You are on page 1of 12

290 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Corporate Governance Policy


and Company Performance:
the Portuguese case
Carlos Alves and Victor Mendes*

Several supervisory authorities and governmental working groups issued corporate gover-
nance best practice codes for listed companies during the nineties. In this paper, we used a
unique database that allowed us to analyse the relationship between the level of compliance
of the code of best practice issued by the Portuguese Securities Market Commission and the
returns of the concerned companies. By using a multifactor model, one can conclude that there
is a positive relationship between the compliance of some of these recommendations and the
returns that were determined. The recommendations on the structure and functioning of the
executive board deserve a special attention. However, globally, CMVM’s code of best practice
doesn’t have a systematic effect on firm returns.

Keywords: Corporate governance, government policy, regulation, information disclosure and


performance

Introduction power given to managers of public companies.


However, these recommendations rarely take

T he study of corporate governance experi-


enced an important impulse in the 1990s.
It moved from the academic realm into the
into consideration the effects of best practice
on performance. In most cases, these measures
aim at a more effective market for corporate
gaze of the institutional debate and several control. Codes of best practice serve to com-
political measures were taken by governments pensate for deficiencies in the legal system
or government agencies. Included in this covering shareholders’ rights (Aguilera and
corporate landscape are: (i) several expert Cuervo-Cazurra, 2000). Such recommenda-
best practice codes (Cadbury, Greenburg and tions establish clear-cut information require-
Hampel for the UK, the Vienot for France ments and recommend the adoption of
and codes from commissions that were organisational structures that are more trans-
purposely created in Germany, Spain, The parent and that facilitate effective monitoring.
Netherlands and Italy); (ii) recommenda- Furthermore, the adoption of manager remu-
tions on various subjects of corporate gover- neration mechanisms able to induce closer
nance issued by international bodies such as alignment with the shareholders’ interests is
the OECD, and by supervisory agencies of recommended. Apparently, aspects related to
*Author for correspondence:
securities markets (e.g. Belgium, Greece and stimulating corporate performance do not
CMVM, Avenida da Liberdade Portugal). carry the same attention. However, there are
252, 1250 Lisboa, Portugal. These codes of best practice aim at adopt- doubts about the applicability of such codes,
Tel: (351) 213177000; Fax:
(351) 213537077/8; E-mail: ing mechanisms that will enhance effective in Continental Europe, because of lower
victormendes@cmvm.pt investor protection over the discretionary enforceability of norms (Cuervo, 2002).

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004. 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford,


Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004 OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.
CORPORATE GOVERNANCE POLICY AND COMPANY PERFORMANCE 291

According to Cuervo (2002), rather than pro- incentive contracts are not immune to criti-
moting codes of good governance, it is neces- cisms regarding their capacity to align the
sary to expand market control mechanisms to interests of managers and shareholders, inas-
facilitate the maximisation of firm value. Sim- much as managers carry out their options
ilarly, Jong et al. (2002) find that The Nether- shortly before the bad news and postpone this
lands’ private sector initiative on self-regulation exercise after the good news (Yermack, 1997),
fault improved corporate governance and had securing in this way their interests from
no relationship with corporate value. the impact fluctuations of their management
Many of the literature contributions have decisions.
given rise to reservations, which are usually In sum, a set of very expressive political
profiled by supervisory authorities, as to the standings has recently emerged regarding cor-
efficiency of some of the control mechanisms. porate governance, but its impact and rele-
There is empirical evidence that supports the vance are yet to be evaluated. The evaluation
idea that some of the measures acclaimed by of the effect of different solutions and of the
many public powers have a negative effect on different mechanisms recommended by public
the performance of the companies that adopt powers on performance is an exercise yet to be
them. In fact, the issue of efficiency is two- carried out. This exercise must be done, not
pronged. Whilst supervisory authorities only to evaluate the importance and suitabil-
discourage the adoption of anti-takeover ity of the measures that are advised and
measures, some authors note the controversy imposed, but to establish the most adequate
of this issue since managers of target compa- ways for the necessary readjustments.
nies usually oppose public offers (see Jensen This study analyses the relationship
(1993) amongst others). Grossman and between the degree of compliance with the
Hart (1980) show that the functioning of recommendations from CMVM1 and the
market control mechanisms and in particular returns of public companies. The purpose of
takeovers may suffer from free rider problems. this study is to investigate if companies com-
On the same note, Shleifer and Vishny (1988) plying with the corporate governance best
forewarn about the possibility of takeovers practice recommended by CMVM distinguish
intensifying agency problems when managers themselves from those companies that present
use company resources to launch offers over lower levels of compliance. In 1999, CMVM
other companies and overpay for acquisitions issued a set of recommendations aimed at
that bring them private benefits of control. listed companies. These recommendations are
This would be a way for these managers to intended to induce companies into increased
gain more power and obtain more private transparency, to ease the exercise of share-
benefits, and would require liquid capital holder rights by investors, to avoid the adop-
markets. To exemplify this, some political tion of mechanisms that hamper the control of
powers are in favour of boards that are con- corporate governance by the market, and to
trolled by, or at least composed of, inde- advise on ways of organisation and function-
pendent managers in order to obtain more ing of the board of directors with a view to
effective monitoring of the executive man- ensuring the full representation of a multiplic-
agers’ actions. However, Zahra (1996) argues ity of the shareholders’ interests as regards the
that the fact that CEOs play an important role decision-making process.
in the selection, remuneration and retention This paper is organised as follows. In the
of outside directors limits their power and next section, we describe CMVM’s code of
monitoring capacity. Porter (1992) suggests best practice and the questionnaires sent to
that non-executive directors do not possess listed companies, followed by a section on
either the information or the time to absorb the dataset. The fourth section describes the
all the necessary data to understand the methodology and explains the model of equi-
functioning of the company. On the other librium used to compute returns. The results
hand, their goals are minimal and that concurs section is followed by our conclusions.
with less commitment in management
monitoring.
As regards the effects on performance, some Portuguese corporate
studies indicate that executive boards of direc-
tors controlled by outside directors tend to governance policy
have less research and development expenses
(Baysinger et al., 1991). Some have also argued
CMVM’S code of best practices
that these boards tend to not follow through In October 1999, CMVM issued a set of
on consistent innovation strategies aimed at non-compulsory recommendations on different
the creation of new areas of business and subjects regarding corporate governance.
venturing (Zahra, 1996). On the other hand, They were classified by CMVM (1999) into

