You are on page 1of 12

Policy Analysis

April 10, 2018 | Number 837

Candy-Coated Cartel
Time to Kill the U.S. Sugar Program
By Colin Grabow

EX EC U T I V E S UMMARY

For decades, the federal government has been operat- both to U.S. consumers and to businesses that use sugar
ing a program to control the production and importation as an ingredient in their products. U.S. sugar policy also
of sugar. One of the program’s main purposes is to ensure justifiably furthers suspicions among the citizenry that the
minimum price levels for sugar that are typically signifi- federal government is more concerned with advancing the
cantly higher than those found on international markets, narrow interests of well-connected groups such as sugar
leading to higher costs for U.S. consumers. As a result, producers than promoting the country’s general welfare.
the federal government is, in essence, the leader of a The paper concludes by scrutinizing the rationalizations
nationwide sugar cartel. typically offered for the sugar program’s existence, which
This paper examines how this situation came to be, are largely found wanting. Claims that the program’s
providing an overview of the sugar program’s history and demise would result in catastrophic consequences for
its essential elements. As will be shown, the program’s the industry are similarly found to be overstated at best.
overriding goals are the provision of a minimum income Recently introduced legislation, meanwhile, would likely
to sugar producers and a higher price for the product curb some of the program’s worst excesses. Although
than would otherwise be the case through the use of it falls short of ideal by failing to abolish the program
various measures that restrict supply. This clear gain to wholesale, this legislation is perhaps the best option for
producers, however, comes at a notable economic cost reform in recent memory.

Colin Grabow is a policy analyst at the Cato Institute’s Herbert A. Stiefel Center for Trade Policy Studies.
2


INTRODUCTION back to the 1934 passage of the Jones-Costigan
The U.S. Those familiar with the intricacies of the Amendment.1 This legislation, passed as an
sugar program federal government’s sugar program could be emergency measure to provide assistance to
forgiven for wondering whether they have sugar farmers and later incorporated into the
is a prime been led astray by their history books and Sugar Act of 1937, had as its key provisions
example of it was actually the Soviet Union’s ideology domestic production quotas, subsidies, tar-
discredited that prevailed in the Cold War. Replete with iffs, and import quotas, all designed to restrict
economic measures designed to achieve certain price sugar supplies and boost prices.
targets—including decisions about how much As noted by the Yale Law Journal in 1938,
central sugar producers in the United States and the result of this market meddling was to
planning in abroad can supply to the market in a given harm consumers, while failing to serve as


action. year—the U.S. sugar program is a prime exam- the industry savior the legislation’s backers
ple of discredited economic central planning imagined it to be:
in action. Despite the popularized image of
the United States as a bastion of capitalism Protection of the domestic beet and
and free trade, the unfortunate reality is that cane producers costs the American
the price of sugar and the sources of its pro- consumer three hundred million dollars
duction are determined in this country as a year even after the duties collected by
much by bureaucrats and politicians as by con- the Treasury have been discounted. No
sumers and producers. attempt is made in the present scheme
A bipartisan group of lawmakers recently of regulation to encourage production
decided that enough is enough and has intro- in those fields which can produce sugar
duced legislation that would significantly limit most economically and to discourage
the program’s size and scope. Combined with it in the fields which require subsidiza-
the arrival of a president with debatable reform- tion. Thus, despite the inefficiency and
ist credentials, who nonetheless has loudly and expensiveness of the beet sugar industry
profusely promised to “drain the swamp,” this and the well nigh intolerable working
effort to pare down the sugar program is per- conditions in the beet fields, the latter
haps the best prospect for genuine reform in area is the only one not really restricted
recent memory. by the quotas which have been imposed.
But first, it’s worth examining how this The most efficient producing areas
situation was created in the first place. How have received the most drastic restrictions.
is this seemingly bizarre system justified, and A proration system has been devised
what problems was it meant to solve? What which prohibits the State of Florida, the
is its impact on consumers and sugar-using only area on the continent which could
industries? And can we do better? Answering produce sugar profitably without a tariff
these and other related questions will be the or direct subsidy, from producing more
focus of this policy analysis. than fifty percent of its own intrastate
consumption. Moreover, the federal gov-
ernment has assisted in increasing the
AN OVERVIEW OF U.S. supply of sugar by spending enormous
SUGAR POLICY sums on research, irrigation, and recla-
Barriers to imports of sugar have been mation during a period when production
employed nearly since the republic’s founding; was already far outstripping consump-
a tariff on the product was first passed in 1789. tion. As a consequence of these mea-
Duties remained in place almost continuously sures, legislation ostensibly enacted for
save for a four-year period from 1890 to 1894, but the relief of domestic farmers results in a
modern-day sugar protectionism can be traced net loss to them.2
3


