” settlements. important change imposed by the modern world system.” A
Indeed, in an influential survey, Davis (2006) referred version of this belief was long held by colonial, and now post-
vaguely to an “informal sector,” long after development econ- colonial powers, as well as international agencies such as the
omists had abandoned that term. Such catchall definitions World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (De Soto
lead to unhelpful generalizations. For example, AlSayyad’s 2000; Large 1973; Simpson 1976; Weaver 2003; cf. Mooya
(2004) suggestion that informal practices have been the his- 2011). One consequence of colonization is that, everywhere
torical norm blurs the precise impact of regulation. from Africa to Asia and the Middle East, new understandings
Slowly, however, usage has converged on an argument that of landed property have challenged established traditions and
urban informality exists in relation to the state (e.g., Guha- lifeways (Benda-Beckman 2001; Krueckeberg 1999; Leaf
Khasnobis, Kanbur, and Ostrom 2006). The most articulate and 1993; McAuslan 2000; Razzaz 1994). And in other regions,
influential scholar has been Ananya Roy, who has suggested the situation was complicated by the introduction, and subse-
that informality is a mode of urban development and, in a book quent removal, of state communism. Land tenure in Eastern
and several papers, framed the argument that “the state has the Europe and China still has something of that overlay (McGee
power . . . to determine what is informal and what is not” (Roy et al. 2007, 73; Li and Huang 2012; Shieh 2011; Verdery 1999).
2005, 149; cf. Roy 2003, 2009, 2011). This is true by definition, Here, the meaning of informality is open to debate.
but Roy also means that informality is politically constructed: The property systems exported by European powers were
states are not neutral arbiters, politicians and officials have themselves more complicated than is often supposed: in Anglo-
interests, and both manipulate the boundaries of informality American law, there are approximately fifty forms of land
to suit their own ends. Those are important insights which I tenure (Doebele 1983, 70–71), and their basis differs from the
will argue are relevant to our understanding of the modal forms regimes exported by France and Spain, as all three do from the
that informality can take. But much informality never rises to Sharia law established under Ottoman rule and now dominant
the level of public debate or political calculation: it involves the in the Middle East. Hence, although no squatters have auto-
inadvertent violation of regulations, the existence of which matic rights in the British excolonies, in Argentina they have
state agencies are barely aware and not much interested in; it the right to land after twenty years of peaceful possession,
commonly involves people who, far from wishing to challenge while in Jordan or Turkey they may only need to erect a roofed
the state, are eager to keep their activities hidden from it (Bayat dwelling overnight (Neuwirth 2006, 143–73; Razzaz 1994,
2000, 550). The state defines what is informal, but whether 28n16; Van Gelder 2010, 251n9; Yonder 1987). Colonial pow-
planners and other state agents are always conscious of that ers exported their systems of property in a variety of contexts
power and use it is an open question. (Simpson 1976). One way of generalizing this is to say that this
If urbanists have been slow to view informality as being introduced “individualistic” forms of ownership to societies
framed by state regulation, it may be because they realize that whose understanding of land was communal (e.g., Porter
it provides limited guidance on how to handle nonstate sources 2011, 116). But some writers argue that this is a false binary
of legitimacy. Such sources are often present. There may exist a (Benda-Beckman, Benda-Beckman, and Wiber 2006; Kruecke-
widespread feeling that the law is unjust. Thus, students of berg 1999). After all, individualistic systems make provision
squatting have emphasized that settlers commonly believe their for restraints that embody the public interest, while the com-
actions to be a reasonable response to their desperate, unsatis- munal label is a catchall that can be “so vague as to be mis-
fied need for shelter (e.g., Cornelius 1976, 255; Fernandes and leading in virtually any specific situation” (Bruce 1988, 24). In
Varley 1998, 4; Jenkins 2009, 103; Smart 1999, 104). Resi- sum, the encounter of two systems of landed property has been
dents of favelas have no doubts about their right to live where common and hardly ever neat, while taking different forms
and how they do (Perlman 1976).Such beliefs are further legit- around the world.
imized where two or more systems of law coexist. As Simon As a result, it is normal for two or more systems of property
(1992, 109) has observed, “settlement which is officially to coexist or intersect (Durand-Lasserve 1990; McAuslan
deemed illegal in terms of Western law, may be perfectly legit- 2002). Such situations are common enough in Latin America
imate according to customary law.” Legal pluralism has been (Connolly 2009; Santos 1977; Wigle 2010), South Asia (Ben-
discussed in general treatments of local, regional, and national jamin 2004; Kundu 2002), and Southeast Asia (Erni and Bian-
economies (Benda-Beckman 2001; Benton 1994; Griffiths poen 1980, 71; Colombijn 2010; Evers and Korff 2000; Leaf
1986; Tamanaha 2000). Arguably, it is especially important for 1993), while being routine in West (Aronson 1978; Durand-
understanding the process of urban development. In all preur- Lasserve, Durand-Lasserve, and Selid 2015; Grant 2009, 118–
ban societies, land is the main source of wealth. Its commodi- 20; Ikejiofor 2006) and in Central and East Africa (Jenkins
fication and formalization, above all in an urban context, have 2004; Nkurunziza 2007; Trefon 2004). It may be impossible
been vital for economic growth, development, and moderniza- to reconcile juxtaposed sources of legitimacy. Illustrating this,
tion. At any rate, Ferguson (2011) suggests that property rights Simpson (1976, 224) repeats the apocryphal statement of an
4 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

African chief that in his culture “land belongs to a vast family everywhere, most commonly in rural areas. But when defined
of which many are dead, few are living and countless numbers in relation to state regulation, its urban nature stands out.
are still unborn,” an understanding not readily melded with Historians and economists agree that when the market value
British law. Commonly, however, the result is a hybrid of property increases so, too, does the pressure to establish
arrangement, usually tipping toward some version of the West- “hard-edged rules to manage it” (Rose 1994, 199; cf. Barzel
ern model (Erni and Bianpoen 1980; Leaf 2009, 59; Myers 1989; Demsetz 1967). This is demonstrably true for land, even
2011; Trefon 2004, 4). This can be messy. Aronson (1978) in rural areas as they are drawn into the global economy (Feeny
discusses a case where family-owned land in Ibadan, Nigeria, 1988; Platteau 2002). It is doubly true in urban settings, where
was “sold” to a single individual even though only seven of the land prices are typically much higher (Dunkerley 1983, 7).
twenty-five people who had rights to the property had been Steeper prices encourage careful measurement, documentation,
consulted—a recipe for dispute; Holston (2008) identifies six and enforcement of property boundaries. That is why, soon
types of informal settlements in Brazil; Benjamin (2004) finds after Hong Kong was founded by the British, a precise land
ten forms of tenure in Bangalore, while Soliman (2004) reports survey was introduced; much later, as land values soared, a
bewildering variety in Cairo. The rise of Western property law resurvey was undertaken to higher standards of precision (Nis-
took centuries (e.g., Karr 2015; Springett 1982), and its victory sim 2008, 137). An analogous process has been described for
is complete nowhere. Even in the United States today, land is cities in sub-Saharan Africa, where urban conditions have fos-
not always, simply, “money with trees on it” (Large 1973, tered individual ownership (Dickerman 1988, 84–85). Urban
1081). In other words, there are more dimensions to property proximity also increases the impact of externalities, such as
rights than are implied by the concept of informality. those generated by noise or pollution, whose incidence declines
As if this were not complex enough, even state law can be away from the source. Their control therefore requires the reg-
contradictory; government often fails to speak with a single ulation of land use, construction, and occupancy. As a result, no
voice (Smart 1999). Research in Istanbul, Amman (Jordan), type of place is more carefully regulated than a city.
Kolkata, and Lisbon, for example, has revealed ambiguities Although we often assume that regulation is imposed by the
in the law (Kuyucu 2014) and lack of official consensus (Raz- state, many restraints have been a response to pressure from
zaz 1994, 33); that state agencies may violate their own regu- private agents (Ben-Joseph 2005, 187–88). Indeed, some land
lations (Roy 2009, 81) or fail to coordinate their actions (Soares use planning and enforcement are still undertaken by private or
and Stüssi 1990, 256). Especially where irregular development civil society organizations. In the United States, zoning and
is common, there is often a difference in attitude between per- building regulations were often introduced by land developers
missive politicians and political parties, which aim to cultivate as a marketing strategy (Weiss 1987). Their modern counter-
votes, and officials whose job is to enforce the law (Roy 2003, parts cater to a growing demand for common-interest develop-
144–46). Sometimes official agencies flout that law; the ments; some of which are gated, privately regulated, and
Hyderabad Development Agency once acted as an illegal sub- guarded (McKenzie 2011). There are now many parallels to
divider (Payne 1989, 41). Agencies express different interests; such private forms of planning elsewhere in the world (e.g.,
legislators create laws that officials fail to enforce; local and Andersson and Moroni 2014; Hudalah and Firman 2012;
national governments may not think alike. The gap between Glasze, Webster, and Frantz 2006). Nair (2005, 133–34), for
municipalities and governments with wider regional or national example, has shown that in Bangalore it is private companies
responsibility is especially common. It is one of many anarchic that cater to the demand for thoroughly planned and tightly
elements in Kinshasa (de Boek 2012, 317) and a major feature regulated projects. But in most cities, the first dominant agent
of urbanization in China (Leaf 2002, 2007, 182; Ma 2013; Sun of documentation, regulation, and enforcement—whether of
and Liu 2015). Clearly, then, the concept of informality alone land titles, contracts, or of building, land use, and occupancy
does not capture the full complexity of property law, and hence regulations—is the state. That is why government regulations
the role and capacity of municipal planning. are more common in urban areas, and why the scope of inform-
None of this means that we should abandon the concept or ality is greater there.
seek another definition. In some places and times, as is appar- That potential is not always realized (Portes and Haller
ently case in Recife, Brazil, formal rights are not hegemonic 2005, 409). Rule breaking is not always common in urban
(Fischer 2016, 142). But there are few places where the state is areas. Its incidence usually depends on the state’s desire and
not the dominant agency of social legitimation, with a mono- capacity to enforce its laws, set against the willingness and
poly on the legitimate use of force. Informality, as it is defined ability of local residents to meet them. But as the number
here, is not a sufficient conceptual tool in understanding urban and scope of regulations increase so does the range of pos-
development, but it is necessary. sible violations, not to mention sources of conflict and cor-
ruption. A recent study has confirmed that the incidence of
informality and bribery increases with the degree of regula-
The Peculiarly Urban, and Suburban,
tion: in this regard, Asia is more extreme than Latin Amer-
Character of Informality ica (Monkkonen and Ronconi 2016, 44). It may well be that
If informality is understood to include inadequate shelters that the most institutionally corrupt places are big cities, where
lack piped water and sanitation, then it can be found regulation is most common.
Harris 5