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004


292 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

distinct groups: (i) recommendations re- quotations adjusted for corporate events (like
garding disclosure of information (G1); dividends, stock splits, etc.), the number of
(ii) recommendations regarding voting and shares issued by each company as well as the
shareholder representation (G2); (iii) a set annual and bi-annual account information
of recommendations on the adoption of that was necessary for the calculation of the
certain corporate internal rules of best company’s book value, are from Dathis. The 3-
practice (G3); and (iv) recommendations on month interbank bid rate series (3M-Lisbor),
the structure and functioning of the board of used as a proxy for the risk-free interest rate,
directors (G4). and the stock indexes were also obtained from
This code of best practice was modelled on Dathis.
OECD guidelines, and includes 17 recom- The annual publications of BVLP and quo-
mendations, 15 directly related with listed tation bulletins were used not only to validate
companies and two related with institutional the annual accounting information that was
investors. In Table 1 we summarise the Por- extracted from Dathis, but also in suppressing
tuguese corporate governance policy and existing gaps, namely when information
identify the CMVM individual relates to past years.
recommendations.

Questionnaires sent to listed companies The degree of compliance


of the recommendations
Soon after CMVM’s recommendations were
issued, CMVM sent out three questionnaires In calculating the degree of compliance of each
to companies listed on the Lisbon Stock of the recommendations and sets of recom-
Exchange (BVLP). These questionnaires aimed mendations, we defined the following vari-
at enquiring which companies comply, and ables: firstly, a dummy variable for each of the
those that do not, with the code of best prac- 13 recommendations. This variable takes on
tice. The reference dates of the questionnaires the value 1 if the company complied with the
are 31 December 1998, 31 March 2000 and 31 recommendation2 and 0 otherwise. We then
March 2001. The questionnaires were sent to computed the degree of compliance for each
82 companies with shares listed on the Lisbon of the four sets of recommendations and
main market. The number of respondent com- bestowed each recommendation within each
panies was 60, 44 and 50, respectively, for each group with equal importance. These variables
questionnaire. are identified as G1, G2, G3 and G4. Lastly,
The first questionnaire comprised 20 ques- we proceeded to calculate the overall level
tions, and the second and third questionnaires of compliance of the 13 recommendations
included 24 questions. All questions are mul- (G), again using the same weight for each
tiple choice. There are no questions concern- recommendation.
ing recommendations R5 and R11; therefore Table 2 shows the degree of compliance for
this paper analyses the compliance of 13 each recommendation and set of recommen-
recommendations only. Besides this, the 1998 dations. There is a reasonable balance between
questionnaire does not include questions the complying and non-complying companies
related to recommendations R2 and R4 – except for R8, R9 and R14. The number of com-
something that did not occur in the following plying companies for R8 is two at most (for the
questionnaires. 2001 questionnaire), and none for the first
questionnaire. Therefore, extra care must be
taken with the interpretation of the results for
G2 inasmuch as that during certain periods
Dataset there is a very small number of complying
Sample and database companies. But that is not the case for the
other recommendations and sets of re-
Our sources of information are: (i) the commendations. For example, in the 2000
responses to the questionnaires sent by questionnaire the percentage of complying
CMVM to listed companies; (ii) the DATHIS companies varies between 27 per cent and 86
database at BVLP, with market and accounting per cent.
information for listed companies; (iii) the Table 2 also shows that there is an im-
annual publications issued by BVLP with provement in the compliance of the recom-
yearly accounting information on listed mendations during the course of time. On
companies, and (iv) the (daily) quotation the other hand, with the exception of G2,
bulletins of BVLP. companies comply with about half of the
The quotation series and the series on recommendations.

Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE POLICY AND COMPANY PERFORMANCE 293

Table 1: CMVM code of best practices

Corporate governance CMVM Recommendation


issue recommendations
Number Group

Board Size Number necessary to provide effective guidance. No specific number R12 G4
suggested.
Limit on Number of Boards per No specific limit, but directors must be able to exercise effective control R12 G4
Director over the day-to-day management of the company.
Board Independence At least one independent director. R13 G4
Definition of Independence Each company determines the concept of independent director which is R13 G4
best suited to its particular characteristics, and that the said concept is
explained publicly.
Separate Chair/CEO Not covered. – –
Executive Committee It is recommended that the composition of the executive committee be a R14 G4
true reflection of the balance existing within the board of directors.
Audit Committee Not covered, because law provides for statutory auditors. – –
Other Committees It is encouraged to set up internal control committees, with the power to R15 G4
interfere in relation to all matters that could potentially lead to
conflicts of interests, such as the evaluation of corporate structure and
governance.
Internal Corporate Rules It is recommended that companies establish internal rules, aimed at R10 G3
efficiently solve conflicts of interest among members of the board and
the company.
Remuneration Committee Not covered, because by law this committee is nominated by shareholders – –
Composition general meeting.
Executive Pay Disclosure Not covered. According to the Portuguese law there is an annual report – –
for global board members remuneration.
Severance Contracts Not covered. – –
One Share, One Vote Not covered. According to the Portuguese law the corporate bylaw defines – –
the equivalence between the number of shares and votes.
Proxy Votes The active exercising of voting rights, whether directly, by post or by R8 and G2
proxy, is encouraged. CMVM stresses the importance of promoting the R9
perfection of procedures linked to requests for representation by proxy.
Timely Meeting Notice and The use of new information technology resources is encouraged with R6 G1
Information respect to the disclosure of financial information and of preparatory
documents for General Meetings.
Director Attendance Disclosure Each listed company is required to ensure the appointment of a permanent R7 G1
representative for liaison with the market. The creation of a department
designed to assist investors is also recommended.
Corporate Governance Statement The publicity of organigrams and diagrams is recommended. Also, it is R1 and G1
encouraged to disclose information on the functions carried out by each R2
member of the board and the managers of the company, as well as the
job positions that they hold in other companies.
Takeover Defences Measures adopted to prevent the success of takeovers are discouraged. R11 G3
Shareholder Agreements It is encouraged to disclose information on any shareholders agreements R5 G1
regarding the transmission of shares.
Board Explanation The board of directors is encouraged to explain the behaviour of the R3 G1
company’s shares in the stock market, and the relevant facts that occur.
Dividend Policy The board of directors is encouraged to disclose and explain the dividend R4 G1
policy.
Institutional Investors Activism Institutional investors activism is encouraged. [*] [*]
Institutional Investors Disclosure Institutional investors should disclose all information on their exercising [*] [*]
of the voting rights afforded to them by the securities they are called
upon to manage.

Obs.: [*] Institutional investors best practices aren’t covered by this study.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004


294 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Table 2: Degree of compliance with the recommendations

Year Complying companies by recommendation

R1 R2 R3 R4 R6 R7 R8 R9 R10 R12 R13 R14 R15

1998* 9 NA 35 NA 17 36 0 4 31 54 42 8 23
15% 58% 28% 60% 0% 7% 52% 90% 70% 13% 38%
2000* 16 12 31 31 19 33 1 5 24 38 31 3 16
36% 27% 70% 70% 43% 75% 2% 11% 55% 86% 70% 7% 36%
2001* 25 17 44 36 28 37 2 6 34 42 36 7 22
50% 34% 88% 72% 56% 74% 4% 12% 68% 84% 72% 14% 44%

Level of compliance by set of recommendations

Average Standard deviation

G G1 G2 G3 G4 G G1 G2 G3 G4

1998 0.39 0.40 0.03 0.52 0.53 0.14 0.28 0.13 0.50 0.19
2000 0.45 0.54 0.07 0.56 0.50 0.16 0.26 0.21 0.50 0.20
2001 0.52 0.62 0.08 0.68 0.54 0.20 0.30 0.21 0.47 0.27

* In the first line, we have the number of complying companies, and in the second the percentage number
of the respondent companies.
For each company and questionnaire G, G1, G2, G3 and G4 were calculated as follows: (i) G = SRi/n, where
n is the number of used recommendations in each questionnaire (i.e. 11 for the 1998 questionnaire and 13
for the remaining questionnaires); (ii) Gj = SRi/nj, where nj represents the numbers of recommendations of
group j (j = 1, . . . , 4). NA: not available.

Methodology features. Hence, this procedure does not allow


distinguishing which part of the return
We use econometric analysis in a two-step surplus is explained by the specific risk of the
process. In the first step, we estimate asset asset, and which part is explained by corpo-
returns; in the second we use first-step inde- rate governance variables. Bhagat and Black
pendent variable coefficient estimates as (1998) claim to prefer performance bench-
dependent variables in models in which the marks not adjusted for the specific risk of each
explanatory variables include compliance firm as a means to obviate the objections of
indicators of the corporate governance best Barber and Lyon (1997). We are in favour of
practices. using market returns adjusted for the specific
risk of the asset, caring to verify the robustness
of the results in the face of alternative period-
Equilibrium model icities of portfolio rebalancing, as well as of
Many of the studies that have analysed the alternative calculation methods of such
impact on companies of diverse corporate returns and of the explanatory factors of
governance solutions evaluate performance those returns.
using accountancy variables (Chaganti and The bulk of the existing literature on the
Damanpour, 1991), Tobin’s Q (Jong et al., 2002) subject of corporate governance and company
or, when resorting to market returns, do not performance uses an event study framework
adjust returns for the specific risk of the firm. (e.g. Comment and Schwert, 1995; Kang and
When this is the case, the excess return of each Shivdasani, 1995; Jong et al., 2002). That is not
stock is established in face of the market return the case in this paper. Here, we test whether
(Chaganti and Damanpour, 1991; Kang and corporate governance variables are useful
Shivdasani, 1995; and Bhagat and Black, 1998). for the explanation of firm’s performance.
As such, these studies choose not to confront However, we do not want to establish any
the returns of each asset with the equilibrium causality relationship between performance
return of that asset according to its specific indicators and governance variables; we aim

Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE POLICY AND COMPANY PERFORMANCE 295

at checking whether there is any significant were used with at least a six months’ time lag.
correlation between corporate governance and As for market value, the daily figures are
company performance.3 instantly known and were used. The continu-
On the subject of the returns’ evaluation ous return cumulated during the last 12
model, we use the Fama and French (1993) months was computed excluding the return of
model for stocks, expanded to include the the most recent month in order to eliminate
“momentum” effect (Jegadeesh and Titman, microstructure-associated problems.
1993) and the January-effect (Keim, 1983): The method used is different to the one used
by Liew and Vassalou (2000) in two main
Ri ,t = a i + bi PSI t + hi HMLt + si SMBt aspects. These authors created three portfolios
(1)
+ giWMLt + di Dt + e it , for each ‘sort’ (high, low and average),
totalling 27 portfolios. Due to the reduced size
where Rit is the average excess return of the
of the Portuguese market, in our case, in the
asset/portfolio i (vis-à-vis the return of the
sorting process each group was divided into
Lisbor 3M interest rate) on week t (t = 1, . . .,
two, making a total of eight portfolios. On the
T); PSI represents the average excess return of
other hand, since this method has the disad-
the PSI Geral index4 (vis-à-vis the Lisbor 3M
vantage that results may depend on the order
interest rate return); HML corresponds to the
of the sorts, we did repeat the portfolio cre-
factor intended to quantify the average excess
ation process 24 times with the necessary
return of high book-to-market-stocks in face of
adaptations, changing the order of the sorts.
the return of a reduced book-to-market ratio;
We’ve also allowed two alternative weighting
SMB is intended to capture the size effect, and
corresponds to the average return of a portfo- methods for each asset: “market value weight-
lio which is long in small caps and short in big MVW” and “equal weight-EW”. In addition,
caps; WML measures the average excess we calculated an overall average (C29) and
return of high cumulative return stocks vis- four partial averages (C25, C26, C27 and C28).
à-vis low cumulative return stocks; D is a Table 3 shows these different criteria. Liew
dummy variable, taking on the value 1 if the and Vassalou (2000) use one criterion only.
week is January, and 0 otherwise; and e is a Our results show that there is greater
random error term. consistency when one uses MVW portfolios.
When calculating these factors, a similar The C1 criterion that was used by Liew and
method to that of Liew and Vassalou (2000)5 Vassalou (2000) originated some inconsistent
was used. The method consists of dividing all results. Criteria C25 and C27 show an excel-
listed companies in a three-step process.6 lent consistency and are both equally capable
Firstly, companies were ranked from the of minimising the effect of the ordering crite-
higher to the lowest book-to-market, being ria on the obtained estimates. Results reported
divided into two groupings (H and L). Sec- in this paper refer to criterion C25, meaning
ondly, in each grouping, stocks were ranked that we opted for the quarterly rebalancing in
in accordance with their market value, order to obtain greater proximity with the
originating four portfolios (HS, HB, LS and daily periodicity rebalancing of the General
LB). Subsequently, in each of the four estab- PSI benchmark.
lished groupings, stocks were divided in
accordance with the cumulated return in the Two-step regressions
previous year, creating winners and losers. A
We used equation (1) for each of the respon-
total of eight portfolios were thus obtained
dent companies and for each questionnaire.
(HSW, HSL, HBW, HBL, LSW, LSL, LBW and
The weekly average of the daily continuous
LBL).7
returns was used as dependent variable. The
Finally, the return series of the various
estimation period corresponds to the period
factors were computed considering the con-
between the reference date of the question-
tinuous daily returns of each portfolio, using:
naire and the reference date of the next ques-
HML = 1 4 * ((HSL - LSL) + (HSW - LSW) tionnaire. For the 2001 questionnaire we used
(2) the reference date of this study (31 July 2001).
+ (HBL - LBL) + (HBW - LBW));
Overall, we did estimate 154 equations,
SMB = 1 4 * ((HSL - HBL) + (HSW - HBW) 60 relating to the first questionnaire, 44 the
+ (LSL - LBL) + (LSW - LBW)); (3) second and 50 the third.
In the second step, equation (1) a estimates
WML = 1 4 * ((HSW - HSL) + (HBW - HBL) were used as dependent variables in other
+ (LSW - LSL) + (LBW - LBL)). (4) regressions. Alternatively, raw returns were
also used. In this second round, the explana-
The return factors were calculated for quar- tory variables were the measures of compli-
terly and half-yearly rebalances. The data ance with CMVM’s recommendations (G, G1,

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004


296 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Table 3: Return-based factors criteria