Despite such documented costs even at this Among the portion reserved for cane sug-
early date, the system persisted with only minor ar, Florida, Louisiana, and Texas are assigned The federal
adjustments through 1974, when a tripling in the allotments based on the production histories government,
price of sugar coincided with the expiration of of both the collective state and individual pro-
the Sugar Act of 1948, and Congress decided cessors. (Hawaii had been allotted 325,000
the country’s
against renewal. A decline in sugar prices then short tons, but its last remaining sugar mill lead enforcer
led to the temporary creation of price sup- produced its final harvest in late 2016.5) Beet in halting anti-
port loans, that is, government loans secured sugar, which is grown in 11 different states,
competitive
by sugar as collateral, which the borrower can has allotments assigned to processors based
either repay with interest or, if prices are too on their sugar production histories.6 Should actions,
low, default on. These were enacted for the sugar new processors enter the market or factories simultaneously
crops of 1977–1979 and lapsed in 1980 and most be sold between processors, allocation condi- finds itself in
of 1981 in the wake of a dramatic sugar price tions would be addressed through regulations
increase. A sugar support program reappeared in the 2014 Farm Bill.
the position
in the 1981 Farm Bill following a price retreat.3 of cartel


Also serving to maintain elevated price levels
Officially known as the Agriculture and and avoid loan forfeitures is the Feedstock Flex- ringleader.
Food Act of 1981, the Farm Bill featured the ibility Program, an arrangement introduced in
reintroduction of price support loans that the 2008 Farm Bill by which the USDA is given
continue today and form one of the U.S. sugar the option of making purchases in order to
program’s four key pillars. Extended through remove sugar from the market and sell it to bio-
the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s (USDA) energy companies for fuel production. That is,
Commodity Credit Corporation, these loans the USDA plays the role of both buyer and seller
are made to sugar processors at an average of sugar in order to ensure the supply available
national rate of 18.75 cents for every pound of for human consumption is reduced, thus driving
raw sugarcane provided as collateral (rates vary prices higher than they would be otherwise and
slightly by region of the country) and 24.09 reducing the possibility of loan defaults.
cents per pound of refined beet sugar.4 These The last, and arguably most important, part
rates effectively serve as a price target for the of the sugar puzzle is tariff rate quotas (TRQs),
USDA. Because processors will simply forfeit without which imports would drive down U.S.
their sugar collateral if the market price dips sugar prices and undermine the policy goal
below that set by the loans, the USDA must of a sugar price sufficient to discourage loan
ensure that supply is sufficiently restricted— forfeitures. Under this approach, a limited
thus boosting prices—so that sugar used as col- amount of raw and refined sugar, currently set
lateral will be sold instead of surrendered. The at a minimum of 1.231 million tons due to a U.S.
nonrecourse nature of the loans, by which lia- commitment to the World Trade Organization,
bility for the loans does not extend beyond the is allowed to be imported duty free through
provided collateral, also encourages this. preference programs, or at the rate of 0.625
Assisting in this effort is the sugar program’s cents per pound.7 Any sugar imported beyond
second element, marketing allotments. In this the quota amount, meanwhile, is subject to
arrangement, the USDA annually determines an a tariff of 15.36 cents per pound for raw cane
overall allotment quantity (OAQ)—effectively sugar and 16.21 cents per pound for refined
a limit on how much sugar can be sold—which sugar. To put this in context, the world price
is designed both to avoid loan forfeitures of refined sugar in 2017 generally fluctuated
and reserve 85 percent of the sugar market to between 17 cents and 25 cents per pound.
domestic producers as mandated by law. This Further complicating matters, the TRQ for
OAQ, in turn, is further divided up, with refined raw cane sugar is divided among 40 countries
beet sugar receiving 54.35 percent of the overall by the Office of the U.S. Trade Representative,
quantity and raw cane sugar 45.65 percent. with quantities assigned based on the period
4


1975–1981, during which trade was relatively with the government’s help) to constrain
Predictably, unrestricted. The refined sugar TRQ, mean- the supply of a good, thus increasing the
this approach while, is currently allocated to Canada and good’s market price, this would also be a
Mexico, with an additional quantity available to violation of the Sherman Act.10
has resulted all countries on a first-come, first-served basis.
in a steady With government planners forced to juggle We have, in effect, the absurd situation in
stream all of these considerations, as well as a directive which the federal government, the country’s
of candy that the USDA provide adequate supplies of lead enforcer in halting anti-competitive actions,
raw and refined sugar in the domestic market, simultaneously finds itself in the position
manufacturers it is no surprise that their efforts are subject to of cartel ringleader. This approach is the very
shifting periodic revision. In July 2017, for example, the opposite of the advice given by Adam Smith,
production USDA announced an increase in the OAQ for who warned that conversations among people
domestic sugar; the reassignment of beet sugar of the same trade typically end “in a conspiracy
to take marketing allotments among processors; the against the public, or in some contrivance to
advantage reassignment of unused cane sugar marketing raise prices,” and advised that “though the law
of cheaper allotments to imports; and an increase in the cannot hinder people of the same trade from
raw sugar TRQ by 269,724 tons.8
sugar prices sometimes assembling together, it ought to do
The end result of these market manipula- nothing to facilitate such assemblies, much less
outside the


