You are on page 1of 12

From Bringing the State Back In 5.

War Making and State Making as Organized


edited by Peter Evans, Dietrich Rueschemeyer, and Theda Skocpol
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1985), 169-191 Crime

Charles Tilly

Waming
If protection rackets represent organized crime at its smoothest. then war
making and state making - quintessential protection rackets with the ad-
vantage of legitimacy - qualify as our largest examples of organized crime.
Without branding all generals and statesmen as murderers or thieves, I
want to urge the value of that analogy. At least for the European experi-
ence of the past few centuries, a portrait of war makers and state makers
as coercive and self-seeking entrepreneurs bears a far greater resemblance
to the facts than do its chief alternatives: the idea of a social contract, the
idea of an open market in which operators of armies and states offer ser-
vices to willing consumers, the idea of a society whose shared norms and
expectations call forth a certain kind of government.
The reflections that follow merely illustrate the analogy of war making
and state making with organized crime from a few hundred years of Eu-
ropean experience and offer tentative arguments concerning principles of
change and variation underlying the experience. My reflections grow from
contemporary concerns: worries about the increasing destructiveness of
war, the expanding role of great powers as suppliers of arms and military
organization to poor countries, and the growing importance of military
rule in those same countries. They spring from the hope that the European
experience, properly understood, will help us to grasp what is happening
today, perhaps even to do something about it.
The Third World of the twentieth century does not greatly resemble Eu-
rope of the sixteenth or seventeenth century. In no simple sense can we
read the future of Third World countries from the pasts of European coun·
tries. Yet a thoughtful exploration uf Europt.'an experience will serve us
well. It will show us that COl'cciVl' l'xpillitalion pl,lyl'd a J,uK(' part in the
creation of the Euro~an stall'S. It will !Ihow us lh,lt pupular n'14i!llan('l~ to
170 Charles Tilly War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 171

coercive exploitation forced would-be power holders to concede protection produces both the danger and, at a price, the shield against it is a racketeer.
and constraints on their own action. It will therefore help us to eliminate Someone who provides a needed shield but has little control over the dan·
faulty implicit comparisons between today's Third World and yesterday's gel's. appearance.qualifies .as a legitimate protector, especially if his price is
Europe. That darification wiD make it easier to understand exactly how no. hiS:"er than his competitors'. Someone who supplies reliable, low·priced
today's world is diCCerent and what we therefore have to explain. It may shleldmg both from local racketeers and from outside marauders makes
~ven help u~ to explain the current looming presence of military organiza·
the best offer of all.
tion and action throughout the world. Although that result would delight ApolOgiSts for parti~lar governments and for government in general
me, I do not promise anything so grand. commonly argue, preosely, that they offer protection from local and exter-
This essay, then, concerns the place of organized means of violence in nal viole":ce. They daim that the prices they charge barely cover the costs
the growth and change of those peculiar forms of government we call na- of protection. They call people who complain about the price of protection
tional states; relatively centralized, differentiated organizations the officials "anarchists," "subversives." or both at once. But consider the defmition of
of which more or less successfully claim control over the chief concentrated a racketeer as someone who creates a threat and then charges for its reduc-
means of violence within a population inhabiting a large, contiguous ter· tion. Governme~ts' provision of protection, by this standard, often quali·
ritory. The argument grows from historical work on the formation of na- ties as racketeenng. To the extent that the threats against which a given
tional states in Western Europe, especially on the growth of the French gove~e~~ protects its citizens are imaginary or are consequences of its
state from 1600 onward. But it takes several deliberate steps away from own actiVIties, the government has organized a protection racket. Since
that work, wheels, and stares hard at it from theoretical ground. The ar- governments themselves commonly simulate, stimulate, or even fabricate
gument brings with it few illustrations and no evidence worthy of the name. threats of external war and since the repressive and extractive activities of
Just as one repacks a hastily filled rucksack after a few days on the trail governments often constitute the largest current threats to the livelihoods
- throwing out the waste, putting things in order of importance, and bal· of their own citizens, many governments operate in essentially the same
ancing the load - I have repacked my theoretical baggage for the climb to ways as racketeers. There is, of course, a difference; Racketeers, by the
come; the real test of the new packing arrives only with the next stretch of conve'itional definition, operate without the sanctity of governments.
the trail. The Irimmed-down argument stresses the interdependence of war How do racketeer governments themselves acquire authority? As a ques--
making and state making and the analogy between both of those processes tion of. fact and of ethics, that is one of the oldest conundrums of political
and what, when less successful and smaller in scale, we call organized analyslS. Ba~ to Machiavelli and Hobbes, nevertheless, political observers
crime. War makes states, I shall claim. Banditry, piracy, gangland rival.ry, have recogmzed that, whatever else they do, governments organize and,
policing, and war making all belong on the same continuum - that 1 shall wherever possible, monopolize violence. It matters little whether we take
claim as well. For the historically limited period in which national states violence in a narrow sense, such as damage to persons and objects, or in a
bc.oa~ sense, such as violation of people'S desires and interests; by either
were becoming the dominant organizations in Western countries, J shall
also claim that mercantile capitalism and state making reinforced each other. cntenon, governments stand out from other organizations by their ten-
dency to monopolize the concentrated means of violence. The distinction
between "legitimate" and "illegitimate" force, lurthennore, makes no dif-
Double-Edged Protection ference to the fact. If we take legitimacy to depend on conformity to an
In contemporary American parlance, the word "protection" sounds two abstract principle or on the assent of the governed (or both at once), these
contrasting tones. One is comforting, the other ominous. With one tone, conditio~s may serve to justify, perhaps even to explain, the tendency to

