You are on page 1of 10

27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics?

| Aeon Essays

Economics is quantum
Money and brains are both quantum phenomena
– so it's not surprising that economics is overdue
for a quantum revolution
David Orrell

‘I’m not absolutely certain of my facts,’ wrote P G Wodehouse in his story ‘Jeeves and
the Unbidden Guest’ (1925), ‘but I rather fancy it’s Shakespeare … who says that it’s
always just when a fellow is feeling particularly braced with things in general that Fate
sneaks up behind him with the bit of lead piping.’

It certainly seems to be the case in science that, just before a field is completely
disrupted by a major discovery, someone has to make a statement that sums up the
field’s complacency for future historians. For years in the future, people can look at it
and think, they had no idea what was about to hit them (and sometimes the lead pipe
is used more than once).
https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 1/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

In 1894, this task fell to the American physicist Albert Michelson, later Nobel
laureate, when he announced that ‘it seems probable that most of the grand
underlying principles have been firmly established, and that further advances are to
be sought chiefly in the rigorous application of these principles’. A few years later,
those principles were hit by the discovery that, at the subatomic scale at least, nature
moves in sudden quantum leaps and jumps.

A century on, at the 2003 Presidential Address of the American Economic


Association, the job fell to the Nobel laureate, economist Robert E Lucas Jr, who told
<https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/000282803321455133> his
audience: ‘My thesis in this lecture is that macroeconomics in this original sense has
succeeded: its central problem of depression-prevention has been solved, for all
practical purposes, and has in fact been solved for many decades.’ A few years later,
that conclusion was shattered by the discovery that the economy had suddenly leaped
off a cliff.

Lucas’s optimism was not out of place at the time. With its visions of ‘efficient
markets’ and ‘rational expectations’ all firmly grounded in mechanistic equations,
economics was the undisputed queen of the social sciences. But the question now is
whether history will repeat itself in another sense. In physics, the quantum revolution
reshaped the field. Will the financial crash lead to a similar reshaping of economics?
After all, mainstream or neoclassical economics is explicitly based on the classical
mechanics of the 19th century, with people seen as individual atoms, their behaviour
guided by deterministic laws. Surely it is ripe for an update?

Indeed, in recent years there have been many calls for economics to reinvent itself,
most noticeably from student groups such as the Post-Crash Economics Society, and
Rethinking Economics. In 2017, the United Kingdom’s Economic and Social
Research Council announced that it was setting up a network of experts from outside
economics whose task it would be to ‘revolutionise’ the field. And there have been
countless books on the topic, including my own Economyths (2010), which called for
just such an intervention by non-economists.

But progress has been slow. Back in 2008, the French physicist and hedge-fund
manager Jean-Philippe Bouchaud wrote the paper
<https://arxiv.org/abs/0810.5306v1> ‘Economics Needs a Scientific Revolution’ in
the journal Nature. In late 2017, he provided an update to the Financial Times:
‘Following the financial crisis, many of us hoped that the economics profession had
finally realised that their models were not representative of how the real economy
works, and that their flawed methods would quickly change. at assumption was
wrong.’ He concluded that: ‘If we don’t embrace new methods of modelling the
economy, we will be as blind to the next crisis as we were to the last one.’

One problem is that, while there have been many demands for a revolution, the exact
nature of the revolution is less clear. Critics agree that the foundations of economics

https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 2/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

are rotten, but there are different views on what should be built in its place. Most
think that the field needs more diversity and should be more pluralistic, and feel that
the emphasis on economic growth for its own sake needs to be reconciled both with
environmental constraints, and fair distribution. Many, including Bouchaud, argue
that economists need to adopt techniques from other areas such as complexity
theory. ere have been attempts to base the subject more on data than on theory.
And, of course, the idea of rational economic man – which forms the core of
traditional models – should be replaced with something a little more realistic.

But what if the problems with economics run even deeper? What if the traditional
approach has hit a wall, and the field needs to be completely reinvented? What if, as
with 19th-century physics, the problem comes down to ontology – our entire way of
thinking and talking about the economy?

And what if the metaphorical piece of lead piping that mugged both physics and
economics was in each case exactly the same thing – namely, quantum reality?