tions is domestic sugar prices that are typically to render them necessary.”
country. twice those of the world sugar market. This,
in the eyes of many legislators in Congress, is
what passes for a policy success. SUGAR AND ECONOMIC DECAY
Yet, it is an approach that would surely draw While the U.S. sugar industry no doubt
deserved howls of protest from elected officials toasts to the high domestic sugar prices that
were the scheme operated without the govern- result from government manipulations of the
ment playing the role of puppet master. Indeed, market, too often overlooked are the many
at this moment voices on the left such as the costs of the current approach. The most
Nation, the New Republic, and Washington Monthly straightforward of these is the higher prices
are expressing increasing worry over alleged borne by retail consumers of sugar, as well as
signs of monopoly within the U.S. economy intermediate users, ranging from bakers to
and calling for more aggressive enforcement of confectioners to soft-drink makers.
anti-trust measures.9 Barely remarked upon, Predictably, this approach has resulted in a
however, is the fact that Washington is operating steady stream of candy manufacturers shifting
a sugar cartel in our midst. As Karl T. Muth and production to take advantage of cheaper sugar
Katheryn DeVelvis argue: prices outside the country. In 2002, Kraft
Foods announced the closure of its Life Savers
If the activities financially encouraged plant in Holland, Michigan, and its relocation
under the American sugar program were to Canada. Sugar may not have been the only
instead done by a group of producers of motive behind the move, but the $90 million
some other good, this would almost cer- the company said it would save over 15 years as
tainly be illegal. For instance, if producers a direct result of lower sugar prices no doubt
of cars or carrots mandated a certain price figured prominently in the decision.11 In 2003,
be charged by downstream distributors, Spangler Candy moved half of its production to
this would be a violation of the Sherman Mexico, citing cheaper sugar, which accounts
Act, the most comprehensive and oft-used for 70 percent of its ingredient costs,12 and Los
antitrust mechanism in federal law. Addi- Angeles–based candy maker Adams & Brooks
tionally, if producers with substantial mar- also shifted about two-thirds of its produc-
ket power colluded (as sugar producers do, tion to Mexico. “It’s really not that much of a
5


choice,” says company president John Brooks. and the subsidized production of corn.18
“You move or you go out of business.13 That Coca-Cola is produced with sugar The dollar
A 2002 Wall Street Journal article examining instead of HFCS elsewhere in the world cost to both
the shift of candy production to Mexico noted (cane sugar in Australia and Mexico and beet
that while lower labor costs were a consider- sugar in Europe) points to the likelihood that
businesses and
ation, the decisive factor was a desire to escape the uniquely high cost of sugar in the United consumers
high U.S. sugar costs: States was the culprit behind the move. Thus from
it has come about that consumers living in the
artificially
An even bigger reason [than labor costs] country where Coca-Cola was invented drink
for the flight of the lollipop and sourball an adulterated version of the beverage, while inflated
makers is the U.S. price of sugar. Candy consumers abroad are able to enjoy it closer sugar prices
manufacturers operating in Mexico to the way it was originally conceived. This likely reaches
and Canada pay world rates for raw has brought about the phenomenon of rising
into the