Historically and geographically, the urban fringe has been may become informal, usually because new regulations make it
the thin end of the wedge. As cities grow, development pushes so. In Indonesia, as urban development and regulation encom-
outward. In regulated environments, this takes the form of passed kampungs (villages), these became “unplanned” and
suburbs: compact, continuous development. Where there are problematic (Erni and Bianpoen 1980); at the fringe of Beirut,
fewer controls, development sprawls discontinuously into development in Hayy el Sellom became illegal when zoning
exurban or peri-urban territory. It may take years or decades regulations were introduced (Fawaz 2008, 573); on the Zim-
for such areas to become fully urbanized. This can produce merman estate in Mathare Valley, a suburb of Nairobi, legal
striking juxtapositions in land use (Fureseth and Lapping ownership dissolved into uncertainty as land transfers were
1999; Ginsburg 1991; Simon 2008). In Southeast Asia, McGee made without registration (Gatabaki-Kamau and Karirah-
(1991) has named this transitional territory desakota (desa ¼ Gitau 2004, 164–67); in the peri-urban areas of Egyptian cities,
town, kota ¼ village), and Harms (2011, 18) has described a Soliman (2004, 188) reports similar shifts, so that housing
typical scene outside Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam: “the land- becomes “exformal” (cf. Sims 2010). In the long run, however,
scape emerges as a collection of juxtapositions: buffaloes bathe the commonest transition is for informal settlements to
in front of factory gates, rubber cutout soles from the local shoe become, or through “negotiation” to be accepted as, formal
factory line the dirt roads leading to rice fields . . . and fancy (Baross and van der Linden 1990, 8). This can take decades.
multi-colored concrete-covered aluminum-trimmed multilevel The best-documented examples are in Latin America (Bider-
brick houses with gingerbread rooftops rise up next to shacks man and Smolka 2012; Ward, Huerta, and Di Virgilio 2014).
made of scrap metal and plywood.” As rural and fringe land is Examples include Mexico City (Duhau 2014; Wigle 2010),
converted to urban use, it jumps in value and so do the stakes, Cochabamba, Bolivia (Goldstein 2004), Rio de Janeiro (Hol-
the need for precision, the impact of externalities, and the like- ston 2008), and Caracas (Karst 1971). But this is not the only
lihood of conflict. Razzaz (1994) has provided a fine example world region where the “proper” sequence of planning–servi-
of this process in his study of the settlement of Yajouz, Jordan, cing–construction has been reversed (Durand-Lasserve 1998,
as it became a suburb of Amman, while Kombe (2000) has 239; cf. Baross 1990). For example, revisiting Accra’s urban
shown something similar for suburban Dar es Salaam. In such fringe after ten years, Gough and Yankson (2006) were able to
places, conditions may improve over time, but as regulations document very much the same trend.
proliferate so does the potential for informality. Around Accra, Mexico City, Nairobi, and Beirut, the
Where the regulations are established early, where rates of growth of regulation sometimes does more than increase the
urbanization are slow, and where states are strong, the whole amount of informality. The encroachment of urban land uses
process may be planned. Today, this is the norm in Northwes- prompts changes in the property regime from traditional/com-
tern Europe, somewhat less so in the United States. Elsewhere, munal to Western/individualistic. Suburbs and the peri-urban
the agents of planning and commodification are private devel- fringe are where the juxtapositions, conflicts, and compro-
opers or individuals, squatter settlements being the obvious mises of legal pluralism are most apparent. Many of the
example (cf. Balaban 2010). Here, the absence of land use or best-documented examples of pluralistic informality have
building regulation often means that the only informal element been situated here (e.g., Friedmann 2011; Gough and Yank-
is the absence of land rights. The earliest, well-documented son 2006; Kasanga, Cochrane, and Roth 1996; Keyder 2000;
examples occurred in Latin America in the 1950s and 1960s Leaf 2002, 2009, 2011; Leduka 2006; Razzaz 1994; Simon
(Mangin 1967; Turner 1963, 1967). Here, the boundaries of 1992, 114; 2008, 171). Around Accra, for example, much land
building sites were at first loosely defined and their price was is still nominally held by the community and controlled by the
zero. But as settlement proceeded, dwellings were improved so chiefs of indigenous estates, but a market has emerged to
that densities increased, markets emerged, boundaries shar- allow outsiders to buy in (Gough 1999, 400). Newcomers
pened, and entrepreneurs became involved (e.g., Duhau form associations to regulate land use, creating a form of
2014; Goldstein 2004; Karst 1971). Although most observers governance that conforms neither to custom nor to state reg-
of squatter settlements have emphasized the markets in prop- ulation. If cities contain the greatest potential for informality,
erty ownership, informal rental arrangements also became it is in the suburbs that it may take uniquely complex forms
common (Gilbert 2012). Often, neither landlords nor tenants and pose exceptional challenges for planners.
understand the law, and both shun the costs of litigation. As
Amis (1984) documented for Nairobi, and as many other writ-
ers have shown since, informality is no barrier to the growth of
A Southern Perspective
markets, whether in land itself or tenancy (cf. Razzaz 1998). It is no accident that most of the research and examples men-
But the pressures for formalization increase. Fringe settlements tioned above are in the global South. Until recently, almost all
become urban neighborhoods and, often, local governments discussions of informality in urban development focused on
recognize their right to exist (e.g., Connolly 2009). In so doing cities or the urban fringe there. A recent international encyclo-
informality is eliminated. pedia of housing, for example, included surveys of informality
The transitional character of suburban informality shows the in Asia and Latin America, but only one marginal entry on the
importance of an historical perspective: transitions can go issue in the global North (Berner 2012; Klaufus and Lindert
either way. Especially in the short run, what was once legal 2012; Smith 2012; cf. Mukhija 2012). A few scholars have
6 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

noted that informality, in some sense, had once existed in the (Allen et al. 2004, 176; Leontidou 1990; Soares and Stüssi
North. Neuwirth (2006), for example, speaks of the squatters 1990) and in parts of what was until 1989 the eastern bloc
that once occupied what became New York’s Central Park (cf. (Berry and McGreal 1995; Hirt 2012; Nientied 1998; Tsenkova
Anders and Sedlmaier 2016; de Soto 2000), while Goff (2016) and French 2011, 62). In North America, the colonias settle-
and Jindrich (2016) have recently amplified America’s history ments in Texas and California that hug the Mexican border
of informal development. Some have even noted in passing have been labeled as a type of informal settlement, sometimes
that, as a matter of fact, informality does exist in the North, misleadingly because many are unregulated (Larson 1995,
but their focus was elsewhere (Fernandes and Varley 1998; 2002; Mukhija 2012; Mukhija and Monkkonen 2006; Ward
Fischer, McCann, and Auyero 2014; Leaf 2005, 125; Gaffikin, 1999, 2004). Many observers have assumed that informality
Perry, and Kundu 2011, 310–15; Peattie 1995, 406; Roy 2005, is largely confined to this region (Larson 2002). In fact, that
148). And so, overwhelmingly, those interested in the global is not so (Ward and Peters 2007). But, in political and eco-
South appear to suppose, or imply, that informality is some- nomic terms, areas such as the colonias lie outside the main-
thing that sets that region apart. This is apparent in the surveys stream, embodying the conventional view of urban informality
of slums and urban development that have been published since in the North.
the 1960s, none of which have found it useful to draw parallels Recently, however, the stereotypes and conceptual barriers
with the North (Acioly 2010; AlSayyad 2004; Baross and van have started to come down. In the global South, more research-
der Linden 1990; Davis 2006; de Soto 2000; Durand-Lasserve ers now recognize that formal and informal developments are
1990, 1998; Fernandes and Varley 1998; Gilbert 1992; Gilbert interrelated. An early and influential argument along these
and Ward 1985; Huchzermeyer and Karam 2006; Lloyd 1979; lines was made by Perlman (1976) with respect to Rio de
Mathey 1997; Payne 1989; Perlman 1976; Potter 1999; Pugh Janeiro’s favelas. It makes sense that they would often be adja-
1997; Rodwin 1987; United Nations - Habitat 2004; Van cent or intermingled, and that illegal settlements produce
Gelder 2013; van Vliet 1987). In an influential early text, for externalities that reduce the property values of the affluent
example, Abrams (1964, 41) devotes only one page to a com- (Cavalcanti 2014; Dupont and Houssay-Holzshuch 2005,
parison of “more and less developed countries,” emphasizing 296). Writers have also shown that informality is not confined
that housing problems in these regions are of a “different to low-income districts (Fischer, McCann, and Auyero 2014;
order,” in part because of contrasting legal norms regarding Roy 2011, 233). Indeed, it may be concentrated at both ends of
land ownership and regulation. A different tack was taken by the class spectrum, albeit for different reasons. Pamuk (1996,
John Turner who argued that the Latin American experience of 2000), for example, speaks about the presence of “informal
owner building did indeed hold lessons for the developed world institutions” in both the poorer and the richer areas of Istanbul
(Turner and Fichter 1972; cf. Harris 2003). Turner, however, and Trinidad, while Soni (2000, 76) has documented illegally
employed neither the label nor the concept of informality as it built “palatial mansions” in peri-urban Delhi. Such situations in
is understood here. In general, then, surveys and studies of the part reflect the weak, or corrupt, character of many state agen-
Southern informality assumed that fundamentally different cies in the Global South, but researchers have begun to show
rules applied there. that informality exists within the North (Durst and Wegmann
The favor has been returned. There is a massive literature on 2017). This understanding has emerged most fully in Los
urban development in the North. Unavoidably, many studies Angeles, where researchers have documented backyard homes,
discuss how builders, developers, and residents violate those accessory units erected in violation of zoning, and often build-
regulations, an issue I discuss later. But this is treated as a ing regulations (Bell 2014; Cuff, Higgins, and Dahl 2010;
marginal matter. Clawson’s classic account of suburban land Mukhija 2014; Wegmann 2015). Some might see this, too, as
development in the United States makes only passing reference a local phenomenon, an effect of large-scale Hispanic migra-
to the way building inspectors can turn a “blind eye” to infrac- tion. As the editors of a recent volume note, informality has
tions (Clawson 1971, 105); Ben-Joseph (2005), surveying the been assumed to be “either limited in scope . . . or criminal”
various regulations that shape American cities, ignores eva- (Mukhija and Loukaitou-Sideris 2014, 3). But they, and the
sions or violations; while Evans (2004a, 2004b), in a systematic contributors to their collection, argue otherwise. And so a small
survey of urban real estate and planning, does not suggest that but growing number of researchers have begun to deploy the
informality is an issue. language of informality to understand other types of quasi-legal
Until very recently, few writers conceived of illegal or non- and nonconforming urban settlements, including squatting
conforming urban development in the global North as exam- (Aguilera and Smart 2016), the creation of secondary suites
ples of informality. In modern encyclopedias, handbooks, and (Mendez and Quastel 2016; Tanasescu 2009), and the methods
readers on housing in North America and Europe, there has by which many Americans finance their homes (Way 2010).
been hardly any reference to the concept (e.g., Carswell Finally, then, if tentatively, urban researchers are putting
2012; Huttman and van Vliet 1998; Tighe and Mueller 2013; into practice the injunction, best articulated by Jenny Robinson
van Vliet 1988). When acknowledged, illegality has usually (2002, 2005), that we should transcend continental boundaries
been understood to be geographically marginal and of local and learn from the global South. There is no better subject on
significance (e.g., Yiftachel 2009). For example, some observ- which to carry out this project than that of informality, the
ers have noted its concentration in cities in Southern Europe leading aspect of urban life which is supposed to set the South
Harris 7

apart. The question is how best to bridge the divide. I believe developers, politicians, and home buyers rode the wave. The
that the concept of “modes of informality” can help but, result in Ireland, for example, was that officials “allowed a kind
because the identification of these modes depends on the var- of honor code building inspection” (Daley 2013).
ious ways in which they arise, it is first necessary to consider Zoning and occupancy codes are also widely “negotiated,”
why informality exists. perhaps especially in the most regulated places. In a neolib-
eral political environment, land use regulation has become
negotiable, a practice common with “inclusionary housing”
Why Informality Exists (Selmi 2009). A currently favored method of producing
Informality commonly arises for a combination of reasons. affordable housing requires developers to include a minimum
There are four possibilities: residents are unable or unwilling proportion of cheaper units, usually on the quid pro quo that
to conform to regulations; the state may be unable or unwilling they may bend other rules, such as height restrictions. Such
to enforce them. In practice, two or more of these are usually in formalized informality is paralleled by more familiar, illegal
play, and sometimes all four, at which point it becomes possi- types. In London, England, the exorbitant cost of housing has
ble to speak about a planning regime that is defined by inform- produced a rash of “sheds with beds”: backyard structures
ality. Those who have sought to explain the prevalence of turned into rental units, where landlords often withhold
informality have emphasized its political dynamic, focusing tenancy agreements (O’Sullivan 2012). In Los Angeles,
on why residents might flout or why state agencies might tol- although only a handful have been approved, thousands of
erate—even welcome—informal arrangements (Dupont et al. backyard dwellings have been built (Cuff Higgins, and Dahl
2016; Gilbert 1990; Payne 1989, 37–41; Ray 1969; Roy 2005; 2010, 7; Mukhija 2014; Wegmann 2015). In San Francisco, a
Smart 1999, 2001, 32; Varley 1998; cf. Castells and Portes city report indicates that three-quarters of Airbnb listings are
1989). Their arguments challenge the naive assumption that illegal (Brinklow 2016); in New York City, Cox and Slee
such practices simply reflect the inadequacy of the resources (2016) have estimated that in 2015 about 21,000 housing units
that are available to everyone involved. But if resources are were listed on Airbnb, even though state law prohibits the
never a sufficient explanation, they are always vital. rental of “entire homes.” But on this issue, as with illegal
The obvious examples are the squatter settlements of Latin conversions, city inspectors usually just respond to com-
America in the 1950s and 1960s, of Asia from the 1970s, and of plaints (Wesseler 2015). Proactive enforcement is a luxury
Africa and parts of eastern Europe since the 1980s. These and systematic enforcement unknown.
emerged because of the large-scale rural–urban migration of On a more modest scale, my hometown, Hamilton, Ontario,
people too poor to afford decent accommodation and where provides a full range of examples. With a population of half a
municipalities lacked the resources to house or regulate them million, Hamilton is a classic “ordinary city” (Robinson 2005).
(Davis 2006; Doebele 1977, 532; Hansen and Vaa 2004, 12; It developed as a manufacturing center, stagnated, and has
Leaf 2005; Neuwirth 2006; Tsenkova and French 2011). This is lately thrived, as it has been drawn into Toronto’s commu-
still true. In Brazil, for example, governments have cleared tershed (Harris Forthcoming). Historically, it had its share of
some favelas, rehousing a few residents, while trying to tame “slums,” a term which embraced a range of conditions but
and regulate others, but to limited effect (Perlman 2010). Ren- which included many properties that contravened health, zon-
ters in such settlements are the poorest and least secure, in part ing, building, and housing bylaws (Weaver 1982; cf. Ackerman
because landlords ignore relevant laws even when such exist 1971). Lately, although it has been growing much more slowly
(Gilbert 2012). More recently, in China since the 1990s, infor- than Lima in the 1950s or Shenzhen in the 2000s, the city’s
mal “small property rights” housing has accommodated mil- permitting and inspection staffs have been overwhelmed. In
lions of migrants for the same reasons (Sun and Liu 2015). 2007, a third of new homes were started before a permit was
Even in China, where the state has built whole new cities, there issued (Buist 2007). Subsequently, staffing levels fell while
has been a widespread lack of capacity. construction increased, a side effect of which has been that
But it is not just the global South that lacks resources, as the many locally active builders have not been registered with the
history of building and land regulation in America demon- provincial organization that guarantees building standards (van
strates. A tragic example of the importance of building regula- Dongen 2013; “Illegal Building . . . ” 2016). In 2014, an audit
tion was the Chicago fire of 1871, but those introduced found that although all businesses in the city were supposed to
afterward came with “no provisions for effective enforcement” be licensed, 684 had been overlooked, including 300 food out-
(Rosen 1986, 107). Half a century later, a national survey noted lets (van Dongen 2014). At the same time, a developer demol-
that building permit requirements were often ignored, espe- ished an historic church without getting the necessary
cially in suburban areas, while a study of Queen’s, New York approvals (“A church’s new face” 2014). A year later, the city
City, in the 1930s found numerous violations (U.S. Bureau of demanded improvements from the owners of a deteriorated
Labor Statistics 1922, 6; Comer 1942, 191). The twenty-first high-rise building, but their efforts were ineffectual and squat-
century has not eliminated the problem and its accompaniment, ters soon occupied vacant units (Craggs 2015; “150
bribery (Listokin and Hattis 2005, 36). Everywhere, informal- Sanford . . . ” 2015). Then it emerged that in urban fringe areas,
ity peaks during building booms, such as the one that preceded some businesses were claiming to be hobby farms, which pay
the crash of 2008. Inspection staffs were stretched, while property tax at a low rate (Moro 2016b). This fact only surfaced
8 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