F or a start: what is economics? If you ask an economist, or look in a textbook, it


turns out that most follow the English economist Lionel Robbins, who wrote in
1932: ‘Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship
between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.’ Or as it is often
paraphrased, economics is the science of scarcity.

And if you ask, what is the point of economics – what is it trying to do? – then the
typical answer is to say that economics is about optimising utility. Or as one book put
it: ‘Economics is about happiness.’

And finally, if you ask how this is accomplished, you learn that prices correspond to
the intersection of supply-and-demand curves, which represent the utility-maximising
behaviour of selfish rational consumers and producers, whose homogeneous
behaviour is typically modelled using a handful of representative agents, perhaps with
various tweaks for ‘bounded rationality’ and so on. e result is a roughly stable and
optimal equilibrium.

But something doesn’t add up about these responses. For one thing, if economics is
about solving scarcity and making people happy by optimising prices, then it appears
to be doing a rather poor job. In many countries, inequality has ballooned in recent
decades, while reported happiness levels seem to have peaked some time back in the
1960s. e financial crisis didn’t make many people happy, except some bankers.

e price theory assumes that there exist fixed and independent curves that describe
supply and demand, but the reality is that these forces are coupled and in flux – and
the idea that they lead to a stable and optimal equilibrium seems more than a little
wobbly.

https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 3/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

The tenets of mainstream economics are made-up, no more


real than Medieval astronomers’ crystalline spheres 

Even stranger, though, is that in answering these basic questions money hardly seems
to be mentioned – despite the fact that one would think money is at the heart of the
subject. (Isn’t economics about money? Aren’t prices set by using money?) If you
look at those textbooks, you will find that, while money is used as a metric, and there
is some discussion of basic monetary plumbing, money is not considered an
important subject in itself. And both money and the role of the financial sector are
usually completely missing from economic models, nor do they get paid lip service.
One reason central banks couldn’t predict the banking crisis was because their
models didn’t include banks.

Economists, it seems, think about money less than most people do: as Mervyn King,
the former governor of the Bank of England, observed in 2001: ‘Most economists
hold conversations in which the word “money” hardly appears at all.’ For example, the
key question of money-creation by private banks, according
<https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1057521915001477> to the
German economist Richard Werner, has been ‘a virtual taboo for the thousands of
researchers of the world’s central banks during the past half century’. And then there
is the mass of complex financial derivatives, whose nominal value was estimated in
2010 at $1.2 quadrillion, but which is nowhere to be found in conventional models,
even though it was at the root of the crisis.

To sum up, the key tenets of mainstream or neoclassical economics – including such
things as ‘utility’ or ‘demand curves’ or ‘rational economic man’ – are just made-up
inventions, no more real than the crystalline spheres that Medieval astronomers
thought suspended the planets. But real things like money are to a remarkable extent
ignored.

In physics, the quantum revolution was born when physicists found that at the
subatomic level energy was always exchanged in terms of discrete parcels, which they
called quanta, from the Latin for ‘how much’. Perhaps we need to follow the quantum
lead, and look at transactions between people. In economics, the equivalent would be
exchanges of money – like when you go into a shop, point at something, and ask:
How much? Or, if you’re in Italy, Quanto?, which makes the connection a little clearer.

O f course, the money objects we use in exchange, such as coins, might not seem
to resemble subatomic objects. But look
<http://et.worldeconomicsassociation.org/papers/a-quantum-theory-of-money-and-
value/> a little <http://et.worldeconomicsassociation.org/papers/a-quantum-theory-
of-money-and-value-part-2-the-uncertainty-principle/> harder
<https://cup.columbia.edu/book/the-evolution-of-money/9780231173728> , and
the fields of economics and quantum physics have much in common.
https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 4/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

e most basic insight of quantum physics was that matter or energy does not move
continuously, but is transmitted in discrete, sudden jumps. Money, of course, is the
same – there isn’t a little needle showing the money draining out of your account
when you make a payment, it just goes in a single step. And as a Bank of England
paper <https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/working-paper/2015/banks-are-not-
intermediaries-of-loanable-funds-and-why-this-matters> noted in 2015, one reason
the money-creation process is hard to accommodate in traditional models is that it
works ‘instantaneously and discontinuously’ (their emphasis) rather like the creation of
quantum particles out of the void.