sugar—about half the federally supported imports to the United States of Coca-Cola
U.S. cost—and can easily undercut U.S. botted in Mexico—perhaps akin to Mexicans billions.
competition. “I just got tired of paying drinking imported American tequila.19
welfare to Big Sugar,” explains Greg Although the added difficulty of procuring
McCormack, president of Bob’s Candies a Coca-Cola with genuine sugar in the United
Inc., of Albany, Ga., which recently States merely rankles, the dollar cost to both
opened a plant in Reynosa.14 businesses and consumers from artificially
inflated sugar prices likely reaches into the
The evidence goes beyond anecdotes. billions. According to the U.S. International
A Wall Street Journal analysis of U.S. Census Trade Commission, the removal of import
Bureau data found that total U.S. confection- restrictions would produce average annual
ary manufacturing employment declined by welfare gains of $342.7 million,20 while
22 percent from 1998 through 2011,15 while a economist Michael K. Wohlgenant of North
2006 Commerce Department study concluded Carolina State University has calculated
that “for each sugar growing and harvesting that the artificially high cost of U.S. sugar
job saved through high U.S. sugar prices, nearly imposes an average burden on consumers of
three confectionery manufacturing jobs are $2.4 billion per year—a benefit to producers of
lost”; every sugar job saved was at a cost of $1.4 billion per year—with a resulting net cost
$826,000.16 A 33 percent rise in the amount of $1 billion.21 A 2017 paper by John Beghin of
of sugar contained in imported products from North Carolina State University and Amani
2002 to 2012 is also suggestive of an overseas Elobeid of Iowa State University found the
production shift by sugar-using companies. cost to consumers to be even higher, placing
Other sugar-using firms that have remained the burden on households at $3.4 billion to
in the United States have opted to change $4 billion. In addition, it also concluded that
their business practices or alter their products the sugar program results in the annual loss of
because of high domestic sugar prices. In 1984, 17,000 to 20,000 jobs in the food industries.22
for example, both the Coca-Cola Company Arguably more offensive than the direct
and PepsiCo announced plans to massively burden imposed by the sugar program is the
increase the amounts of high fructose corn syr- crony capitalist nature of the arrangement. The
up (HFCS) in their soft drinks in order to cut U.S. sugar program’s function as a net wealth
their sugar usage.17 The Cola-Cola Company transfer from consumers to the sugar indus-
notes that among HFCS’s advantages is that try is not really in dispute. Indeed, the title of
it has “historically cost substantially less than a June 2000 report issued by the Government
cane or beet sugar” in the United States—a fac- Accountability Office summed up the situa-
tor explained by restrictions on sugar imports tion: “Sugar Program: Supporting Sugar Prices
6


Has Increased Users’ Costs While Benefiting with Australia over the free trade agreement
How can the Producers.”23 That it persists is a tribute to the eventually reached with that country in 2004,
United States phenomenon of concentrated benefits and for example, the U.S. government’s refusal to
diffuse costs, whereby a relatively small group cede ground on sugar prompted Australia to
bemoan of industry members reaps billions in extra maintain protectionist policies on goods such
closed foreign revenue and the costs are dispersed among tens as wheat and on broadcasting and audio-visual
agriculture of millions of consumers. It is therefore no sur- services.24 This is an example of bad policy
markets when prise that the sugar industry is heavily invested begetting further bad policy, to the detriment
in the program’s continuation, while average of American and foreign consumers alike.
it engages consumers, whose individual financial stakes
in such are comparatively slight, have little incentive to
protectionism advocate for its demise. Indeed, they may even SUGAR PROGRAM
be unaware of its existence. RATIONALIZATIONS
in the same


Ignorance about the sugar program, however, All of this raises the question of why such
sector? does not mean that voters are blind to the exis- a costly and counterproductive program is
tence of forces in Washington that seek to pro- kept in place. While numerous factors help
mote the narrow interests of powerful groups explain its continued existence, one of the
over the general welfare. That many policies foremost justifications proffered is an alleged
advanced by Congress are primarily aimed at need for price stability to avoid the boom-
accommodating the clients of well-connected and-bust cycle of past years. Certainly such
lobbyists, such as those who work for the sugar thinking figured prominently in the minds
industry, may help explain the current appe- of legislators and sugar farmers alike in the
tite for populism and the oft-heard refrain of early 1980s when price supports were rein-
“Drain the swamp!” during the 2016 election troduced in the 1981 Farm Bill. As the Con-
campaign. The continued existence of such gressional Research Service notes, a report
arrangements—despite their well-documented from the Senate Committee on Agriculture,
costs—helps advance the notion of a broken Nutrition, and Forestry about the legislation
system, raising the appeal of political forces that “cited the importance of sugar imports to U.S.
promise more radical solutions. sugar supplies, pointing out that volatile world
Beyond stoking voter ire and furthering a market prices of sugar contributed to sharp
perception that the U.S. government caters to fluctuations in U.S. sugar prices.”25
the whims of narrow interest groups, the sugar Similar arguments were advanced out-
program also comes at considerable cost to side of Capitol Hill. A May 1981 letter to
U.S. moral authority on trade policy. As much the editor published by the New York Times
as U.S. officials, including President Donald from the president of the Rocky Mountain
Trump, seek to portray the United States as Farmers Union, for example, argued that
a free trade exemplar beset by trading part- “[sugar] producers and consumers have been
ners engaged in practices that are supposedly victimized by the wild price swings of the
neither fair nor reciprocal, the existence so-called free market” since the end of price
of arrangements such as the sugar program supports in 1974, and it hailed the 1981 Farm
expose this rhetoric as at best overwrought. Bill for “seeking to free domestic producers
How can the United States bemoan closed and consumers from booms and busts.”26 The
foreign agriculture markets when it engages in same newspaper published a letter to the edi-
such protectionism in the same sector? tor from the vice president of the Hawaiian
In addition to the loss of moral authority, Sugar Planters Association the following year
U.S. insistence on preserving the sugar status that deemed any higher prices resulting from
quo has also served to undermine its leverage the federal sugar program to be a “very small
at the negotiating table. During negotiations price to pay for the increased stability and
7


Figure 1
World refined sugar price vs. U.S. wholesale refined beet sugar price It’s not
apparent,
World U.S. since its
60 reintroduction
in the early
50 1980s, that
the sugar
Cents per pound

40
program has
done much
30
to eliminate
20
volatility in
U.S. sugar


10 prices.