because one of these businesses held landscaping contracts Van Gelder 2013). For example, Pamuk (2000) notes that cum-
from the city (Moro 2016a). bersome “land transfer processes,” together with guidelines
These situations arose because the city lacked the resources from the English Town and Country Planning Acts, were
to ensure that its regulations were followed, itself a reflection imposed on Trinidad. Worse, many postcolonial governments
of taxpayer resistance. The clearest examples of incapacity, have kept them on the books. In more modest ways, the same
however, concern affordable housing. Major sources of afford- problem exists in the North. For example, Hamilton, like many
able rental accommodation in Hamilton, as elsewhere, are sec- other Canadian cities, requires that secondary suites be a min-
ondary suites in single-family homes that have been subdivided imum size that is larger than that of many new condominiums
(cf. Mendez and Quastel 2016). In 2012, city staff estimated (Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation 2014). Nomin-
that 23,000 of these apartments were illegal in some way, ally, this renders illegal many units that their current tenants
commonly because they contravened zoning regulations, but consider adequate. Then, too, the prohibition of secondary
sometimes because they violated fire, electrical, or health suites in many residential areas is arguably discriminatory and
codes (van Dongen 2012a, 2012b). Some of the worst condi- certainly unhelpful. Unfortunately, many legislators assume
tions exist in student housing. Recently, a dwelling with twelve that by mandating high standards, they will compel improve-
bedrooms was rented to Chinese exchange students who, ignor- ment to happen, while, more cynically, others reckon that the
ant or heedless of the local law, paid twelve months’ rent up appearance of action will impress voters.
front and signed no contract (Bennett 2017). City staff respond By recognizing such facts, we have moved into the politics
to complaints, but these pertain to a small minority of the of calculation. There are many contexts where state agencies
properties in question. The city knows this, and recently began turn a blind eye to violations and infractions. The clearest cases
a modest program of proactive enforcement, but this engages are where irregular practices are common and widely viewed as
barely 10 percent of the inspection staff. Even then, they prob- legitimate: the political price of taking action is understood to
ably catch only the most visible issues, such as the owner be too high (Smart 1999, 104). But such calculations are always
builder who stored supplies in the front yard (Macrury 2015). in play to some degree. The City of Hamilton could ram
More importantly, strict enforcement would eliminate many through a licensing bylaw for secondary suites, ramp up proac-
affordable units and increase homelessness. That is one reason tive enforcement, and sit back while apartments are shut down
why tenants, as well as landlords, resisted efforts to introduce and tenants evicted, but councilors know that the fallout would
licensing in 2012. Tenants are too poor to pay landlords for be terrible. In terms of urban development, the greatest pres-
better housing, and the city cannot house them. This is a famil- sures come from land developers. In North America, develo-
iar situation throughout the global North. There is a large dif- pers have shaped both federal guidelines and municipal land
ference of degree between Lima and Hamilton and, arguably in use planning, a classic case where regulation has favored the
a country like Canada, the state could provide decent and powerful (e.g., Logan and Molotch 1987; Weiss 1987; cf.
affordable housing for the poor. But, for familiar reasons of Schneiberg and Bartley 2001). It is at least as relevant in the
politics and intergovernmental fiscal arrangements, Hamilton global South (Gilbert 1990, 25–26; Payne 1989, 39), where the
cannot bridge the housing gap. real estate lobby in both formally and informally developed
The state’s capacity is determined not only by its fiscal base areas is now sometimes organized in syndicates with global
but also by its ability to act effectively. Money alone does not financial connections (Berner 2012, 58; Cornelius 1976, 265;
make for efficient staff, including management. Coordination Nair 2005, 175).
of agencies is even more problematic. We often speak about the And then there are several reasons why one or more gov-
state as if it is a single entity, but it has branches that are ernment agencies might allow squatters, builders, developers,
organized both geographically and by responsibility. These landlords, or other property owners to act illegally (Ren 2017).
routinely function as silos. In Istanbul, for example, Yonder For one, it takes the pressure off: if people house themselves, or
(1987) speaks about the failures of communication between the endure poor housing, then the state is effectively absolved of
property registrar’s office, the municipalities, and various plan- responsibility. That is why the Venezuelan government ignored
ning agencies. Even when a new message gets through, it can squatting from the 1960s onward, why Tunis allowed pirate
take time for an agency, or level of government, to adjust its subdividers a free hand in the 1980s, and why Indonesian cities
practices. In Indonesia, land transactions often fail to conform have lately adopted a policy of “flexible enforcement” of land
to national law (Leaf 2005, 121). In Ontario, the provincial use regulations (Chabbi 1988; Monkkonen 2013; Ray 1969).
government has long encouraged municipalities to allow sec- Then, too, a permissive attitude toward nonconforming settle-
ondary suites and now compels them, but many, including ments offers governments some flexibility, notably in the pro-
Hamilton, have retained old zoning bylaws. As a result, the vision of infrastructure. They can plausibly disclaim
legal status of many secondary suites is uncertain. Such lags, responsibility for servicing districts that contravene official
failures of adjustment, and ambiguities are the norm. plans, so that they can deal with these areas as and when they
Everywhere, the lack of capacity may suggest that some choose (Gilbert 1990, 25). The criteria for selection are almost
state regulations are too exacting. Colonial powers imported bound to be political. Developers may offer bribes to get their
building and land use regulations from the home country into pirate subdivision recognized and serviced (Gilbert 1990, 25;
settings where they made no sense or were unrealistic (e.g., Smart 1999, 184). This may be surreptitious and hard to
Harris 9

document, as Goldstein (2004, 98) found in Cochabamba, Boli- regulations involved. Such thinking makes sense—after all,
via, but are often blatant. At the urban fringe of Karachi in the laws define binaries, while the real world is more complex—
1980s, Hasan (1987, 23) reported that it was common knowl- but are insufficient. Degrees of informality have social charac-
edge that developers and corrupt drug networks visibly and teristics and consequences that are discontinuous. When a tip-
“effectively employ[ed] the authorities.” ping point is crossed, a practice that once seemed deviant can
Politicians may overlook “elite informalities” or recognize begin to appear normal and with new ramifications. The rele-
settlements whose residents are powerful (Roy 2011, 233; Soni vance of these considerations to urban informality has often
2000; cf. Ren 2017). They may also embrace those whose been recognized. For example, many writers have suggested
leaders can mobilize the vote (Gilbert 1990, 28; Payne 1989, that widespread informality is associated with certain forms of
38; Smart 2001, 32). In that fashion Mathare Valley, Nairobi, governance. Sometimes they treated this in a binary, sometimes
was protected by an ambitious deputy mayor who secured votes in a more nuanced way (Leaf 2005, 116; Leeds and Leeds
and built a career (Gatabaki-Kamua and Karirah-Gitau 2004, 1976). But missing from this conversation has been a systema-
167–69); residents of the tidal Isla de Kokomo, Manila, sup- tic consideration of the ways in which discontinuities, or
ported a mayor in return for catwalks between houses, sports thresholds, define distinct modes of informality.
facilities, and preelection handouts (Laquian 1964, 115); in I argue that there are important discontinuities. Beyond the
Kolkata, a municipal party exercised patronage to perpetuate first—the act of regulation itself—these arise in part from the
its rule (Roy 2003, 141–44). The same has been documented, or extent to which activities ignore or violate standards, but even
indicated for innumerable cities, including Rio de Janeiro and more from the manner in which informality is socially orga-
Buenos Aires (Fischer 2008, 233–39; Van Gelder 2010, 261). nized, whether loosely coordinated, structured, or pervasive. It
Given that regulations are rarely well publicized and some- is unhelpful, indeed impossible, to establish precise criteria by
times contradictory, that residents are commonly ill-informed which these may be measured. We lack the evidence on which
and sometimes illiterate, there is ample scope for states and any exact and principled argument might be based, and we can
developers to exploit ignorance and ambiguity. Roy (2003, expect that, in some contexts, the different modes will overlap
144), for example, reports that Kolkata politicians exploited and coexist. Anyway, in practice, exact guidelines would typi-
“the cacophony of land use regulations” to serve their own cally be unhelpful; even local, well-informed observers find it
ends, while Kuyucu (2014, 609) observed that both public and very difficult to determine the extent and the social organiza-
private actors made use of “legal ambiguities and administra- tion of informality, and so a rough and ready assessment is
tive arbitrariness” to the same end. With resignation, one resi- usually the best they can produce. But just because we cannot
dent of Bangalore commented that “nobody tells us, sir, we are put a number on something does not mean it is unimportant.
illiterate and we don’t know anything” (Schenk 2001, 130). The four discontinuities, or thresholds, define five modes:
Weak enforcement and contradictory regulations may signal latent, diffuse, embedded, overt, and dominant (Table 1).1
the weakness of the state, but they can be also be strategic. The continuum on which these sit is not purely linear. As a
In many ways, then, governments shape urban informality result, some situations may straddle their boundaries, combin-
(Marx 2009; Ren 2017; Roy 2005, 149). ing elements from two although only very rarely more. None-
And so state agencies and staff may try to stamp out, toler- theless, they are serviceable in distinguishing the most
ate, or encourage informality. Their choice will depend in part common scenarios.
on the numbers, actions, political resources, and motives of
those who are violating the rules. Large numbers of peaceable
residents who offer votes for sale encourage one response;
Latent Informality
activist opposition from a small minority another. The reverse The first is latent. Regulation casts a temporal shadow beyond
is also true. How residents view and use their involvement in the issues and territory to which it pertains. A common exam-
informal activity will depend in part on how state agencies treat ple pertaining to urban development in North America involves
them, a fact that has long been recognized (Leeds and Leeds unincorporated, unplanned suburbs, Toronto being a case in
1976; Rogler 1967, 520; Van Gelder 2013). This is part of a point (Harris 1991, 1996). Here, while fringe neighborhoods
complex, ever-changing dance of governance in which there within the city were governed by building regulations and the
are few rules, written or unwritten (Leaf 2005; Roy 2005; mandatory provision of piped water and sewers—accompanied
Smart 1999). But there are some very broad patterns, which by higher property taxes—those who settled just beyond city
can usefully be understood in relation to the different modes limits were free to build and live as they chose. They were well
that informality can take. aware of the contrast. Contemporaries deplored the results of
unregulated development: shacktowns, muddy streets, and
unhealthy living conditions. The possibility of, and arguably
Modes of Informal Development the need for, regulation hovered over such areas before it
The very word “informal” implies a binary contrast, while became a reality. It influenced the actions of developers,
more subtle logic recognizes a continuum. This may exist along builders, lenders, and residents, albeit in unpredictable ways:
several dimensions: the extent to which a regulation is violated, some rushed to build precariously while they could; lenders
the seriousness of consequences, and the number of people or decline to make loans, seeing trouble ahead; others fought to
10 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

Table 1. Modes of Urban Informality.