In quantum physics, attributes such as position or momentum are fundamentally


indeterminate until measured, and according to the uncertainty principle cannot be
known beyond a certain precision. Similarly, money’s use in transactions is a way of
attaching a number (the price) to the fuzzy and indeterminate notion of value, and
therefore acts as a kind of quantum measurement process. When you sell your house,
you don’t know exactly how much it is worth or what it will fetch; the price is revealed
only at the time of transaction.

One of the more mysterious aspects of quantum physics is that particles can become
entangled so that they become a unified system, and a measurement on one affects
the other instantaneously. In economics, the information encoded in money is a kind
of entanglement device, because its creation always has two sides, debt and credit (for
example modern fiat money represents government debt). And its use entangles
people with each other and with the system as a whole, as anyone with a loan will
know. If you go bankrupt, that immediately affects the state of your creditors, even if
they don’t find out straight away.

According to quantum physics, matter is fundamentally dualistic in the sense that it is


composed, not of independent, billiard ball-like atoms, but of entities that behave in
some ways as ‘virtual’ waves, and in other ways as ‘real’ particles. Neither the particle
nor the wave description is complete by itself. is sounds confusing – but the same
can be said of money, which is also real and virtual at the same time. For example, a
coin is made by pressing a stamp into a metal slug. e stamp specifies the numeric
value of the coin, while the metal represents its value as an object that can be owned
or exchanged. It therefore lives partly in the virtual world of numbers and
mathematics, and partly in the physical world of things and people and value, which is
one reason for its perplexing effects on the human psyche.

You don’t need to be an Einstein to know that tapping a


credit card initiates a virtual money transfer

roughout its history, money has alternated between these two sides, presenting
either as a virtual system for accounting (clay cuneiforms in ancient Mesopotamia,
wooden tally sticks in early Medieval England, electronic money today), or as a
https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 5/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

treasured thing (Ancient Greece and Rome, the gold standard), while retaining the
essential characteristics of each. e dichotomy is also reflected in our two main
theories of money: chartalism, which says that money represents a virtual debt to the
state; and bullionism, which says it boils down to metal. Most economists ignore the
debate and treat money as an inert medium of exchange with no special properties of
its own. e situation therefore resembles the old debate about whether light was a
virtual wave (Aristotle) or a real particle (Isaac Newton). Eventually, quantum
physicists came to the conclusion that light isn’t a particle or a wave, it is both at the
same time. Most people didn’t care, and just worried about keeping the lights on, and
so it is with money.

It is something of a cliché to say that the discrete, dualistic, entangled and uncertain
behaviour of quantum matter challenges every aspect of our commonsense
worldview. But it does not seem quite so bizarre or alienating when viewed from an
economic perspective – in fact, we deal with it every time we go shopping or cash a
cheque. e point is not that quantum mechanics can be viewed as a metaphor for
understanding money, but that the economy is a quantum system in its own right,
with its own very real versions of measurement, indeterminacy and entanglement. An
advantage is that these concepts lack the obscure and confusing nature of their
counterparts in physics. You don’t need to be an Albert Einstein or an Erwin
Schrödinger or have a degree in quantum mechanics to know that value is uncertain,
or to understand that tapping your credit card initiates a virtual money transfer.

e quantum nature of money only comes fully into its own, however, when it
interacts with another delicate quantum system – the one that designed it: our brains.

T he most disturbing and weird feature of quantum physics, at least for quantum
physicists, was that it seemed to hold out a role for consciousness. According to
the standard ‘Copenhagen interpretation’, a particle such as an electron is described
by a mathematical wave function, whose amplitude at any point describes the
probability of finding the electron at that location. is wave function ‘collapses’ to a
certain value during the measurement process. No one knows how this collapse
occurs, but a conscious observer is usually assumed to be involved, which seemed to
undercut the idea of physics as a purely objective science. (It tells you something
about science that consciousness – the one thing we all have direct experience of –
can be considered disturbing and weird.) It is perhaps unsurprising then that
consciousness, and the way that we pattern our thoughts, seems to have much in
common with quantum physics.