0
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
Source: U.S. Department of Agriculture.

assurance of continued reasonable prices pro- to eliminate such volatility in U.S. sugar prices,
vided by maintaining the domestic production which appears to largely mirror the fluctuations
of more than half of our sugar needs.”27 of the world sugar market. It has, however, fat-
More than 30 years later this line of argu- tened profit margins for sugar farmers and
ment is still being used. The American Sugar producers through the boosting of domestic
Alliance, a special interest representing the var- sugar prices. Indeed, from 1982 through 2016,
ious groups that compose the domestic-sugar the average U.S. sugar price was 29.28 cents per
supply chain, claims the federal government’s pound, nearly double that of the average world
sugar policy is “based on the common-sense price of 15.12 cents (Figure 1).
notion that supply and demand should be When confronted with the sharp dispar-
in balance. . . . By avoiding oversupplies and ity between U.S. and global sugar prices and
shortages, sugar prices stay stable.”28 the ensuing high costs imposed on American
While there is little doubt that price consumers, the sugar industry often responds
smoothing and reduced uncertainty are benefi- that it is willing to move away from govern-
cial to sugar farmers and processors, it is much ment supports provided that other countries
less clear why its pursuit is in the public inter- do the same. This stance, known as “zero for
est, or why government resources should be zero,” is reflected in industry support for a bill
committed to such a goal. Price instability, it introduced by Rep. Ted Yoho (R-Florida) in
should be noted, is hardly unique to the sugar 2017. Calling for the elimination of all direct
industry, with unpredictable prices the norm and indirect sugar subsidies by countries that
for any number of commodities. It’s also not have exported at least 200,000 tons of sugar in
apparent, since its reintroduction in the early 2014, 2015, or 2016, as well as those with whom
1980s, that the sugar program has done much the United States has a free trade agreement,
8


Yoho’s bill states that these twin objectives most vital pillar—would see “employment
There is must first be met before “legislation to imple- in the sugarcane farming and cane sugar
considerable ment United States sugar policy reforms” is manufacturing sectors . . . decrease by 12.4
submitted to Congress by the president.29 and 10.7 percent respectively.” Although
cause for This constitutes an extreme and unrealistic significant, such an amount hardly counts
skepticism bar, considering that such criteria apply to at as catastrophic. Regarding the beet sugar
regarding least 30 countries and the issue of what consti- industry, meanwhile, the USITC finds that
tutes an indirect subsidy is often in dispute.30
claims that “employment in the sugar beet farming and
This suggests that the industry’s true interest beet sugar manufacturing sectors would
unilateral may lie more in preserving the status quo than increase,” with growth seen as “about the
dismantlement in serious movement toward a free market. same as the growth rates projected without
of the U.S. The U.S. sugar industry justifies this stance the removal of these import restraints.”33
by warning that “unilaterally disarming”— A 2015 Cato Institute policy analysis also
sugar program industry-speak for the elimination of sugar suggests that an end to such restrictions would
would prove supports without regard to the actions of have less than devastating consequences for
devastating to other countries—would result in the United the sugar industry, arguing that “most U.S.
the domestic States “becoming dependent on subsidized growers of sugarcane and sugar beets would
foreign suppliers.”31 As support for this claim, remain in that business.”34 As support for
sugar


the American Sugar Alliance reaches back to this position, author Daniel Pearson cites the
industry. World War II, citing domestic sugar ration- example of Canada, which features neither
ing at the time as evidence that “depending on sugar import restrictions nor domestic sup-
other countries for a food staple was a recipe port measures (helping to explain why it has
for disaster.” (Never mind the fact that a U.S. been a destination for candy producers that
sugar program had existed for years prior to have located away from the United States).
U.S. involvement in the war.) According to the Canadian Sugar Institute, the
Sugar-industry favorite Sen. Marco Rubio country produces approximately 1.2 million
(R-Florida) meanwhile warned in 2015 that tons of refined sugar annually, of which roughly
if the United States scrapped its support 6 percent—or 72,000 tons—is supplied domes-
programs for sugar, absent corresponding tically.35 As Pearson says, “Those who argue
moves from other countries, “Brazil will wipe that the U.S. industry would be destroyed by
out our agriculture and it’s not just sugar.” liberalization have yet to explain how sugar
Expanding on this line of thinking, Rubio can be produced successfully in the open and
imaginatively added that “these other coun- competitive Canadian market.”36
tries will capture the market share, our agri- Indeed, that the sugar industry is found
cultural capacity will be developed into real in countries where such elaborate price sup-
estate, you know, housing and so forth, and port mechanisms do not exist also calls into
then we lose the capacity to produce our own question the wisdom behind the unilateral
food, at which point we’re at the mercy of a disarmament argument, as well as claims
foreign country for food security.”32 regarding price volatility. Australia, for exam-
Leaving aside the validity of such specu- ple, provides no government subsidies and
lative national security arguments, there is began operating at world market prices after
considerable cause for skepticism regarding the Australian government removed import
claims that unilateral dismantlement of the restrictions in 1988 and tariff protections in
U.S. sugar program would prove devastating 1997. While it should be noted that Canada,
to the domestic sugar industry. According to with its free market approach, is a minor
a 2017 study from the U.S. International Trade player in the sugar industry, the same cannot
Commission (USITC), the removal of import be said of Australia, which is the world’s third-
restrictions—arguably the sugar program’s largest sugar exporter.
9