Threshold Mode Social Characteristics Scope Visibility Comments

Latent: Varied individualistic Wide narrow High moderate


Geographic
Topical
Regulation introduced
Diffuse Individualistic Narrow Low Often disguised
Coordination; concentration
Embedded Group Broad Moderate
Organized, perhaps leaders
Overt Group Broad High May attract repression
Evasion and corruption routine
Dominant Societal General Very high Informality normalized

forestall regulation, as Cornelius (1976, 265) has shown for legitimacy of “nonconforming” uses, thereby half-
peri-urban Mexico City. Regardless, the shadow of regulation formalizing a new informality. But a clear threshold has been
mattered, and in a variety of ways, including a range of land crossed (Table 1). In the whole world, there is probably no
use, building, and occupancy regulations. bylaw pertaining to urban development to which every affected
A shadow can also be cast within jurisdictions that are person or property conforms. In that sense, informality is ubi-
already well governed when a new issue comes up for debate. quitous. It commonly flies under the radar, which makes it
Such issues, and associated regulations, tend to be specific, and difficult to measure. One reason for its invisibility to the state
so the shadow is narrowly defined (Table 1). Good examples is that builders and residents have every incentive to keep it that
are rent controls or licensing. Thus, O’Sullivan (2016) reports way. Bayat (2000, 550) observes that people work hard to be
that the number of rentals listed in Berlin on Airbnb fell by 40 unobtrusive, and thereby “retain their gains through quiet non-
percent between February and March, 2016, ahead of a new compliance without necessarily engaging in collective
bylaw that largely prohibited vacation rentals. Although unre- resistance.” One example among many is how Indians evade
ported, it is likely that this threat of regulation was also deter- or reduce their liability for stamp duty by understating the value
ring investors who had previously been thinking about moving of the property they have purchased (Alm, Annez, and Modi
into this market. Such situations have been given various 2004). Hidden informality is also common in the North; a
labels: Smart and Zerilli (2014) speak of them as “not-yet- property owner builds an extension or rents out her basement
illegal”; referring to the Texan colonias Larson (1995, 140) without a permit; a tradesman asks for cash payment so as to
uses the term “extra-legal.” evade income tax; a resident sets up a home-based business in a
Latent informality is, almost by definition, highly visible but residentially zoned area. As activity becomes regulated, then, it
at the same time open to debate. In a strict sense, of course, often goes underground where it is unobtrusive.
latency exists everywhere and on an almost limitless range of
issues; after all, there are no restraints on the character of urban
development at the poles. But in practical terms, the concept is Diffuse Informality
meaningful only in those situations where new legislation has What helps to keep it that way is that it is individualistic,
been, or might plausibly be, proposed. The debate has to do weakly coordinated, and geographically dispersed. At most,
with what should count as “plausible.” If, as is commonly the the home handyman may call on the assistance of a friend or
case, there is agitation and discussion about the extension of coworker; the only obvious evidence of a basement apartment
regulation, whether to new territory or to a new domain of may be a second mailbox; a tradesman works a few hours or
urban practice, then it is obvious that we can speak of latency. days at one address, and then moves on; the sign of a home
Historically, the evidence for this can be found in newspaper business may be nothing more than large mail deliveries, and
accounts and municipal reports. Today, in addition, there will these days even that may be absent. Small-scale violations are
be buzz in social media. But if a regulation has been proposed everywhere. Such diffuse informality is surely the commonest
only by a zealous planner, and supported by a mere handful of mode and the most widespread (Table 1). Even to document, it
local residents, then we may conclude that to speak of latent is difficult. For example, using a variety of sources that include
informality is premature. Only time will tell whether such a building permits, property assessment records, rental listings,
judgment was accurate. and field surveys, many North American researchers have tried
The passage of a new law can create informality overnight. hard to document the prevalence of illegal secondary suites but
Castells and Portes (1989, 298) speak of this process as with very limited success (Harris and Kinsella 2017). To stamp
“passive,” in the sense that those affected have done nothing out such practices, or to render them legal by offering carrots
to earn their new status as outlaws. Often, this fact is conceded and sticks, would require substantial resources and intrusive
by grandfathering; zoning regulations often recognize the action. More affordable and therefore limited initiatives would
Harris 11

be arbitrary and appear unfair. And so planners and other immigrant neighborhoods are sometimes terrae incognitae to
municipal officials often turn a blind eye. Such a strategy can officials, politicians, and decent middle-class folks, being vis-
itself become almost formal; the Dutch have a word for it, ited only by social explorers who bring back titillating tales.
gedogen, the deliberate lack of enforcement. Historically, the best-documented examples are the “slum”
neighborhoods of British and American cities (Keating
1976), but colonial cities, such as Calcutta, received a similar
Embedded Informality treatment (Kipling 1891). Avoidance, and therefore ignorance,
A second threshold is crossed when such activities become remains the norm if areas are perceived to be dangerous or
organized, commonly within a particular social group (Table deviant. But the wholesale disregard for basic zoning or build-
1). This typically includes three elements: cooperation, physi- ing laws, as is the case in the irregular settlement of whole
cal concentration, and popular legitimacy. Cooperation pro- neighborhoods, is another matter. It requires a correspondingly
vides practical support encouraging more irregular activity; greater degree of coordination and perhaps leadership. This
on a wider range of practices, not just building unauthorized may be provided through election or, as in Villa Pagador, Boli-
extensions, say, but crowding in two or more families. Geo- via, by self-appointed persons (Goldstein 2004, 97; cf. Gilbert
graphical concentration, too, is enabling, while social legiti- and Ward 1985, 78; Lobo 1992); pirate subdivisions are
macy emerges from both. These features are not perfectly “carefully directed” by entrepreneurs (Ray 1969, 33; cf. Doe-
correlated, but they are closely associated because they rein- bele 1977). In both cases, the degree of organization may
force one another. It is easier to organize people who live close decline as homes and community centers are built and services
by, while collective activity often produces clusters. Prime installed (Mangin 1967; Van Gelder 2010). The purpose of
examples are ethnic and (im)migrant neighborhoods. The organization is to make settlement possible, but it may come
squatters who settled whole districts at the fringe of Latin to include defense against officials who try to suppress it. A
American cities in the 1950s and 1960s formed associations longer-term goal is usually to make settlement permanent and
to help one each other build homes and community services; perhaps formalized. In this manner, clustered informality
so, too, did the British immigrants who settled Toronto’s sub- becomes visible and hence overt.
urbs in the early twentieth century (Lobo 1992; Harris 1996). Researchers should have no difficulty in identifying situa-
Less visibly, the prevalence of back houses in parts of South tions where large numbers of people are manifestly flouting the
Central Los Angeles reflects the cooperation of neighbors, law, and governments often find it difficult to ignore them. The
actively in construction and passively by refraining from regis- point at which they respond, and how, depends on many con-
tering complaints (Wegmann 2015), while the organization of siderations. These include the amount of illegal activity there
sublets by Latin Americans on Long Island in the 1990s was is; the level of popular tolerance or support, within and beyond
helped by their segregation (Mahler 1995, 188–213). On a the communities in question; how powerful those communities
more modest scale still, with help from neighbors and family are, and therefore what types of political pressures are brought
with relevant skills, property owners may undertake repairs and to bear; how serious the consequences are, whether for those
renovations without seeking permits and in violation of build- involved or for the public at large; and what resources are
ing, health, and electrical codes. Subsequent gentrifiers will available to deal with the situation (cf. Ren 2017). But when
discover evidence of such work in older homes in what had illegality becomes overt, another threshold is crossed: it has
been a working-class or immigrant neighborhood. Trust, based become an unavoidable subject of public debate and a likely
on local acceptance, is often critical to the emergence of such object of government policy.
embedded informality, whether based on shared language, cul- Faced with visible violations of its requirements, govern-
ture, class, or experience, and this is something that coresi- ments may adapt and compromise or perhaps “regularize” such
dence reinforces (Ferman and Ferman 1973, 17; Portes and practices by offering assistance, but they often attempt to sup-
Haller 2005, 407). press instead. In that case, settlements of organized and clus-
tered informality in effect become “rebellious spaces” (Smart
1999, 104). If these are few in number, they can plausibly be
Overt Informality regarded as exceptions and dealt with accordingly, for exam-
Embedded practices are typically obvious to members of the ple, by suspending enforcement on a more or less temporary
social group or geographical community in question, so obvi- basis. This strategy can be a sort of safety valve. A similar
ous as to be taken for granted. Researchers, or just interested approach may be adopted with respect to relatively minor,
observers, who have an entrée into such a community, whether ubiquitous practices that happen to have attracted public atten-
by virtue of shared language, culture, or residency, may easily tion. In Hamilton, an example is the widespread existence of
be able to identify embedded practices. So, too, should out- illegal secondary suites, which normally fly under the radar but
siders who are able to demonstrate that they are trustworthy. which have become news in part because of their overlap with
Interviews and everyday conversations may make the situation student housing, itself a major issue in specific neighborhoods.
plain. But some practices may remain invisible to the state for But, at a certain point, when substantial and overt informality
years or even decades (Table 1). Modest violations of less becomes widespread, suppression becomes politically impos-
important regulations can be hidden, while fringe, slum, or sible. Fawaz (2008, 580), for example, describes how the
12 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

settlement of Hayy el Sellom, outside Beirut, eventually a family of practices; an understanding of which depends upon
became so large that the city simply could not evict people. some acquaintance with the literature on the South. This survey
is, in part, a guide to some pertinent studies. For those inter-
Dominant Informality ested in the South, it helps to make the case, developed by a
growing number of researchers, that that region is not a place
Where many such settlements grow up, they begin to shape the apart, and that concepts developed there are relevant elsewhere.
mode of state governance itself. In Castells and Portes’ (1989, But if informal elements of urban development are not con-
298–99) terms, they create a “market for exceptional fined to particular parts of the world, they are much more
treatment,” making corruption routine from the street level to common in some places than in others, they happen in different
the back rooms of legislatures. Plenty of examples have been ways, and with varying degrees of prominence, not to mention
documented, notably in Latin America, Africa, and parts of significance. The question is how best to understand such var-
Asia. Speaking of Rio de Janeiro, for example, Fischer iation. The concept of “modes of informality” speaks to that
(2008, 233) writes that all sorts of people, from “small-time issue.2 The objective is not classification for its own sake, but
shysters to self-made political operators to some of the city’s rather to help us make the comparisons that highlight common-
wealthiest property owners and most powerful politicians,” alities and differences across cities, thereby pointing to the
have profited from the manipulation of development in the importance of those processes that bring qualitative change,
favelas. Generalizing about Africa, Hansen and Vaa (2004, and the more useful state responses.
12) speak about the way informality pervades politics, the A key contribution of this concept is that it directs our
bureaucracies, and public services. Berner (2012, 58) suggests attention to the character and importance of the sociopolitical
that in some Asian cities, informal housing has become “big thresholds that affect how planning happens. These deserve
business,” organized by “syndicates” that involve local offi- more attention than they have received. Once regulation has
cials and police. An example is Mumbai, where Weinstein been introduced, the crossing of thresholds depends on the
(2008, 22) has documented an “illicit nexus” involving crimi- numbers of people involved in informal practices, their phys-
nal organization, politicians, bureaucrats, and the police. Cor- ical location, and especially their manner of social organiza-
ruption pervades the system from bottom to top. In Tehran, tion. The importance of regulation is obvious and widely
fines for exceeding height restrictions have become de facto recognized, but its shadow effect on unregulated territory has
permits (Shahshahani 2005, 234). In Karachi, Hasan (2004, 69, not been, while many writers still speak as though informality
1987) observes that under-the-table arrangements have become can be thought of more loosely, as a conceptual umbrella. It is
so routine that “through whom, and at what time” bribery must worth reiterating that legislation matters along with the debates
happen “have also been formalized.” In Egypt, Sims (2010) and battles that surround it. It provides the state with a lever;
speaks about “informal Cairo triumphant.” Faced with forma- how it uses that tool is another matter.
lized informality, the line between what is legal and what is not A second threshold concerns the emergence of embedded
ceases to be blurred and becomes arbitrary and almost mean- social legitimacy and cooperation, a development with practi-
ingless. With respect to Indian cities, notably Kolkata, Roy cal significance for those involved and also, potentially, for
(2005, 2009) has discussed the character and implications of planning practices and wider politics. We could usefully think
this situation, with its carefully calculated lack of enforcement. more about the forms that embeddedness takes, and its precon-
Here, clearly, informality has become dominant. ditions. A third threshold is crossed when irregular practices
In a rough and ready way, such situations are among the are organized or even led, becoming overt, an unavoidable
easiest to identify. The ubiquity of petty bribery, or of viola- matter of debate and policy. This is the least predictable step:
tions of building, zoning, and health codes, is a matter of it depends on the prevalence and physical visibility of illegal
public knowledge or casual observation. In that context, the development, but on much else besides. Its concentration in a
absence of public discussion about such matters may be the ghetto may attract attention or discourage it; media reports may
best clue to the fact that they are taken for granted. Larger- trigger disproportionate response or fall on deaf ears. As we
scale corruption, for example of the sort that links building know in many contexts, how people, and governments, respond
contractors with politicians, can be much harder—and indeed to news is unpredictably variable.
more dangerous—to detect. It may be only intermittent reve- The final threshold occurs when informality defines the
lations, of the sort that have recently surfaced in Brazil, that state’s whole mode of governance, the form as well as the
can provide a glimpse of the netherworld in which dominant practice of planning. Interesting observations have been made
informality flourishes. about those places where that threshold has been left behind,
but less attention has been given to the mix of conditions that
nudge cities, and nations, across it. Here, discussions of urban
Concluding Comments informality must take account of the wider literature on state
The argument developed here is directed primarily at those governance.
interested in cities of the global North, where some form of An assumption and implication of the present argument is
planning is the norm. My hope is that it will encourage and help that informality is more than ubiquitous; it is an inevitable
researchers to see a myriad of often minor infractions as part of context of planning, a fact of social existence. Systematic,
Harris 13