One of the hottest areas in economics, especially since the crisis, has been
behavioural economics, which was founded in the 1970s by the psychologists Daniel
Kahneman and Amos Tversky. e most basic lesson of behavioural economics seems
to be that making decisions is hard, so we look for shortcuts. And we are easily
influenced when someone – the state, an advertiser, our social group, or even our own
habits – supplies that shortcut. For example, we prefer to stick with what we know
https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 6/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

and we dislike change, which explains why investors often cling on to shares that do
nothing but go downhill. Recency bias means that we put too much weight on new
information – like last year’s investment returns – than older information – such as
historical returns. And in general our decisions are shaped by things such as history
and context.

However, while behavioural economists can model these effects, they can do so only
on a case-by-case basis. And a number of scientists believe that the problem is not so
much that people are being irrational; it is just that they are basing their decisions,
not on classical logic, but on quantum logic. After all, quantum systems, such as us,
are intrinsically uncertain and affected by history and context.

A new kind of economics will point the way to a better,


fairer economy. Or at least one less likely to blow up

One person to make this connection was the Pakistani mathematical physicist Asghar
Qadir, who pointed <https://www.jstor.org/stable/25824883?
seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents> out in 1978 that quantum mechanics seems a better
fit than classical mechanics to modelling the vagaries of economic behaviour. His
paper made few waves, but in the 1990s a number of researchers
<https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-94-015-8816-4_11> working
<https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/quantum-social-
science/156E054488073E842C6A3C598FC8DC87> in social sciences such as
psychology showed how our decision-making at the individual or societal level can be
modelled and even predicted using a quantum formalism. is grew into the field of
quantum cognition and later quantum social science. As the political scientist
Alexander Wendt noted <https://www.cambridge.org/core/books/quantum-mind-
and-social-science/3D5DB273B648D0A23B49C1C4ABA5CF7A> in Quantum Mind
and Social Science (2015), the situation is again similar to physics at the start of the
20th century: ‘In both domains rigorous testing of classical theories had produced a
string of anomalies; efforts to explain them with new classical models were ad hoc and
partial; and then a quantum theory emerged that predicted them all with great
precision.’

At the same time, other researchers were applying the quantum formalism to the area
of quantitative finance, which is used for modelling the behaviour of financial
markets. It turned out that many of the formulas regularly used by ‘quants’ to value
derivatives such as options (the right to buy or sell a security for a set price at a future
date) could be restated as quantum effects. e Black-Scholes equation, for example,
can be expressed
<http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0165176599000956> as a
version of the Schrödinger wave equation from quantum physics. Markets even have
their own version of an uncertainty principle (which will come as no surprise to
investors).
https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 7/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

To date, the focus in quantum finance and quantum cognition has primarily been on
reproducing the results of neoclassical or behavioural economics using the methods
of quantum physics. Combined with quantum money, though, the result I believe
points towards a new kind of economics that will overturn the most basic
assumptions of traditional economics, and point the way to a better, fairer and more
sustainable economy. Or at least one less likely to blow up.

S o how to define this new, quantum-inspired economics? It is not the science of


scarcity, and it certainly isn’t the science of happiness (which is not to say these
things aren’t important); rather, it can be defined as the study of transactions that
involve money. Instead of assuming that market prices represent the intersection of
made-up curves and optimise utility, prices are seen as the emergent result of a
measurement procedure. Rather than modelling the economy as a kind of efficient
machine, it makes more sense to use methods such as complexity theory and network
theory that are suited to the study of living systems, and which as mentioned above
are now being adopted in economics. One tool is agent-based models, where the
economy emerges indirectly from the actions of heterogeneous individuals who are
allowed to interact and influence each other’s behaviour, mirroring in some ways the
collective dance of quantum particles. Agent-based models have managed to
reproduce for example <https://arxiv.org/abs/1709.05117> the characteristic boom-
bust nature of housing or stock markets, or the effect of people’s expectations on
inflation. Meanwhile, network theory can be used to illustrate processes and reveal
vulnerabilities in the complex wirings and entanglements of the financial system.

Because it starts from different assumptions and uses different methods than
mainstream economics, the quantum version also comes to very different conclusions
and predictions. Instead of assuming that market forces drive prices towards a stable
equilibrium, it sees the economy as driven by complex feedback loops, including
those that affect the creation and destruction of money by private banks. One
conclusion is that the risk models currently taught in universities and business
schools, and relied upon by businesses and financial institutions, are not fit for
purpose (as many guessed after the last crisis).