Beyond the fact that other countries have cost basis to the federal government. Should
demonstrated an ability to maintain a sugar the Agriculture Secretary determine that this The existence
industry absent the same level of support provision has been violated, the legislation of destructive
granted farmers and producers in the United authorizes the USDA to collect payments
States, it is also unclear why policy choices in from sugar processors to restore the program
policies
foreign lands that fly in the face of economic to balance. elsewhere
logic necessitate the implementation of simi- Beyond this mandate, two other significant is no
lar policies in this country. The existence of provisions in the bill are the termination of
justification
destructive policies elsewhere is no justifica- the feedstock flexibility program and the
tion for mimicking them here. scrapping of marketing allotments. Slated to for mimicking
One other oft-heard claim from sugar take effect beginning in the 2020 crop year, them


program supporters is that current policy the feedstock flexibility program’s demise here.
comes at no cost to the U.S. taxpayer, which is would halt USDA purchases of sugar. As to
misleading at best and perhaps more accurately marketing allotments, they are an absurd
characterized as simply false. This argument exercise in central planning by which the fed-
rests on the fact that high domestic sugar eral government determines how much sugar
prices help ensure that government loans to processors can sell each year. The repeal of
sugar farmers are repaid. Ultimately, this is these programs is both welcome and overdue.
a distinction without a difference, merely Lastly, the legislation would introduce
resulting in Americans paying for the program added flexibility into the tariff rate quota
circuitously through their purchases of sugar (TRQ) program, allowing countries that have
and products containing sugar at artificially been assigned a share of the overall quota to
inflated prices, instead of more directly through temporarily transfer all or part of their share
taxation. Furthermore, even the narrowest to any other country that has been allocated
interpretation of this claim is wrong. In 2013, a quota. Currently, the maximization of the
the USDA was forced to spend tens of millions TRQ for sugar is ensured by the U.S. Trade
of dollars to prop up sugar prices to avoid loan Representative’s office, which reallocates
forfeitures—a development that provided fod- unused capacity. More significantly, the bill
der for late-night comedians—and there’s also mandates an adjustment to the TRQs so that
the small matter that this argument ignores the stocks-to-use ratio—the quantity of sugar
the salaries of those employed by the USDA to available at the end of the marketing year
oversee this program. (September 30) expressed as a percentage
Regrettably, such arguments—along with a of annual usage—would increase from its
fierce lobbying effort by sugar interests—have current level of 13.5 percent to 15.5 percent
thus far carried the day. There is, however, by fiscal year 2021. This should translate into
some hope that this may be about to change. increased imports and lower sugar prices for
U.S. consumers.
The legislation does fall short of ideal, how-
REFORM EFFORT AFOOT ever, by leaving much of the sugar program
Some lawmakers have begun to take notice in place. Price support loans, for example,
of the sugar program’s myriad costs, and legis- are made slightly less generous (a pound of
lation has been introduced in both the House sugarcane provided as collateral would garner
and Senate that would produce significant only 18 cents in loans instead of the current
reforms. Known as the Sugar Modernization 18.75) but still left intact. Likewise, TRQs are
Act of 2017, the House version of this pro- made less onerous instead of abolished. The
posed law rests on four key provisions.37 The decision to loosen rather than eliminate such
first of these is the introduction of a mandate quotas is particularly unfortunate because
that the sugar program operate on a zero net quotas are one of the most damaging aspects
10


of the sugar program, serving to raise domes- and politicians. While not ideal, it is a very
For years, the tic prices far above those found on the global real opportunity to pare down a particular-
U.S. sugar sugar market. ly insidious symbol of narrow self-interest
Such complaints aside, the bill represents triumphing over the common good.
program has a significant step forward on sugar policy,
existed as one which would make possible an expanded role
of the most for market forces and serve to lower prices. NOTES
blatant and Indeed, the legislation’s ability to bring needed 1. Andrew Schmitz and Douglas Christian, “The
reform is perhaps best evidenced by the furi- Economics and Politics of U.S. Sugar Policy,” in
grotesque ous reaction of the U.S. sugar lobby, which has The Economics and Politics of World Sugar Policies,
examples labeled it a “Sugar Farmer Bankruptcy Bill.”38 ed. Stephen V. Marks and Keith E. Maskus
of crony Such overwrought rhetoric is properly viewed (Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press,