Rebalance order Rebalance period Weighting

C1 B/M; MV; CCR Quarterly MVW


C2 B/M; MV; CCR Quarterly EW
C3 B/M; MV; CCR Half-yearly MVW
C4 B/M; MV; CCR Half-yearly EW
C5 B/M; CCR; MV Quarterly MVW
C6 B/M; CCR; MV Quarterly EW
C7 B/M; CCR; MV Half-yearly MVW
C8 B/M; CCR; MV Half-yearly EW
C9 MV; B/M; CCR Quarterly MVW
C10 MV; B/M; CCR Quarterly EW
C11 MV; B/M; CCR Half-yearly MVW
C12 MV; B/M; CCR Half-yearly EW
C13 MV; CCR; B/M Quarterly MVW
C14 MV; CCR; B/M Quarterly EW
C15 MV; CCR; B/M Half-yearly MVW
C16 MV; CCR; B/M Half-yearly EW
C17 CCR; B/M; MV Quarterly MVW
C18 CCR; B/M; MV Quarterly EW
C19 CCR; B/M; MV Half-yearly MVW
C20 CCR; B/M; MV Half-yearly EW
C21 CCR; MV; B/M Quarterly MVW
C22 CCR; MV; B/M Quarterly EW
C23 CCR; MV; B/M Half-yearly MVW
C24 CCR; MV; B/M Half-yearly EW

C25 average of C1, C5, C9, C13, C17 and C21


C26 average of C2, C6, C10, C14, C18 and C22
C27 average of C3, C7, C11, C15, C19 and C23
C28 average of C4, C8, C12, C16, C20 and C24
C29 average of C1 to C24

B/M: Book-to-market.
MV: Market value.
CCR: Continuous cumulative return.

G2, G3 and G4) for each company and each that there is a high probability that the com-
questionnaire. Other explanatory variables panies included on the PSI20 also show a high
were W, BM, CR12 and P20. W is the average W value. Given the relevance of a small
monthly weight of the market value per share number of companies in the total market value
relative to the overall market capitalization. and the PSI20 market value, W does not, by
This variable controls for the size of the firm. itself, guarantee the attainment of a probable
BM controls for the book-to-market effect and liquidity effect. Therefore, P20 is intended
is the average month-end value of the book- to capture the liquidity effect.
to-market ratio of each share. CR12 is the (12-
month) cumulative8 continuous return of the
share, and controls for the ‘momentum’ effect. Raw and risk-adjusted returns
P20 takes on the value 1 if the share belongs to
the PSI20 index at the date of the questionnaire Results of the second step regressions (with
in the first step regression, and 0 otherwise. 154 observations) are in Table 4.9 Our estimates
The PSI20 index includes the 20 blue ships of show the relevance of some corporate gover-
the Portuguese stock market (selected accord- nance variables. In fact, G4 exhibits a positive
ing to size and liquidity criteria). This means effect on both raw and abnormal returns, and

Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE POLICY AND COMPANY PERFORMANCE 297

Table 4: Second step regression results

Constant Independent Variables R2Adj.

G G1 G2 G3 G4 W BM CR12 P20

Panel I. Dependent Variable: Abnormal Returns


0.00038 -0.00052 0.00969 0.00002 0.51680* -0.00105*** 18.35%
0.00007 -0.00054 0.00097 -0.00057 0.00134**** 0.00804 -0.00005 0.51099* -0.00106*** 19.76%
-0.00018 -0.00088 0.00108 -0.00054 0.00136**** 0.00178 0.00017 0.56338* 18.41%
0.00003 -0.00050 0.00112 -0.00057 0.00146*** -0.00008 0.52292* -0.00074*** 19.58%
-0.00020 -0.00058**** 0.00143*** 0.52285* -0.00076* 20.41%
Panel II. Dependent Variable: Raw Returns
-0.00001 -0.00129 0.00614 0.00018 0.83008* -0.00070 41.62%
-0.00031 -0.00118*** -0.00016 -0.00031 0.00122**** 0.00495 0.00007 0.82522* -0.00069 42.97%
-0.00047 -0.00141** -0.00010 -0.00029 0.00123**** 0.00085 0.00022 0.85952* 42.57%
-0.00033 -0.00116*** -0.00007 -0.00031 0.00130*** 0.00005 0.83256* -0.00050 43.09%
-0.00059 -0.00127** 0.00125*** 0.00460 0.00015 0.83859* -0.00057 43.11%

In Panel I the dependent variable corresponds to the a coefficient estimates of equation (1), determined in the first-step regressions.
In Panel II the dependent variable is the average of Rij (raw returns) of equation (1).
The symbols *, **, *** and **** show statistical significance at 1%, 5%, 10% and 15%, respectively.