Instead of rational economic man, who makes decisions selfishly to optimise his
personal utility, we have quantum economic person, who is unselfishly entangled with
other quantum economic people. Happiness is therefore not a solo pursuit that
economists can calculate and optimise. And instead of seeing the economy as a
machine devoid of such things as will, volition and personal responsibility – Milton
Friedman, for example, wrote in 1953 that economics is ‘in principle independent of
any particular ethical position or normative judgments … [It] is, or can be, an
“objective” science, in precisely the same sense as any of the physical sciences’ –
quantum economics (if we can call it that) sees the economy as a living system where
ethics plays an important role. One lesson from the crisis was that economists were
heavily implicated in the financial system that they were responsible for regulating,

https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 8/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

for example through highly paid consulting gigs; as in quantum physics, the observer
is never separate from the system.

And while neoclassical economics treats ‘market failures’ such as economic inequality
and environmental degradation as aberrations or externalities, from a quantum
perspective they appear more to reflect the conflict inherent in money between
numeric price and real value, as manifested in a debt-based financial system that
prioritises growth above all else. e theory therefore builds on the findings of
thinkers such as the English chemist Frederick Soddy (who switched to economics
after being awarded a Nobel Prize in 1921 for his work on the basic properties of
radiation), the American ecological economist Herman Daly, and many others, who
have made similar statements.

A theory is likely to be accepted if it tells a story that


benefits a powerful constituency

In fact, many aspects of this quantum economics can be found in so-called ‘heterodox
economics’ – ie, theories that don’t fit with the mainstream. And the problems were
summed up as long ago as 1926, when John Maynard Keynes – perhaps inspired by
the quantum revolution that was then in full swing, or perhaps mindful of that piece
of lead piping left on the ground – wrote that: ‘We are faced at every turn with the
problems of Organic Unity, of Discreteness, of Discontinuity – the whole is not equal
to the sum of the parts, comparisons of quantity fail us, small changes produce large
effects, the assumptions of a uniform and homogeneous continuum are not satisfied.’
Conventional mechanistic models can no more incorporate such effects than pre-
quantum models of the atom could incorporate quantum effects. Unfortunately,
mainstream economists failed to recognise or act on this, but instead remained
wedded to their classical approach.

So will the heterodox become the new orthodoxy, and economics go quantum? It
would be nice to say that the answer will depend on some impartial test, like the
ability to make accurate predictions, but of course this is far from being the case;
neoclassical economics has remained in place for a century and a half without much
of a predictive track record to boast of (the main achievement of the efficient-market
hypothesis was to provide an excuse). Instead, a theory is likely to be accepted if it
tells a story that benefits a powerful constituency.

e mainstream mantra that the economy is stable, rational and efficient was perfect
PR for the financial sector, so quantum economics can’t compete with that. Its natural
constituency is instead similar to that which fuelled the anti-nuclear protests: people
– including scientists and non-economists – who have lived through the recent
financial crisis, and who want to prevent it from happening again.

https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 9/10
27/02/2018 Has the time come for a quantum revolution in economics? | Aeon Essays

Economics, which models itself after 19th-century physics, is clearly due for an
update.

But here ‘revolution’ doesn’t seem to be quite the right word, because the revolution
already happened a century ago. What we need is a recognition. As Marshall McLuhan
wrote in Laws of Media: e New Science (1992): ‘I do not think that philosophers in
general have yet come to terms with this declaration from quantum physics: the days
of the Universe as Mechanism are over.’ Nowhere is that more true than in economics.

David Orrell is a writer and mathematician. His research on complex systems has been
featured in the Financial Times, BBC radio and New Scientist, and his writing on science
and economics has been published in World Finance, Bitcoin Magazine and e New
Economy, among others. His latest book is e Money Formula: Dodgy Finance, Pseudo-
Science, and How Mathematicians Took Over the Markets
<http://eu.wiley.com/WileyCDA/WileyTitle/productCd-1119358612.html> (2017), co-
written with Paul Wilmott. He lives in Toronto.

aeon.co 04 January, 2018

https://aeon.co/essays/has-the-time-come-for-a-quantum-revolution-in-economics 10/10

You might also like