“modern” forms of regulation cannot be wholly reconciled to Alm, J., P. Annez, and A. Modi. 2004. “Stamp Duties in Indian States:
the messy character of urban life, so that lawmakers are forever A Case for Reform.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper
destined to tighten and then relax their grip (Rose 1988; Val- 3413, World Bank, Washington, DC.
verde 2011). Then, too, there is the practical inability of people AlSayyad, N. 2004. “Urban Informality as a ‘New’ Way of Life.” In
to meet official expectations and of planners to enforce them. Urban Informality, edited by A. Roy and N. AlSayyad, 7–32.
Another strand to the present argument is that this social con- Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.
dition is nowhere more apparent than in urban areas. It is an Amis, P. H. 1984. “Squatters or Tenants: The Commercialization of
unusually prominent aspect of development in cities and sub- Unauthorized Housing in Nairobi.” World Development 12 (1): 87–96.
urbs alike, though taking different forms in each. But of course, Anders, F., and A. Sedlmaier, eds. 2016. Public Goods versus Eco-
any experienced building inspector could have told us that. nomic Interests: Global Perspectives on the History of Squatting.
London, UK: Routledge.
Acknowledgment Andersson, D., and S. Moroni, eds. 2014. Cities and Private Planning:
The author would like to thank Victoria Kelley, Michael Leaf, Alan Property Rights, Entrepreneurship and Transaction Costs.
Smart, Jake Wegmann, and four anonymous reviewers for their com- Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.
ments on earlier drafts. Aronson, D. R. 1978. “Capitalism and Culture in Ibadan Urban Devel-
opment.” Urban Anthropology 7 (3): 253–69.
Declaration of Conflicting Interests Balaban, U. 2010. “The Enclosure of Urban Space and Consolidation
The author(s) declared no potential conflicts of interest with respect to of the Capitalist Land Regime in Turkish Cities.” Urban Studies 48
the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. (10): 2162–79.
Baross, P. 1990. “Sequencing Land Development: The Price Implica-
Funding tions of Legal and Illegal Settlement Growth.” In The Transforma-
tion of Land Supply Systems in Third World Cities, edited by P.
The author(s) received no financial support for the research, author-
Baross and J. van der Linden, 57–87. Aldershot, UK: Avebury.
ship, and/or publication of this article.
Baross, P., and J. Van der Linden. 1990. “Introduction.” In The Trans-
formation of Land Supply Systems in Third World Cities, edited by
Notes
P. Baross and J. Van der Linden, 1–16. Aldershot, UK: Avebury.
1. There are certain parallels with the forms of informal planning that Barzel, Y. 1989. Economic Analysis of Property Rights. New York:
are discussed by Briassoulis (1997) who, however, speaks in purely Cambridge University Press.
theoretical terms about all types of planning and does not refer to Bayat, A. 2000. “From ‘Dangerous Classes’ to ‘Quiet Rebels’: Politics
the presence of thresholds. of the Urban Subaltern in the Global South.” International Sociol-
2. My usage is more specific than that of Ananya Roy (2005) who has ogy 15 (3): 533–57.
written of informality itself as a mode of metropolitan Bell, J. P. 2014. “Response to Comments: The Informal Housing
organization. Debate Remains Open.” UrbDeZine Los Angeles, November 12.
Accessed November 2, 2017. http://losangeles.urbdezine.com/
References 2014/11/12/response-to-comments-the-informal-housing-
“150 Sanford, Now Half Empty, Has Many Problems Still Not Fixed.” debate-remains-open/.
2015. CBC Hamilton, February 18. Accessed November 2, 2017. Ben-Joseph, E. 2005. “Facing Subdivision Regulations.” In Regulat-
http://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/hamilton/news/150-sanford-no ing Place: Standards and the Shaping of Urban America, edited by
w-half-empty-has-many-problems-still-not-fixed-1.2960538. E. Ben-Joseph and T. S. Szold, 167–87. New York: Routledge.
Abrams, C. 1964. Man’s Struggle for Shelter in an Urbanizing World. Benda-Beckman, F. von. 2001. “Legal Pluralism and Social Justice in
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Economic and Political Development.” IDS Bulletin 32:46–56.
Acioly, C. 2010. “The Informal City and the Phenomenon of Slums: Benda-Beckman, F. von, von K. Benda-Beckmann, and G. M.
The Challenges of Slum Upgrading and Slum Prevention.” In New Wiber. 2006“The Properties of Property.” In Changing Proper-
Towns for the 21st Century. The Planned and Unplanned City, ties of Property, edited by Benda-Beckman, F. von, von K.
edited by International New Town Institute, 222–31. Amsterdam, Benda-Beckmann, and G. M. Wiber, 1–39. New York: Berghahn.
the Netherlands: SUN Architecture. Benjamin, S. 2004. “Urban Land Transformation for Pro-poor Econo-
Ackerman, B. 1971. “Regulating Slum Housing Markets on Behalf of mies.” Geoforum 35:177–87.
the Poor: Of Housing Codes, Housing Subsidies and Income Bennett, K. 2017. “Overcrowded Hamilton House Near McMaster
Redistribution Policy.” The Yale Law Journal 80 (6): 1093–197. Has 12 Bedrooms.” CBC Hamilton, March 24. Accessed Novem-
Aguilera, T., and A. Smart. 2016. “Squatting, North, South and ber 2, 2017. http://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/hamilton/overcrow
Turnabout: A Dialogue Comparing Illegal Housing Research.” In ded-12-bedroom-hamilton-house-1.4035008.
Public Goods versus Economic Interests: Global Perspectives on Benton, L. 1994. “Beyond Legal Pluralism: Towards a New Approach
the History of Squatting, edited by F. Anders and A. Sedlmaier, to Law in the Informal Sector.” Social and Legal Studies 3:223–42.
29–55. London, UK: Routledge. Berner, E. 2012. “Informal Housing: Asia.” In International Encyclo-
Allen, J., J. Barlow, J. Leal, T. Maloutas, and L. Padovani. 2004. pedia of Housing and Home, edited by S. Smith, 56–77.
Housing and Welfare in Southern Europe. Oxford, UK: Blackwell. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: Elsevier.
14 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

Berry, J., and S. McGreal. 1995. European Cities, Planning Systems Connolly, P. 2009. “Observing the Evolution of Irregular Settlements:
and Property Markets. London, UK: E & FN Spon. Mexico City’s Colonias Populares, 1990 to 2005.” International
Biderman, C., and M. Smolka. 2012. “Measuring Informality. Why Development Planning Review 31 (1): 1–35.
Bother? An Application to Latin America.” Lincoln Institute for Cornelius, W. A. 1976. “The Impact of Cityward Migration on Urban
Land Policy Working Paper, Lincoln Institute for Land Policy, Land and Housing Markets. Problems and Policy Alternatives in
Cambridge, MA. Mexico City.” In The City in Comparative Perspective, edited by J.
Birch, E. L., S. Chattaraj, and S. M. Wachter, eds. 2016. Slums: How Walton and L. H. Masotti, 249–70. New York: Sage.
Informal Real Estate Markets Work. Philadelphia: University of Cox, M., and T. Slee. 2016. “How Airbnb’s Data Hid the Facts in
Pennsylvania Press. New York City.” February 10. Accessed November 2, 2017.
Briassoulis, H. 1997. “How the Others Plan: Exploring the Shapes and http://whimsley.s3.amazonaws.com/wordpress/wp-content/
Forms of Informal Planning.” Journal of Planning Education and uploads/2016/02/how-airbnbs-data-hid-the-facts-in-new-york-
Research 17:105–17. city.pdf.
Brinklow, A. 2016. “City Says 76 Percent of Airbnb Listings Are Craggs, S. 2015. “Some Residents from 150 Sanford Evacuated and
Illegal.” Curbed San Francisco, April 8. Accessed November 2, Put in Hotel Rooms.” CBC Hamilton, February 18. Accessed
2017. http://sf.curbed.com/2016/4/8/11394592/airbnb-study- November 2, 2017. http://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/hamilton/
illegal-san-francisco. news/some-residents-from-150-sanford-evacuated-and-put-in-ho
Bruce, J. W. 1988. “A Perspective on Indigenous Land Tenure Sys- tel-rooms-1.2962011.
tems and Land Concentration.” In Land and Society in Contempo- Cuff, D., T. Higgins, and P.J. Dahl, eds. 2010. Backyard Homes L.A.
rary Africa, edited by R. E. Downs and S. P. Reyna, 23–52. Los Angeles, CA: cityLAB, UCLA.
Hanover, NH: University Press of New England. Cullingworth, B., and R. W. Caves. 2014. Planning in the U.S.A:
Buist, S. 2007. “City Allows Builders to Break Rules.” Hamilton Policies, Issues and Processes. New York: Routledge.
Spectator, May 23. Accessed November 2, 2017. https://www.the Daley, S. 2013. “Irish Try to Erase Ghosts of a Housing Crash.” New
spec.com/news-story/2161296-city-allows-builders-to-break- York Times, December 21. Accessed November 2, 2017. http://
rules/. www.nytimes.com/2013/12/22/world/europe/legacy-of-a-crash-
Canada Mortgage and Housing Corporation. 2014. “Accessory Apart- ghost-estates-haunt-ireland.html?_r¼0.
ment Regulations in Canadian Census Metropolitan Areas and Davis, M. 2006. Planet of Slums. London, UK: Verso.
Census Agglomerations.” Research Highlight. Socio-economic De Boek, F. 2012. “Spectral Kinshasa: Building the City through an
Series 14-002. Ottawa, Canada: CMHC. Architecture of Words.” In Urban Theory beyond the West: A
Carswell, A. T. 2012. The Encyclopedia of Housing, vol. 2. Los World of Cities, edited by T. Edensor and M. Jaye, 311–28. New
Angeles, CA: Sage. York: Routledge.
Castells, M., and A. Portes. 1989. “World Underneath. The Origins, De Soto, H. 2000. The Mystery of Capital. New York: Basic Books.
Dynamics, and Effects of the Informal Economy.” In The Informal Demsetz, H. 1967. “Towards a Theory of Property Rights.” American
Economy. Studies in Advanced and Less Developed Countries, Economic Review 57 (2): 347–59.
edited by A. Portes, M. Castells, and L. Benton, 11–37. Baltimore, Dickerman, C. 1988. “Urban Land Concentration.” In Land and Soci-
MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. ety in Contemporary Africa, edited by R. E. Downs and S. P.
Cavalcanti, M. 2014. “Threshold Markets: The Production of Real Reyna, 76–90. Hanover, NH: University Press of New England.
Estate Value between the ‘Favela’ and the ‘Pavement.’” In Cities Doebele, W. A. 1977. “The Private Market and Low Income Urbani-
from Scratch. Poverty and Informality in Urban Latin America, sation: The ‘Pirate’ Subdivisions of Bogotá.” American Journal of
edited by B. Fischer, B. McCann, and J. Auyero, 208–37. Durham, Comparative Law 25 (3): 530–64.
NC: Duke University Press. Doebele, W. A. 1983. “Concepts of Urban Land Tenure.” In Urban
Chabbi, M. 1988. “The Pirate Developer: A New Form of Land Land Policy: Issues and Opportunities, edited by H. B. Dunkerley,
Developer.” International Journal of Urban and Regional 63–107. New York: Oxford University Press.
Research 12:8–21. Duhau, E. 2014. “The Informal City: An Enduring Slum or Progres-
Chalana, M., and J. Hou, eds. 2016. Messy Urbanism: Understanding sive Habit?” In Cities from Scratch. Poverty and Informality in
the ‘Other’ Cities of Asia. Hong Kong, China: Hong Kong Uni- Urban Latin America, edited by B. Fischer, B. McCann, and J.
versity Press. Auyero, 150–69. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
“Church’s new face, A”. 2014. Hamilton Spectator, July 4. Accessed Dunkerley, H. B., ed. 1983. Urban Land Policy: Issues and Opportu-
November 2, 2017. https://www.thespec.com/news-story/ nities. New York: Oxford University Press.
4614757-a-church-s-new-face/. Clawson, M. 1971. Suburban Dupont, V., and M. Houssay-Holzshuch. 2005. “Fragmentation and
Land Conversion in the United States. Baltimore, MD: Johns Access to the City: Cape Town and Delhi in Comparative Perspec-
Hopkins University Press. tive.” In Reconfiguring Identities and Building Territories in India
Colombijn, F. 2010. Under Construction: The Politics of Urban Space and South Africa, edited by P. Gervais-Lambony, F. Landy, and S.
and Housing during the Decolonisation of Indonesia, 1930–1960. Oldfield, 275–312. Delhi, India: Manohar-CSH.
Leiden, the Netherlands: KTLV Press. Dupont, V., D. Jordhus-Lier, C. Sutherland, and E. Braathen, eds.
Comer, J. P. 1942. New York City Building Control. New York: 2016. The Politics of Slums in the Global South: Urban Informality
Columbia University Press. in Brazil, India, South Africa and Peru. London, UK: Routledge.
Harris 15