G1 has a negative impact on raw returns. Moreover, (ii) we run another regression
Amongst the control variables, CR12 and P20 with all 13 individual R’s and the four control
show some capacity to explain the cross- variables. R4, R10, R12 and R14 revealed to be
section estimates of abnormal returns. significant. Finally, (iii) we estimated 13
Also worthy of note is that neither the equations, each one of them including one
overall level of code of best practice com- corporate governance variable only. R4, R7,
pliance (G), nor the level of compliance of R10, R12 and R14 turned out significant.12
groups 2 (G2) and 3 (G3) have any signi- Results of our final estimations are in Table
ficant statistical effect on returns. We can 5. The explanatory variables were those
therefore conclude that, overall, CMVM re- selected in (i), (ii) and (iii), and the control
commendations are not associated to any variables W, BM, CR12 and P20. The White test
effect, be it positive or negative, on returns of did show no sign of heteroskedasticity. Our
the different companies. In other words, results confirm the statistical relevance of G3.13
although G1 and G4 reveal statistical signifi- They also show that the positive effect of G4
cance, the various recommendation groups is due to recommendation R14. Finally, re-
show opposite signs, evidencing that, on commendation R4 included in group G1
average, the global effect of those recommen- shows a negative effect on the abnormal and
dations is negligible. raw return estimates.
However, the White heteroskedasticity test It seems appropriate therefore to conclude
does not allow us to accept the null hypothe- upon the relevance of the results and observe
sis in Table 4 regressions.10 Therefore, we shall the lack of performance differences between
not give special relevance to the statistical tests companies that follow and those that do not
performed. follow three out of the four recommendations
Looking now at the individual recommen- regarding information disclosure. In other
dations (Ri), we try to find out which of them words, investors do not seem to reward com-
is relevant for the explanation of abnormal panies that disclose information. By the same
returns. In other words, (i) we did estimate token, they do not penalise them. This might
four equations11 in which we include W, BM, be explained, we speculate, by two circum-
CR12 and P20 as control variables, as well as stances. On the one hand, investors resort to
that group’s individual Ri variables. We then financial intermediaries and these may not
selected the relevant explanatory variables in require that the information be disclosed in
each equation: R4 and R7 in the first, R10 in order to know how corporate governance
the third, and R14 in the fourth equation. is carried out in each of the Portuguese

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004


298 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

Table 5: Second step regressions with individual recommendations

Constant Independent variables R2Adj.

R4 R7 R10 R12 R14 W BM CR12 P20

Panel I. Dependent Variable: Abnormal Returns


0.0040* -0.0029* -0.0020** -0.0017**** 0.0007 0.0024** 29.04%
0.0032*** -0.0026** -0.0016 -0.0017*** 0.0014 0.0027** 0.0099 0.0005 0.5243*** -0.0016 34.15%
0.0029*** -0.0025** -0.0020** 0.0009 0.0028** 0.0088 0.0004 0.4677**** -0.0023**** 32.36%
0.0044* -0.0027** -0.0013 -0.0017*** 0.0028** 0.0113 0.0003 0.4992*** -0.0018 39.68%
0.0006 -0.0009*** 0.0012*** 0.0093 0.0001 0.5435* -0.0014*** 21.50%
Panel II. Dependent Variable: Raw Returns
0.0029*** -0.0022** -0.0022** -0.0010 0.0000 0.0018**** 19.14%
0.0026**** -0.0017**** -0.0017*** -0.0012 0.0008 0.0023** 0.0062 0.0000 0.7791* -0.0020 36.14%
0.0023 -0.0016**** -0.0015**** 0.0003 0.0024** 0.0050 -0.0001 0.7172* -0.0028** 33.06%
0.0033** -0.0017*** -0.0015**** -0.0012 0.0023** 0.0070 -0.0002 0.7641* -0.0021**** 45.75%
0.0026** -0.0016**** -0.0015*** 0.0024** 0.0056 -0.0002 0.7327* -0.0028** 43.63%
0.0016**** -0.0021** 0.0023** 0.0083 0.0000 0.7772* -0.0026** 41.02%

In Panel I the dependent variable corresponds to the a coefficient estimates of equation (1), determined in the first-step regressions.
In Panel II the dependent variable is the average of Rij (raw returns) of equation (1).
The symbols *, **, *** and **** show statistical significance at 1%, 5%, 10% and 15%, respectively.

companies. On the other hand, it is not costly R10 on the regulation of situations regarding con-
to generate and disclose information. flicts of interest among members of the board and
This is not true for R4. This recommendation of the company. There is evidence that compa-
is related to information disclosure on divi- nies that show less concern for the level of pre-
dend policy. It seems that investors do not vention and clarification of situations related
like what they see when they look at the to conflicts of interest among members of the
announced dividend policy. In other words, board and the company show higher perfor-
investors seem not to penalise those societies mances and vice-versa. Owing to the fact that
that do not disclose information regarding the this is somewhat unexpected, it is important to
firm’s dividend policy, but seem to penalise emphasise that this variable controls only one
those that announce their policy.14 recommendation of the two that integrate
It could also happen that investors may not the group, since none of the questionnaires
take into account the informational aspects of quantifies the compliance or non-compliance
corporate governance and therefore do not of recommendation R11.
think it relevant. However, this hypothesis The most significant fact regarding corpo-
hardly coincides with the results obtained for rate governance variables is the result for
G3 (R10), and particularly G4 (R14), since G4. The analysis of individual recommenda-
many aspects of the information referring to tions shows that R14 is the more relevant.
G1 are based on the disclosure of solutions Among the four groups of CMVM recommen-
related to the organisation and structure of the dations, only G4 refers to recommendations
company (in G4). Thus, market does not seem on the organisational structure of the compa-
to be indifferent to the essence, but only to the nies and the modus operandi of the board
way and manner the information is disclosed. members. As seen in earlier, one has included
This being so, the interest of the first group recommendations regarding the organisation
of CMVM recommendations would only be of the board of directors and the executive
investors’ protection, particularly those commission, so that they represent the many
investors that seem to have more difficulty in interests of shareholders. Entailed in this
obtaining information from financial inter- group is the recommendation that the board of
mediaries,15 and those that do not have enough directors should include one or more inde-
market power to penalise non-complying pendent members, so as to maximise the
companies. interests of the company. Our results re-
As previously explained, group G3 only garding R14 indicate that companies that
controls the compliance of recommendation abided by the CMVM recommendation on the

Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE POLICY AND COMPANY PERFORMANCE 299

organisational structure and the manner of doesn’t have a systematic effect on returns. In
functioning of the board of directors show other words, the different groups of recom-
higher estimates for abnormal returns. However, mendations show opposing effects and there-
the other recommendations included in G4 fore the total effect of those recommendations
(R12, R13 and R16) do not exhibit any relevant is negligible. On the other hand, there is a pos-
effect, R12 showing a positive effect when we itive relationship between compliance with
include all 13 recommendations as explana- CMVM recommendations on the structure and
tory variables. functioning of the board of directors and abnor-
As depicted above, there is the perception mal returns. This relationship, however, is
that the concerns on effectiveness and effi- mainly attributed to the compliance with re-
ciency have not always been present the re- commendations on the executive committee.
commendations of supervisory authorities. On top of this, it was possible to obtain a pos-
Besides this and as previously mentioned, itive and significant association between esti-
there are theories (e.g. Porter, 1992; Zahra, mated abnormal returns and recommendation
1996) that defend the idea that the presence of R14. Another interesting result was obtained
independent members creates a negative rela- for R13, regarding independent directors: a
tionship with the performance of the board of negligible association on the performance of
directors and consequently the company. the company. We have also found evidence of
This result seems to indicate that even a negative relationship between G3 and the
though performance concerns were not em- companies’ performance. The disclosure of
bodied by the CMVM at the time of the information regarding the company’s divi-
issue of its recommendations regarding the dend policy was also found negatively corre-
organisational structure of companies, these lated with abnormal returns, suggesting that
measures cannot be associated with abnormal investors have not liked the information that
negative performances. Quite to the contrary, companies have disclosed regarding these
there is an indication of a positive association matters.
between the above-normal returns and the We should finally note that it would be
level of compliance of the recommendation of important to study the relationship between
CMVM. On the other hand, it is true that we recommendation compliance and firm’s expo-
cannot consider R13 responsible for a negative sure to the different factors of return genera-
and significant effect. It is also true that when tion. It would be interesting to evaluate
the executive committee exists and operates whether corporate governance effects are
according to the recommended terms the stronger than other return generating effects,
company tends to exhibit higher abnormal originating profitable strategies for portfolio
returns. On top of this, we have also noted a creation. This will be done in future studies.
slightly positive relationship between R12 The disclosure of information regarding the
and the performance of the company. dividend policy deserves future attention
The results in Tables 3 and 4 further allow as well.
us to conclude that accumulated returns are
relevant in explaining the cross differences of
the weekly abnormal returns notwithstanding Acknowledgements
the inclusion of the ‘momentum’ effect: CR12
estimates are positive, meaning that abnormal We wish to acknowledge comments by W.
returns are higher when the absolute returns Ness, K. Peasnell, J. Pinegar, participants at the
are higher too. Finally, it is important to note 2nd Portuguese Finance Network Conference,
the relevance of P20. The P20 effect cannot be the EFMA 2002 Meeting, and the FMA 2002
confused in this context with the size effect. Meeting, and two anonymous referees. Carlos
Actually, when one repeats the regression and Alves also acknowledges support from
excludes W, P20 remains significant. The P20 CEMPRE. CEMPRE is supported by FCT
effect must therefore be interpreted as an through POCTI of the QCAIII, which is
‘award’ that is required by investors so that financed by FEDER and Portuguese funds.
they invest in less liquid companies. The usual disclaimer applies.

Conclusions Notes
1. The Portuguese Securities Market Commission.
Our results show that there exists a relation- 2. We use the valuation criteria of the supervisory
ship between the compliance of some cor- authority itself on the compliance or non-
porate governance recommendations and compliance of each of the recommendations.
computed (abnormal) returns. They also show 3. Soon after our empirical work was completed,
that, globally, CMVM’s code of best practices a new paper came out using this methodology.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004