as both a testament to the bill’s virtues and a 1993), p. 50.
capitalism. tacit admission that American consumers have
been overpaying for the sugar they consume. 2. “The Sugar Act of 1937,” Yale Law Journal 47,
no. 6 (April 1938): 988–89, https://www.jstor.org/
stable/pdf/792093.pdf.
CONCLUSION
For years, the U.S. sugar program has 3. Schmitz and Christian, “The Economics and
existed as one of the most blatant and Politics of U.S. Sugar Policy,” 51.
grotesque examples of crony capitalism, and
one that is securely entrenched in the federal 4. “Policy,” United States Department of Agricul-
bureaucracy. Best understood as an involuntary ture, https://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/crops/sugar-
wealth transfer from consumers to producers, sweeteners/policy.aspx#price.
the sugar program’s economic cost reaches
into the billions of dollars. Other downsides, 5. “Policy,” United States Department of Agri-
such as lost market-opening opportunities culture, https://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/crops/
during free trade negotiations, are more diffi- sugar-sweeteners/policy.aspx#marketing; and
cult to calculate but surely nontrivial. Lawrence Downes, “The Sun Finally Sets on
Justifications offered by supporters of Sugar Cane in Hawaii,” New York Times, January
the sugar program, such as the alleged need 16, 2017.
for predictable prices or the argument that
economically destructive sugar policies are 6. “Frequently Asked Questions,” Sugar Industry
required to offset similarly damaging policies Biotech Council, http://www.sugarindustrybio
in other countries, are less than compelling. techcouncil.org/sugar-beet-faq.
The claim that the sugar program comes at
no cost to taxpayers, meanwhile, is insulting. 7. The United States also allows small additional
That the program continues to exist is a trib- amounts of sugar to be imported from nine countries
ute to the familiar story of concentrated ben- covered by four free trade agreements. Preference
efits and diffuse costs, abetted by the rational programs that allow sugar to be imported duty free,
ignorance of voters. meanwhile, include free trade agreements as well as
As none other than the New York Times the Generalized System of Preferences.
argued in 1982, a sane sugar policy by the
United States would be no sugar program at 8. “USDA Announces Adjustments to Fiscal Year
all.39 Sadly, that’s not currently on offer. What 2017 Sugar Program,” United States Department
is available, however, is legislation that takes a of Agriculture, July 24, 2017, https://www.fas.usda.
notable step toward a sugar policy oriented to gov/newsroom/usda-announces-adjustments-
consumers and markets rather than lobbyists fiscal-year-2017-sugar-program.
11

9. Joseph E. Stiglitz, “America Has a Monopoly Problem—and Benefits of the US Sugar Program,” American Enterprise
It’s Huge,” Nation, October 23, 2017; Matt Stoller, “The Return of Institute, November 2011, p. 2, http://www.aei.org/wp-content/
Monopoly,” New Republic, July 13, 2017; and Barry C. Lynn, “Dem- uploads/2011/11/-sweets-for-the-sweet-the-costly-benefits-
ocrats Must Become the Party of Freedom,” Washington Monthly, of-the-us-sugar-program_153001980761.pdf.
January/February 2017.
22. John Beghin and Amani Elobeid, “Analysis of the US Sugar
10. Karl T. Muth and Katheryn DeVelvis, “Sweet Nothings: Program,” American Enterprise Institute, November 2017, p. 1,
The History, Law, and Economics of American Sugar Subsidies,” http://www.aei.org/wp-content/uploads/2017/11/Analysis-of-the-
Kennedy School Review, March 18, 2016, http://ksr.hkspublications. US-Sugar-Program.pdf.
org/2016/03/18/sweet-nothings-the-history-law-and-economics-
of-american-sugar-subsidies/. 23. “Sugar Program: Supporting Sugar Prices Has Increased
Users’ Costs While Benefiting Producers,” United States
11. Dean Reynolds, “Costly Sugar Pushes Candy Plant to Cana- General Accounting Office, June 2000, https://www.gao.gov/
da,” ABC News, http://abcnews.go.com/Business/story?id=87274. assets/230/229176.pdf.