Durand-Lasserve, A. 1990. “Articulation between Formal and Infor- Friedmann, J. 2011. “Becoming Urban: Periurban Dynamics in Viet-
mal Land Markets in Developing Countries: Issues and Trends.” In nam and China. Introduction.” Pacific Affairs 84 (3): 425–34.
The Transformation of Land Supply Systems in Third World Cities, Fureseth, O. J., and M. B. Lapping, eds. 1999. Contested Countryside:
edited by P. Baross and J. van der Linden, 37–56. Aldershot, UK: The Rural-urban Fringe in North America. Brookfield, VT: Ashgate.
Avebury. Gaffikin, F., D. C. Perry, and R. Kundu. 2011. “The City and Its
Durand-Lasserve, A. 1998. “Law and Urban Change in Developing Politics: Informal and Contested.” In The City, Revisited: Urban
Countries: Trends and Issues.” In Illegal Cities: Law and Urban Theory from Chicago, Los Angeles and New York, edited by D. R.
Change in Developing Countries, edited by E. Fernandes and A. Judd and D. Simpson, 305–31. Minneapolis: University of Minne-
Varley, 233–57. London, UK: Zed. sota Press.
Durand-Lasserve, A., M. Durand-Lasserve, and H. Selid. 2015. Land Gatabaki-Kamau, R., and S. Karirah-Gitau. 2004. “Actors and Inter-
Delivery Systems in West African Cities: The Example of Bamako, ests: The Development of an Informal Settlement in Nairobi,
Mali. Washington, DC: World Bank. Accessed November 2, 2017. Kenya.” In Reconsidering Informality: Perspectives from Urban
https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/ Africa, edited by K. T. Hansen and M. Vaa, 158–75. Oslo, Norway:
21613/9781464804335.pdf?sequence¼1. Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
Durst, N., and J. Wegmann. 2017. “Informal Housing in the United Gërxhani, K. 2004. “The Informal Sector in Developed and Less
States.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 41 Developed Countries: A Literature Survey.” Public Choice 120:
(2): 282–97. 267–300.
Erni, M., and Ir. Bianpoen. 1980. “Jakarta, Indonesia.” In Policies Gilbert, A. 1990. “The Costs and Benefits of Illegality and Irregularity
towards Urban Slums: Slums and Squatter Settlements in the in the Supply of Land.” In The Transformation of Land Supply
ESCAP Region. Case Studies of Seven Cities, edited by M. Sarin, Systems in Third World Cities, edited by P. Baross and J. van der
, 62–75. Bangkok, Thailand: United Nations. Linden, 17–36. Aldershot, UK: Avebury.
Evans, A. W. 2004a. Economics and Land Use Planning. Oxford, UK: Gilbert, A. 1992. “The Housing of the Urban Poor.” In Cities, Poverty
Blackwell. and Development, edited by A. Gilbert and J. Gugler, 14–32. New
Evans, A. W. 2004b. Economics, Real Estate and the Supply of Land. York: Oxford University Press.
Oxford, UK: Blackwell. Gilbert, A. 2012. “Private Rental Landlords: Developing Countries.”
Evers, H.-D., and R. Korff. 2000. Southeast Asian Urbanism: The In International Encyclopedia of Housing and Home, edited by S.
Meaning and Power of Social Space. New York: St. Martin’s Press. Smith, , 381–86. Oxford, UK: Elsevier.
Fawaz, M. 2008. “An Unusual Clique of City-makers: Social Net- Gilbert, A., and P. Ward. 1985. Housing, the State and the Poor:
works in the Production of a Neighbourhood in Beirut (1950-75). Policy and Practice in Three Latin American Cities. Cambridge,
” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 32 (3): MA: Cambridge University Press.
565–85. Ginsburg, N. 1991. “Extended Metropolitan Regions in Asia: A
Feeny, D. 1988. “The Development of Property Rights in Land: A New Spatial Paradigm.” In The Extended Metropolis: Settle-
Comparative Study.” In Toward a Political Economy of Develop- ment Transition in Asia, edited by N. Ginsburg, B. Koppell,
ment: A Rational Choice Perspective, edited by H. R. Bates, , and T. G. McGee, 27–46. Honolulu: University of Hawaii
272–99. Berkeley: University of California Press. Press.
Feige, E. L. 1990. “Defining and Estimating Underground and Infor- Glasze, G., C. Webster, and K. Frantz, eds. 2006. Private Cities:
mal Economies: The New Institutional Economics Approach.” Global and Local Perspectives. New York: Routledge.
World Development 18:989–1002. Goff, L. 2016. Shantytown USA: Forgotten Landscapes of the Work-
Ferguson, N. 2011. Civilization: The West and the Rest. New York: ing Poor. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Penguin. Goldstein, D. 2004. The Spectacular City: Violence and Performance
Ferman, P. R., and L. A. Ferman. 1973. “The Structural Underpin- in Urban Bolivia. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
nings of the Irregular Economy.” Poverty and Human Resources Gough, K. V. 1999. “The Changing Role and Nature of Urban Gov-
Abstracts 8 (1): 3–17. ernance in Peri-urban Accra, Ghana.” Third World Planning
Fernandes, E., and A. Varley, eds. 1998. Illegal Cities: Law and Review 21 (4): 393–410.
Urban Change in Developing Countries. London, UK: Zed. Gough, K. V., and P. Yankson. 2006. “Conflict and Cooperation in
Fischer, B. 2008. A Poverty of Rights: Citizenship and Inequality in Environmental Management in Peri-Urban Accra, Ghana.” In The
Twentieth-century Rio de Janeiro. Stanford, CA: Stanford Univer- Peri-urban Interface: Approaches to Sustainable Natural and
sity Press. Human Resource Use, edited by D. McGregor, D. Simon, and D.
Fischer, B. 2016. “Beyond Insurgency and Dystopia: The Role of A. Thompson, 196–210. London, UK: Earthscan.
Informality in Brazil’s Twentieth-century Urban Formation.” In Gouverneur, D. 2015. Planning and Design for Future Informal Set-
Public Goods versus Economic Interests: Global Perspectives on tlements: Shaping the Self-Constructed City. London, UK:
the History of Squatting, edited by F. Anders and A. Sedlmaier, Earthscan.
122–49. London, UK: Routledge. Granovetter, M. 1978. “Threshold Models of Collective Behavior.”
B. Fischer, B. McCann, and J. Auyero, eds. 2014. Cities from Scratch. American Journal of Sociology 83:1420–43.
Poverty and Informality in Urban Latin America. Durham, NC: Grant, R. 2009. Globalizing City: The Urban and Economic Trans-
Duke University Press. formation of Accra, Ghana. Syracuse: New York University Press.
16 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

Griffiths, J. 1986. “What Is Legal Pluralism?” Journal of Legal Plur- “Illegal Building Continuing in the City.” 2016. Hamilton Spectator,
alism and Unofficial Law 18 (24): 1–55. October 14. Accessed November 2, 2017. https://www.thespec.
Guha-Khasnobis, B., R. Kanbur, and E. Ostrom. 2006. “Beyond Form- com/news-story/6912120-illegal-building-continuing-in-the-city/.
ality and Informality.” In Linking the Formal and Informal Econ- Jenkins, P. 2004. “Beyond the Formal/Informal Dichotomy:
omy, edited by B. Guha-Khasnobis, R. Kanbur, and E. Ostrom, Access to Land in Maputo, Mozambique.” In Reconsidering
2–24. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. Informality: Perspectives from Urban Africa, edited by K. T.
Hansen, K. T., and M. Vaa, eds. 2004. Reconsidering Informality: Hansen and M. Vaa, 210–26. Oslo, Norway: Nordiska
Perspectives from Urban Africa. Oslo, Norway: Nordiska Afrikainstitutet.
Afrikainstitutet. Jenkins, P. 2009. “African Cities. Competing Claims on Urban Land.”
Harms, E. 2011. Saigon’s Edge: On the Margins of Ho Chi Minh City. In African Cities: Competing Claims over Urban Spaces, edited
Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. by F. Locatelli and P. Nugent, 81–108. Leiden, the Netherlands:
Harris, R. 1991. “The Impact of Building Controls on Residential Brill.
Development in Toronto, 1900-1940.” Planning Perspectives 6: Jindrich, J. 2016. “Squatting in the U.S. What Historians Can Learn
269–96. from Developing Countries.” In Public Goods versus Economic
Harris, R. 1996. Unplanned Suburbs: Toronto’s American Tragedy, Interests: Global Perspectives on the History of Squatting, edited
1900-1950. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. by F. Anders and A. Sedlmaier, 56–77. London, UK: Routledge.
Harris, R. 2003. “A Double Irony: The Originality and Influence of Karr, R. D. 2015. “Suburban Land Development in Antebellum Bos-
John F.C. Turner.” Habitat International 27:245–69. ton.” Journal of Urban History 41 (5): 862–80.
Harris, R. 2017. “Hamilton. Poster Child for Concentrated Poverty.” Karst, K. L. 1971. “Rights in Land and Housing in an Informal Legal
In Changing Neighbourhoods. Social and Spatial Polarization in System: The Barrios of Caracas.” American Journal of Compara-
Canadian Cities, edited by J. Grant, A. Walks, and H. Ramos. tive Law 19 (3): 550–74.
Vancouver, Canada: University of British Columbia Press. http:// Kasanga, R. K., J. A. Cochrane, and M. J. Roth. 1996. “Land Markets
onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/cag.12424/abstract. and Legal Contradictions in the Peri-urban Area of Accra, Ghana.”
Harris, R., and K. Kinsella. 2017. “Secondary Suites. A Survey of Research Paper No.127, Land Tenure Centre, University of Wis-
Evidence and Municipal Policy.” The Canadian Geographer. consin-Madison, Wisconsin.
Hart, K. 2010. “Informal Economy.” In The Human Economy, edited Keating, P. 1976. Into Unknown England, 1866-1913: Selections from
by K. Hart, J.-L. Laville, and A. D. Cattani, 142–53. Cambridge, the Social Explorers. London, UK: Fontana.
MA: Polity. Keyder, C. 2000. “Liberalization from Above and the Future of the
Hasan, A. 1987. Interviews Related to Illegal Subdivisions and Devel- Informal Sector: Land, Shelter, and Informality on the Periphery.”
opment in Yaqoob Abad and Orangi Township. Karachi, Pakistan: In Informalization. Process and Structure, edited by F. Tabak and
UNESCAP. M. A. Critchlow, 119–32. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univer-
Hasan, A. 2004. “The Changing Nature of the Informal Sector in sity Press.
Karachi Due to Global Restructuring and Liberalization, and Its Kipling, R. 1891. The City of Dreadful Night and Other Places. Alla-
Repercussions.” In Urban Informality, edited by A. Roy and N. habad, India: A.H. Wheeler.
AlSayyad, 67–78. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books. Klaufus, C., and P. van Lindert. 2012. “Informal Housing. Latin
Hein, C. 2018. Planning History Handbook. London, UK: Routledge. America.” In International Encyclopedia of Housing and Home,
Hernández, F., P. Kellett, and L. K. Allen, eds. 2010. Rethinking the edited by S. Smith, 70–77. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: Elsevier.
Informal City: Critical Perspectives from Latin America. New Kombe, W. J. 2000. “Regularising Housing Land Development during
York: Berghahn. the Transition to Market-led Supply in Tanzania.” Habitat Inter-
Hirt, S. 2012. Iron Curtains: Gates, Suburbs, and Privatization of national 24:167–84.
Space in the Post-socialist City. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley. Krueckeberg, D. A. 1999. “Private Property in Africa. Creation Stories
Holston, J. 2008. Insurgent Citizenship. Disjunctions and Democracy of Economy, State and Culture.” Journal of Planning Education
and Modernity in Brazil. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. and Research 19:176–82.
Huchzermeyer, M., and A. Karam, eds. 2006. Informal Settlements: A Kudva, N. 2009. “The Everyday and Episodic: The Spatial and Polit-
Perpetual Challenge? Cape Town, South Africa: University of ical Impacts of Urban Informality.” Environment and Planning A
Cape Town Press. 41:1614–28.
Hudalah, D., and T. Firman. 2012. “Beyond Property: Industrial Kundu, A. 2002. “Tenure Security, Housing Investment and Environ-
Estates and Post-suburban Transformation in Jakarta Metropolitan mental Improvement: The Cases of Delhi and Ahmedabad, India.”
Region.” Cities 29:40–48. In Land, Rights and Innovation, edited by G. Payne, , 136–57.
Huttman, E., and W. Van Vliet, eds. 1988. Handbook of Housing and London, UK: ITDG.
the Built Environment in the United States. Westport, CT: Green- Kuyucu, T. 2014. “Law, Property and Ambiguity: The Uses and
wood Press. Abuses of Legal Ambiguity in Remaking Istanbul’s Informal Set-
Ikejiofor, U. C. 2006. “Integrative Strategies or Functional Interface? tlements.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
Emerging Trends in Land Administration in Contemporary Enugu, 38 (2): 609–27.
Nigeria.” International Development Planning Review 28 (2): Lagos, R. 1995. “Formalizing the Informal Sector.” Development and
137–58. Change 26:111–31.
Harris 17