300 CORPORATE GOVERNANCE

In the words of Gompers et al., “Like most R&D Strategy, Academy of Management Journal, 34,
examples of legal origin and change, the gov- 205–214.
ernance structures of a firm are not exogenous, Bhagat, S. and Black, B. (1998) The relationship
so it is difficult in most cases to draw causal between board composition and firm perfor-
inferences. For this reason, we make no claims mance. In: K. Hopt, H. Kanda, M. Roe,
about the direction of causality between governance E. Wymeersch and S. Prigge (eds) Comparative
and performance. Instead, we analyse whether Corporate Governance – the State of the Art and
governance is a useful variable for explaining Emerging Research. Oxford: Clarendon Press,
cross-sectional variation in performance that is 281–306.
not already incorporated into market prices or Chaganti, R. and Damanpour, F. (1991) Institutional
other firm characteristics” (2001, p. 4). Ownership, Capital Structure and Firm Perfor-
4. This index includes all stocks listed shares. mance, Strategic Management Journal, 12, 479–491.
5. The use of independent ranking of stocks to CMVM (1999) Recommendations on Corporate
create portfolios long in stocks of specific fea- Governance (http://www.CMVM.pt)
tures and short in stocks of opposite features Comment, R. and Schwert, W. (1995) Poison or
(Fama and French, 1993) is not recommendable, Placebo? Evidence on the Deterrence and Wealth
if one refers to a small market like the Por- Effects of Modern Antitakeover Measures, Journal
tuguese, insofar as it is difficult to separate out of Financial Economics, 39, 3–43.
the effects of the several factors which generate Cuervo, A. (2002) Corporate Mechanisms: a Plea for
returns. Less Code of Good Governance and More Market
6. We have used all listed companies, not just the Control, Corporate Governance – an International
respondent companies. Review, 10, 84–93.
7. In each sorting the different stocks were inte- Fama, E. and French, K. (1993) Common Risk
grated in either grouping, depending on the Factors in the Returns on Bonds and Stocks,
stocks registering for the relevant variable a Journal of Financial Economics, 33, 3–56.
value above or below the median. Gompers, P., Ishii, J. and Metrick, A. (2001) Corpo-
8. 12 months prior to the date of the regression for rate Governance and Equity Prices, NBER WP
each share in the first-step. 8449, August.
9. Results of the first-step regressions are not Grossman, S. and Hart, O. (1980) Takeover Bids,
reported. the Free-Rider Problem, and the Theory of the
10. Upon realising this, a finer analysis of our Corporation, Bell Journal of Economics, 11, 42–64.
results allows us to conclude that the real Jegadeesh, N. and Titman, S. (1993) Returns to
problem is the definition of the G’s more than Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications
true heteroskedasticity. In fact, the problem for Stock Market Efficiency, Journal of Finance, 48,
seems to rest on the equal weight attributed to 65–91.
each recommendation within each group. Jensen, M. (1993) The Modern Industrial Revolu-
11. One for each group. tion, Exit, and the Failure of Internal Control
12. Heteroskedasticity was not present in any of Systems, Journal of Finance, 48, 831–880.
the (i), (ii) and (iii) regressions. These results are Jong, A., DeJong, D., Mertens, G. and Waslwey, C.
not reported. On the other hand, the “consis- (2002) The Role of Self-Regulation in Corporate
tency” of these results is a sign that multicolin- Governance: Evidence from The Netherlands,
earity is not a problem, for (i), (ii) and (iii) SSRN Electronic Paper n° 246952.
regressions revealed the same significant Kang, J. and Shivdasani, A. (1995) Firm
recommendations. Performance, Corporate Governance, and Top
13. G3 matches R10 exactly, for R10 is the only Executive Turnover in Japan, Journal of Financial
variable of this group. Economics, 38, 29–58.
14. It would be interesting to check whether this is Keim, D. (1983) Size-Related Anomalies and Stock
a generalised effect or if the market distin- Return Seasonality: Further Empirical Evidence,
guishes between different dividend policies. Journal of Financial Economics, 12, 13–32.
15. Resorting only to bank reception desks, for Liew, J. and Vassalou, M. (2000) Can Book-to-
example. Market, Size and Momentum Be Risk Factors
That Predict Economic Growth?, Journal of Finan-
cial Economics, 57, 221–245.
Porter, M. (1992) Capital Disadvantage: America’s
References Failing Capital Investment System, Harvard Busi-
ness Review, 70, 65–82.
Aguilera, R. and Cuervo-Cazurra, A. (2000) Codes Shleifer, A. and Vishny, R. (1988) Value Maxim-
of Good Governance Worldwide. CIBER Working ization and the Acquisition Process, Journal of
Paper, University of Illinois at Urbana Economic Perspectives, 2, 7–20.
Champaign. Yermack, D. (1997) Good Timing: CEO Stock
Barber, B. and Lyon, J. (1997) Detecting Long-Run Option Awards and Company News Announce-
Abnormal Stock Returns: The Empirical Power ments, Journal of Finance, 52, 449–476.
and Specification of Test Statistics, Journal of Zahra, S. (1996) Governance, Ownership, and Cor-
Financial Economics, 43, 341–372. porate Entrepreneurship: The Moderating
Baysinger, B., Kosnik, R. and Turk, T. (1991) Effects Impact of Industry Technological Opportunities,
of Board and Ownership Structure on Corporate Academy of Management Journal, 39, 1713–1775.

Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004 © Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004


CORPORATE GOVERNANCE POLICY AND COMPANY PERFORMANCE 301

Carlos Alves is teaching at the Faculdade de of Research at the Portuguese Securities


Economia do Porto (Portugal). He was adviser Commission (CMVM). He got his PhD in
of Portuguese Secretary of State for Treasury Economics from the University of South Car-
and Finance, and is a former member of the olina in 1990. He taught at the Faculdade de
Board of Portuguese Securities Commission Economia do Porto (Portugal), where he was
(CMVM). His research areas include corporate Associate Professor, before joining CMVM.
governance and capital markets. His research interests include econometrics,
Victor Mendes is the director of the Division banking and finance.

“It seems that shareholders can’t win. For years the media and others have criticised insti-
tutional investors for not taking an active interest in the companies in which they invest.
Now they are taking such an interest, there is a danger that they will be accused of inter-
fering in matters they do not understand.” Editorial, International Corporate Governance, Issue
124, February 2004, Page 2.

© Blackwell Publishing Ltd 2004 Volume 12 Number 3 July 2004

You might also like