12. Oliver Nieburg, “No Country for Hard Candy: Production Stays 24. Aaron Lukas, “A Sticky State of Affairs: Sugar and the
in Mexico until US Adopts ‘Level Playing Field’ Sugar Regime, Says U.S.–Australia Free Trade Agreement,” Cato Institute, Feb-
Spangler Candy,” Confectionarynews.com, March 19, 2014. ruary 9, 2004, https://www.cato.org/publications/free-trade-
bulletin/sticky-state-affairs-sugar-us-australia-free-trade-
13. Ron Nixon, “American Candy Makers, Pinched by Inflated agreement.
Sugar Prices, Look Abroad,” New York Times, October 30, 2013.
25. Mark A. McMinimy, “U.S. Sugar Program Fundamentals,”
14. Joel Millman, “U.S. Candy Makers Go to Mexico, Changing Congressional Research Service, April 6, 2016, https://fas.org/sgp/
the Face of the Industry,” Wall Street Journal, February 13, 2002. crs/misc/R43998.pdf.

15. Alexandra Wexler, “Cheaper Sugar Sends Candy Makers 26. John Stencel, “The Sugar Industry Has Taken Its Lumps,” New
Abroad,” Wall Street Journal, October 20, 2013. York Times, May 30, 1981, http://www.nytimes.com/1981/05/30/
opinion/l-the-sugar-industry-has-taken-its-lumps-137343.html.
16. “Employment Changes in U.S. Food Manufacturing: The
Impact of Sugar Prices,” U.S. Department of Commerce 27. Eiler C. Ravnholt, “Sugar Subsidies,” New York Times, August
International Trade Administration, https://www.trade.gov/mas/ 8, 1982, http://www.nytimes.com/1982/08/08/business/l-sugar-
ian/build/groups/public/@tg_ian/documents/webcontent/tg_ subsidies-070536.html.
ian_002705.pdf.
28. “U.S. Sugar Policy,” American Sugar Alliance, https://
17. Lee A. Daniels, “Coke, Pepsi to Use More Corn Syrup,” New sugaralliance.org/us-sugar-policy.
York Times, November 7, 1984.
29. H. Con. Res. 40, 115th Cong. (2017) in Congress.gov, https://
18. “FAQs,” Coca-Cola Company, http://www.coca-colacompany. www.congress.gov/bill/115th-congress/house-concurrent-
com/contact-us/faqs. resolution/40/text.

19. Erin Geiger Smith, “An Imported Soda That Comes with 30. “Sugar: World Markets and Trade,” United States Department
Buzz,” New York Times, October 3, 2014. of Agriculture Foreign Agricultural Service, November 2017,
https://apps.fas.usda.gov/psdonline/circulars/sugar.pdf.
20. “The Economic Effects of Significant U.S. Import Restraints,”
United States International Trade Commission, September 2017, 31. “ASA Releases New Sugar Policy Video, Touts ‘Zero-for-
p. 59, https://www.usitc.gov/publications/332/pub4726.pdf. Zero’ Strategy,” American Sugar Alliance, May 22, 2013, https://
sugaralliance.org/asa-releases-new-sugar-policy-video-touts-
21. Michael K. Wohlgenant, “Sweets for the Sweet: The Costly zero-for-zero-strategy/4409.
12

32. Timothy P. Carney, “At Kochfest, Rubio Defends Sugar 36. Pearson, “Toward Free Trade in Sugar,” 9.
Subsidies on National Security Grounds,” Washington Examiner,
August 2, 2015. 37. Sugar Policy Modernization Act of 2017, H.R. 4265, 115th
Cong. (2017), https://www.congress.gov/bill/115th-congress/
33. “The Economic Effects of Significant U.S. Import Restraints,” house-bill/4265.
United States International Trade Commission, September 2017,
p. 59, https://www.usitc.gov/publications/332/pub4726.pdf. 38. “‘Sugar Farmer Bankruptcy Bill’ Introduced to Outsource
U.S. Sugar Production,” Press Release, American Sugar
34. Daniel R. Pearson, “Toward Free Trade in Sugar,” Cato Institute Alliance, November 7, 2017, https://sugaralliance.org/sugar-
Policy Analysis no. 768, February 11, 2015, https://object.cato.org/ farmer-bankruptcy-bill-introduced-outsource-u-s-sugar-
sites/cato.org/files/pubs/pdf/pa-768-updated-6-30-17.pdf. production/13742.

35. “Canadian Sugar Today,” Canadian Sugar Institute, http:// 39. “A Shameful Sugar Policy,” editorial, New York Times, May 10,
www.sugar.ca/International-Trade/Canadian-Sugar-Industry/ 1982, http://www.nytimes.com/1982/05/10/opinion/a-shameful-
Canadian-sugar-today.aspx. sugar-policy.html.

The views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and should not be attributed to the Cato Institute, its
trustees, its Sponsors, or any other person or organization. Nothing in this paper should be construed as an attempt to
aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress. Copyright © 2018 Cato Institute. This work by Cato Institute is
licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 4.0 International License.

You might also like