Laquian, A. A. 1964. “Isla de Kokomo: Politics among Urban Slum Ma, J. 2013. The Land Development Game in China. Lanham, MD:
Dwellers.” Philippine Journal of Public Administration 8 (2): Lexington.
112–22. Macrury, A. 2015. “Home Renovations Land Do-it-yourselfer in Hot
Large, D. W. 1973. “This Land Is Whose Land? Changing Concepts of Water.” Hamilton Spectator, September 22. Accessed November
Land as Property.” Wisconsin Law Review 4:1039–83. 2, 2017. https://www.thespec.com/news-story/5923600-action-
Larson, J. E. 1995. “Free Markets Deep in the Heart of Texas.” Geor- line-home-renovations-land-do-it-yourselfer-in-hot-water/.
getown Law Journal 84:179–260. Mahler, S. J. 1995. American Dreaming: Immigrant Life on the Mar-
Larson, J. E. 2002. “Informality, Illegality and Inequality.” Yale Law gins. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
and Policy Review 20:137–82. Mangin, W. 1967. “Latin American Squatter Settlements: A Problem
Leaf, M. 1993. “Land Rights for Residential Development in Jakarta, and a Solution. Latin American Research Review 2 (3): 65–98.
Indonesia: The Colonial Roots of Contemporary Urban Dualism.” Marx, C. 2009. “Conceptualising the Potential of Informal Land Mar-
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 17:477–91. kets to Reduce Urban Poverty.” International Development Plan-
Leaf, M. 2002. “A Tale of Two Villages: Globalization and Peri-urban ning Review 31 (4): 335–53.
Change in China and Vietnam.” Cities 19 (1): 23–31. Mathey, K. 1997. “Self-help Approaches to the Provision of Housing:
Leaf, M. 2005. “The Bazaar and the Normal: Informalization and The Long Debate and a Few Lessons.” In Cities in the Developing
Tertiarization in Urban Asia.” In Service Industries and Asia- World: Issues, Theory and Policy, edited by J. Gugler, , 280–90.
Pacific Cities, edited by P. W. Daniels, K. C. Ho, and T. A. Hatton, New York: Oxford University Press.
110–28. New York: Routledge. McAuslan, P. 2000. “Only the Name of the Country Changes: The
Leaf, M. 2007. “Chengzhongcun: China’s Urbanizing Villages Diaspora of ‘European’ Land Law in Commonwealth Africa.”
from Multiple Perspectives.” In Urbanization in China: Critical In Evolving Land Rights, Policy and Tenure in Africa, edited
Issues in an Era of Rapid Growth, edited by S. Yan and D. by C. Toulmin and J. Quan, 75–95. London, UK: IIED and
Chengri, 169–89. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute for Land NRI.
Policy. McAuslan, P. 2002. “Tenure and the Law. The Legality of Illegality
Leaf, M. 2009. “The Peri-urban Frontier of Ho Chi Minh City, Viet- and the Illegality of Legality.” In Land, Rights and Innovation,
nam.” Asia-Pacific Forum 43:55–75. edited by G. Payne, , 23–40. London, UK: ITDG.
Leaf, M. 2011. “Periurban Asia. A Commentary on ‘Becoming Urban. McFarlane, C., and M. Waibel. 2012. “Introduction.” In Urban
’” Pacific Affairs 84 (3): 525–34. Informalities: Reflections on the Formal and the Informal, edited
Leduka, R. C. 2006. “Chiefs, Civil Servants and City Council. State- by C. McFarlane and M. Waibel, 1–12. Farnham, UK: Ashgate.
society Relationships in Evolving Land Delivery Processes in McGee, T. G. 1991. “The Emergence of Desakota Regions in Asia:
Maseru, Lesotho.” International Development Planning Review Expanding a Hypothesis.” In The Extended Metropolis, edited by
28:181–208. N. Ginsberg, , B. Koppel, and T. McGee, 3–26. Honolulu: Univer-
Leeds, A., and E. Leeds. 1976. “Accounting for Behavioural Differences: sity of Hawaii Press.
Three Political Systems and the Responses to Squatters in Brazil, McGee, T. G., G. C. S. Lin, A. Marton, M. Y. L. Wang, and J. Wu.
Peru and Chile.” In The City in Comparative Perspective, edited by 2007. China’s Urban Space: Development under Market Social-
J. Walton and L. Masotti, 193–248. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage. ism. London, UK: Routledge.
Leontidou, L. 1990. The Mediterranean City in Transition: Social McKenzie, E. 2011. Beyond Privatopia: Rethinking Residential Pri-
Change and Urban Development. New York: Cambridge Univer- vate Government. Washington, DC: Urban Institute.
sity Press. Mendez, P., and N. Quastel. 2016. “Subterranean Commodification.
Li, J., and Y. Huang. 2012. “Housing Property Rights Disputes in Informal Housing and the Legalisation of Basement Suites in Van-
Urban Chinese Families: An Institutional and Sociological Per- couver from 1928 to 2009.” International Journal of Urban and
spective.” In Emergence of a New Urban China. Insiders’ Perspec- Regional Research 36 (6): 1155–71.
tives, edited by Z. Liang, S. F. Messner, C. Chen, and Y. Huang, Miraftab, F. 2009. “Insurgent Planning: Situating Radical Planning in
163–92. Lanham, MD: Lexington. the Global South.” Planning Theory 8 (1): 32–50.
Listokin, D., and D. Hattis. 2005. “Building Codes and Housing.” Monkkonen, P. 2013. “Urban Land-use Regulations and Housing
Cityscape 8 (1): 21–68. Markets in Developing Countries: Evidence from Indonesia on the
Lloyd, P. 1979. Slums of Hope? Shanty Towns of the Third World. Importance of Enforcement.” Land Use Policy 34:255–64.
Manchester, UK: Manchester University Press. Monkkonen, P., and L. Ronconi. 2016. “Comparative Evidence on
Lobo, S. 1992. A House of My Own. Social Organization in the Squat- Urban Land Use Regulation Bureaucracy in Developing Coun-
ter Settlements of Peru. Tucson: University of Arizona Press. tries.” In Slums: How Informal Real Estate Markets Work, edited
Logan, J., and H. Molotch. 1987. Urban Fortunes: The Political Econ- by E. Birch, S. Chattaraj, and S. Wachter, 24–46. Philadelphia:
omy of Place. Toronto, Canada: University of Toronto Press. University of Pennsylvania Press.
Losby, J. J., E. L. Edgcomb, J. Else, E. Malm, M. Kingslow, and V. Mooya, M. M. 2011. “Making Urban Real Estate Markets
Rao. 2002. Informal Economy Literature Review. Washington, Work for the Poor: Theory, Policy and Practice.” Cities 28:
DC: Institute for Social and Economic Development, and Aspen 238–44.
Institute. Accessed November 2, 2017. http://www.kingslow-as Moro, T. 2016a. “City Awarded Contracts to ‘Illegal’ Business.”
soc.com/images/Informal_Economy_Lit_Review.pdf. Hamilton Spectator, February 11. Accessed November 2, 2017.
18 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

https://www.thespec.com/news-story/ City, edited by R. Stren, , 389–416. Toronto, Canada: Centre for


6272741-city-awarded-contracts-to-illegal-business/. Urban and Community Studies, University of Toronto.
Moro, T. 2016b. “Illegal Businesses Costing City Millions, Com- Perlman, J. 1976. The Myth of Marginality: Urban Poverty and Pol-
mittee Told.” Hamilton Spectator, February 3. Accessed itics in Rio de Janeiro. Berkeley: University of California Press.
November 2, 2017. https://www.thespec.com/news-story/ Perlman, J. 2010. Favela: Four Decades of Living on the Edge in Rio
6259336-illegal-rural-businesses-costing-city-millions- de Janeiro. New York: Oxford University Press.
planning-committee-told/. Platteau, J.-P. 2002. “Does Africa Need Land Reform?” In Evolving
Moser, C. 1984. “The Informal Sector Reworked: Viability and Vul- Land Rights, Policy and Tenure in Africa, edited by C. Toulmin
nerability in Urban Development.” Regional Development Dialo- and J. Quan, 31–50. London, UK: International Institute for Envi-
gue 5 (2): 135–78. ronment and Development, and Natural Resources Institute.
Mukhija, V. 2012. “Informal Housing: Colonias in the United States.” Porter, L. 2011. “Informality, the Commons and the Paradoxes of
In International Encyclopedia of Housing and Home, edited by S. Planning: Concepts and Debates for Informality and Planning.”
Smith, 63–69. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: Elsevier. Planning Theory and Practice 12 (1): 115–20.
Mukhija, V. 2014. “Outlaw In-laws. Informal Second Units and the Portes, A., and W. Haller. 2005. “The Informal Economy.” In The
Stealth Reinvention of Single-family Housing.” In The Informal Handbook of Economic Sociology, edited by N. J. Smelser and R.
American City, edited by V. M. Mukhija and A. Loukaitou-Sideris, Swedberg, 403–25. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
39–57. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Potter, R. 1999. “Low Income Housing in the Third World City.” In
Mukhija, V., and A. Loukaitou-Sideris, eds. 2014. The Informal Amer- Applied Geography, edited by M. Pacione, , 497–508. London,
ican City. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. UK: Routledge.
Mukhija, V., and P. Monkkonen. 2006. “Federal Colonias Policy in Pugh, C. 1997. “Poverty and Progress? Reflections on Housing and
California. Too Broad and Too Narrow.” Housing Policy Debate Urban Policies in Developing Countries, 1976-1996.” Urban Stud-
17 (4): 755–80. ies 34 (10): 1547–95.
Myers, G. 2011. African Cities: Alternative Visions of Urban Theory Ray, T. F. 1969. The Politics of the Barrios of Venezuela. Los
and Practice. London, UK: Zed. Angeles: University of California Press.
Nair, J. 2005. The Promise of the Metropolis: Bangalore’s Twentieth Razzaz, O. 1994. “Contestation and Mutual Adjustment: The Process
Century. New Delhi, India: Oxford University Press. of Controlling Land in Yajouz, Jordan.” Law and Society Review
Neuwirth, R. 2006. Shadow Cities: A Billion Squatters, A New World. 28 (2): 1–39.
New York: Routledge. Razzaz, O. 1998. “Land Disputes in the Absence of Ownership Rights:
Nientied, P. 1998. “The Question of Town and Regional Planning in Insights from Jordan.” In Illegal Cities: Law and Urban Change in
Albania.” Habitat International 22 (1): 41–47. Developing Countries, edited by E. Fernandes and A. Varley,
Nissim, R. 2008. Land Administration and Practice in Hong Kong. 69–88. London, UK: Zed.
Hong Kong, China: Hong Kong University Press. Ren, X. 2017. “Governing the Informal: Housing Policies over Infor-
Nkurunziza, E. 2007. “Informal Mechanisms for Accessing and mal Settlements in China, India and Brazil.” Housing Policy
Securing Urban Land Rights. The Case of Kampala, Uganda.” Debate. Accessed November 2, 2017. https://www.scopus.com/
Environment and Urbanisation 19 (2): 509–26. record/display.uri?eid¼2-s2.0-85014516817&origin¼inward&
O’Sullivan, F. 2012. “Why Are Londoners Building Slums in Their txGid¼E6A88F4F785C2E499B26886F186C3A94.
Backyards?” Quartz, November 12. Accessed November 2, 2017. wsnAw8kcdt7IPYLO0V48gA%3a2.
http://qz.com/26594/ Robinson, J. 2002. “Global and World Cities: A View from Off the
why-are-londoners-building-slums-in-their-backyards/. Map.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 26
O’Sullivan, . 2016. “Berlin Is Banning Most Vacation Apartment (3): 531–54.
Rentals.” City Lab, April 28. Accessed November 2, 2017. Robinson, J. 2005. Ordinary Cities: Between Modernity and Devel-
http://www.citylab.com/housing/2016/04/airbnb-rentals-berlin-va opment. London, UK: Routledge.
cation-apartment-law/480381/. Rodwin, L. ed. 1987. Shelter, Settlement and Development. Boston,
Pamuk, A. 1996. “Convergence Trends in Formal and Informal Hous- MA: Allen and Unwin.
ing Markets: The Case of Turkey.” Journal of Planning Education Rogler, L. 1967. “Slum Neighborhoods in Latin America.” Journal of
and Research 16:103–13. Inter-American Studies 9:507–28.
Pamuk, A. 2000. “Informal Institutional Arrangements in Credit, Land Rose, C. M. 1988. “Crystals and Mud in Property Law.” Stanford Law
Markets and Infrastructure Delivery in Trinidad.” International Review 40 (3): 577–610.
Journal of Urban and Regional Research 24 (2): 379–96. Rose, C. M. 1994. Property and Persuasion: Essays on the History,
Payne, G. 1989. Informal Housing and Land Subdivision in Third Theory and Rhetoric of Private Ownership. Boulder, CO: West-
World Cities: A Review of the Literature. Oxford, UK: Centre for view Press.
Development and Environmental Planning. Rosen, C. M. 1986. The Limits of Power: Great Fires and the Process
Peattie, L. 1987. “An Idea in Good Currency and How It Grew: The of City Growth in America. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge Univer-
Informal Sector.” World Development 15 (7): 851–60. sity Press.
Peattie, L. 1995. “An Approach to Urban Research in the 1990s.” In Roy, A. 2003. City Requiem, Calcutta: Gender and the Politics of
Urban Research in the Developing World. 4. Perspectives on the Poverty. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Harris 19

Roy, A. 2005. “Urban Informality: Towards an Epistemology of Plan- Soni, A. 2000. “Urban Conquest of Outer Delhi: Beneficiaries, Inter-
ning.” Journal of the American Planning Association 71 (2): mediaries and the Victims. The Case of the Mehrauli Countryside.”
147–58. In Delhi: Urban Space and Human Destinies, edited by V. Dupont,
Roy, A. 2009. “Why India Cannot Plan Its Cities: Informality, Insur- E. Tarlo, and D. Vidal, 75–94. Delhi, India: Manohar-CSH.
gence and the Idiom of Urbanisation.” Planning Theory 8 (1): Springett, J. 1982. “Landowners and Urban Development: The Rams-
76–87. den Estate and Nineteenth-century Huddersfield.” Journal of His-
Roy, A. 2011. “Slumdog Cities: Rethinking Subaltern Urbanism.” torical Geography 8 (2): 129–44.
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 35 (3): Sun, L., and Z. Liu. 2015. “Illegal but Rational: Why Small Property
223–38. Rights Housing Is Big in China.” Land Lines (July):14–19, 34.
Santos, B. de S. 1977. “The Law of the Oppressed: The Construction Accessed November 2, 2017. https://www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/
and Reproduction of Legality in Pasagarda.” Law and Society 3566_Illegal-But-Rational–Why-Small-Property-Rights-Housing-
Review 12 (1): 5–126. Is-Big-in-China.
Sanyal, B., L. J. Vale, and C. D. Rosan, eds. 2012. Planning Ideas that Tabak, F. 2000. “Introduction: Informalization and the Long Term.”
Matter: Livability, Territoriality, Governance, and Reflective In Informalization. Process and Structure, edited by F. Tabak and
Practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. M. A. Critchlow, 1–20. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University
Sassen, S. 1988–1989. “New York City’s Informal Economy.” Insti- Press.
tute for Social Science Research IV. Paper 9, ISSR, New York. Tabak, F., and M. A. Critchlow, eds. 2000. Informalization: Process
Schenk, H., ed. 2001. Living in India’s Slums: A Case Study of and Structure. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Bangalore. New Delhi, India: Manohar-CSH. Tamanaha, B. Z. 2000. “A Non-essentialist Version of Legal Plural-
Schneiberg, M., and T. Bartley. 2001. “Regulating American Industries. ism.” Journal of Law and Society 27 (2): 296–321.
Markets, Politics, and the Institutional Determinants of Fire Insur- Tananescu, A. 2009. “Informal Housing in the Heart of the New West:
ance Regulation.” American Journal of Sociology 107 (1): 101–46. An Examination of State Tolerance of Illegality in Calgary.” North
Selmi, D. P. 2009. “Land Use Regulation by Contract.” Loyola-Los American Dialogue 12 (2): 1–11.
Angeles Legal Studies Paper No. 2009-51, Loyola Law School, Tighe, J. R., and E. J. Mueller, eds. 2013. The Affordable Housing
Los Angeles, CA. Reader. New York: Routledge.
Shahshahani, S. 2005. “Tehran. A Mega-city Built without a Vision.” Trefon, T., ed. 2004. Re-inventing Order in the Congo: How
In Directors of Urban Change in Asia, edited by P. Nas, , 227–44. People Respond to State Failure in Kinshasa. London, UK:
London, UK: Routledge. Zed Books.
Shieh, L. 2011. “Becoming Urban. Rural-urban Integration in Nanj- Tsenkova, S., and M. French. 2011. Affordable Land and Housing in
ing, Jiangsu Province.” Pacific Affairs 84 (3): 475–94. Europe and North America. Nairobi, Kenya: U.N. Habitat.
Simon, D. 1992. Cities, Capital and Development: African Cities in Turner, J. F. C. 1963. “Dwelling Resources in South America.” Archi-
the World Economy. London, UK: Belhaven. tectural Design 33:360–93.
Simon, D. 2008. “Urban Environments: Issues on the Peri-urban Turner, J. F. C. 1967. “Barriers and Channels for Housing Develop-
Fringe.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources 33:167–85. ment in Modernising Countries.” Journal of the American Institute
Simpson, J. R. 1976. Land Law and Registration. Cambridge, MA: of Planners 32 (3): 167–81.
Cambridge University Press. Turner, J. F. C., and R. Fichter. 1972. Freedom to Build. New York:
Sims, D. 2010. Understanding Cairo: The Logic of a City out of Macmillan.
Control. Cairo, Egypt: American University of Cairo. United Nations—Habitat. 2004. The Challenge of Slums. London,
Smart, A. 1999. “Predatory Rule and Illegal Economic Activities.” In UK: Earthscan.
States and Illegal Practices, edited by J. M. Heyman, , 99–128. US Bureau of Labor Statistics. 1922. Building Permits in the Principal
Oxford, UK: Berg. Cities of the United States, 1920. Washington, DC: USGPO.
Smart, A. 2001. “Unruly Places. Urban Governance and the Persis- Valverde, M. 2011. “Seeing Like a City. The Dialectic of Modern and
tence of Illegality in Hong Kong’s Urban Squatter Areas.” Amer- Premodern Ways of Seeing in Urban Governance.” Law and Soci-
ican Anthropologist 103 (1): 30–44. ety Review 45 (2): 277–312.
Smart, A., and F. Zerilli. 2014. “Extralegality.” In A Companion to Van Dongen, M. 2012a. “Rental Licensing Battle Looms.” Hamilton
Urban Anthropology, edited by D. M. Nonini, 222–38. New York: Spectator, August 22. Accessed November 2, 2017. https://www.
Wiley. thespec.com/news-story/2253729-rental-licensing-battle-looms/.
Smith, S., ed. 2012. International Encyclopedia of Housing and Van Dongen, M. 2012b. “Licensing Plan Threatens One Third of
Home. Amsterdam, the Netherlands: Elsevier. City’s In-house Rentals: Report.” Hamilton Spectator, December
Soares, B., and R. Stüssi. 1990. “Parallel Land Markets in the Lisbon 5. Accessed November 2, 2017. https://www.thespec.com/news-s
Region.” In The Transformation of Land Supply Systems in Third tory/2264048-licensing-plan-threatens-one-third-of-city-s-in-
World Cities, edited by P. Baross and J. van der Linden, 243–60. house-rentals-report/.
Aldershot, UK: Avebury. Van Dongen, M. 2013. “City Staff Swamped by Building Boom.”
Soliman, A. 2004. “Tilting at Sphinxes. Locating Urban Informality in Hamilton Spectator, November 6. Accessed November 2,
Egyptian Cities.” In Urban Informality, edited by A. Roy and N. 2017https://www.pressreader.com/canada/the-hamilton-spectator/
AlSayyad, 171–208. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books. 20131106/281586648355919
20 Journal of Planning Literature XX(X)

Van Dongen, M. 2014. “Unlicensed Businesses Escape Crackdown.” Weaver, J. 1982. Hamilton: An Illustrated History. Toronto, Canada:
Hamilton Spectator, March 24. Accessed November 2, 2017. Lorimer.
https://www.thespec.com/news-story/ Weaver, J. 2003. The Great Land Rush and the Making of the Modern
4427844-unlicensed-hamilton-businesses-escape-crackdown/. World, 1650-1900. Montreal, Canada: McGill-Queen’s University
Van Gelder, J.-L. 2010. “Tales of Deviance and Control: On Space, Press.
Rules, and Law in Squatter Settlements.” Law and Society Review Wegmann, J. 2015. “The Hidden Cityscapes of Informal Housing in
44:239–68. Suburban Los Angeles and the Paradox of Horizontal Density.”
Van Gelder, J.-L. 2013. “Paradoxes of Urban Housing Informality in Buildings and Landscapes 22 (2): 89–110.
the Developing World.” Law and Society Review 47 (3): 493–522. Weinstein, L. 2008. “Mumbai’s Development Mafias: Globalization,
Van Vliet, W. 1987. “Housing in the Third World.” Environment and Organized Crime and Land Development.” International Journal
Behaviour 19:267–86. of Urban and Regional Research 32 (1): 22–39.
Van Vliet, W., ed.1988. The Encyclopedia of Housing. Thousand Weiss, M. 1987. The Rise of the Community Builders: The American
Oaks, CA: Sage. Real Estate Industry and Urban Land Planning. New York:
Varley, A. 1998. “The Political Uses of Illegality: Evidence from Columbia University Press.
Urban Mexico.” In Illegal Cities: Law and Urban Change in Wesseler, S. 2015. “Inequality and Informality in New York.” Arch
Developing Countries, edited by E. Fernandes and A. Varley, Daily, January 19. Accessed November 2, 2017. http://www.arch
172–90. London, UK: Zed. daily.com/589157/inequality-and-informality-in-new-york-situ-
Verdery, K. 1999. “Fuzzy Property.” In Uncertain Transition: Ethnogra- studio-s-proposal-for-moma-s-uneven-growth-exhibition.
phies of Change in the Postsocialist World, edited by M. Burawoy and Wigle, J. 2010. “Social Relations, Property and Peripheral Urban
K. Verdery, 53–81. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield. Settlement: The Case of Ampliación San Marcos, Mexico City.”
Wallerstein, E. 2012. “Land, Space and People. Constraints of the Urban Studies 47 (2): 411–36.
Capitalist World Economy.” Journal of World Systems Research Yiftachel, O. 2009. “Theoretical Notes on ‘Gray’ Cities: The Coming
18 (1): 6–13. of Urban Apartheid.” Planning Theory 8:88–100.
Ward, P. M. 1999. Colonias and Public Policy in Texas and Mexico: Yonder, A. 1987. “Informal Land and Housing Market: The Case
Urbanization by Stealth. Austin: University of Texas Press. Study of Istanbul.” Journal of the American Planning Association
Ward, P. M. 2004. “Informality of Housing Production and the Urban- 53 (2): 213–19.
rural Interface: The ‘Not-so-strange Case of the Texas Colonias.”
In Urban Informality, edited by A. Roy and N. AlSayyad, 243–70.
Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.
Author Biography
Ward, P. M., E. R. J. Huerta, and M. M. Di Virgilio. 2014. Housing
Policy in Latin American Cities. New York: Routledge. Richard Harris is a fellow of the Royal Society of Canada, teaches
Ward, P. M., and P. A. Peters. 2007. “Self-help and Informal Home- urban geography at McMaster University. He has written about the
steading in Peri-urban America: Settlement Identification Using history of housing, neighborhoods, and suburbs in Canada, the United
Digital Imagery and GIS.” Habitat International 31:205–18. States, and British colonies. His latest book, co-edited with Charlotte
Way, H. K. 2010. “Informal Homeownership in the United States and Vorms, is What’s in a Name? Talking about Urban Peripheries
the Law.” St. Louis University Public Law Review 29 (1): 113–92. (Toronto, 2017).

You might also like