"protection" calls up images of the shelter against danger provided by a monopolize force; they do not contradict the fact.
powerful friend. a large insurance policy, or a sturdy roof. With the other, In any case, Arthur Stinchcombe's agreeably cynical treatment of legiti·
it evokes the racket in which a local strong man forces merchants to pay ~~cy serves the'purpos~s of political analysis much more efficiently. Le-
~hmacy, accordmg to Stinchcombe, depends rather little on abstract prin·
tribute in order to avoid damage - damage the strong man himself threat-
ens to deliver. The difference, to be sure, is a matter of degree: A hell·and· ople or assent of the governed: "The person over whom power is eXeTcised is
n?~ usually as important as other power-holders. "I Legitimacy is the proba.
damnation priest is likely to collect contributions from his parishioners only
b,h~ that other auth~r~ties will act to Ctlnfirm the decisions of a given au·
to the extent that they believe his predictions of brimstone for infidels; our
neighborhood mobster may actually be, as he claims to be, a brothel's best thorJty .. <?ther authonlles, I wuuld add, ,ul' much morc likely to confirm
guarantee of operation free of police intcrfcrt'nfi'. the deCISions of a challcnKl'" authority Iholt controls substantial force; not
Which image the word "prot<'Ctiun" ttrinKs to mind depends mainly un only fear of retaliatiun, bUI al...u desire to maintain a stattle envirnnment
our assessmt'nt uf thl' n'alily 'JIld t'.h'C1lollily of tht' thn'at. SUmt'Unl' whu recommend that ~eneral rule. The rule ullller~core" 1111' Impurtance ot lhe
172 Charles Tilly War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 173
authority's monopoly of force. A tendency to monopolize the means of tween "legitimate" and "illegitimate" force credible. Eventually, the per-
violence makes a government's daim to provide protection, in either the sonnel of states purveyed violence on a larger scale, more effectively, more
comforting or the ominous sense of the word, more credible and more efficiently, with wider assent from their subject populations, and with
difficult to resist. readier collaboration from neighboring authorities than did the personnel
Frank recognition of the central place of force in governmental activity of other organizations. But it took a long time for that series of distinctions
does not require us to believe that governmental authority rests "only" or to become established. Early in the state-making process, many parties sha red
"ultimately" on the threat of violence. Nor does it entail the assumption the right to use violence, the practice of using it routinely to accomplish
that a government's only service is protection. Even when a g~vernment's their ends, or both at once. The continuum ran from bandits and pirates to
use of force imposes a large cost, some people may well drode that the kings via tax collectors, regional power holders, and professional soldiers.
government's other services outbalance the costs of acreding to its monop- The uncertain, elastic line between "legitimate" and "illegitimate" vio-
oly of violence. Recognition of the centrality of force opens the way to an lence appeared in the upper reaches of power. Early in the stale-making
understanding of the growth and change of governmental forms. process, many parties shared the right to use violence, its actual employ-
Here is a preview of the most general argument: Power holders' pursuit ment, or both at once. The long love-hate affair between aspiring state
of war involved them willy-nilly in the extraction of resources for war mak- makers and pirates or bandits illustrates the division. "Behind piracy on
ing from the populations over which they had control and in the promo- the seas acteci cities and city-states," writes Femand Braudel of the six-
tion of capital accumulation by those who could help them borrow and teenth century. "Behind banditry, that terrestrial piracy, appeared the con-
buy. War making, extraction, and capital accumulation interacted to shape tinual aid of lords. "2 In times of war, indeed, the managers of full-fledged
European state making. Power holders did not undertake those three mo- states often commissioned privateers, hired sometime bandits to raid their
mentous activities with the intention of creating national states - central- enemies, and encouraged their regular troops to take booty. In royal ser-
ized, differentiated, autonomous, extensive political organizations. Nor did vice, soldiers and sailors were often expected to provide for themselves by
they ordinarily foresee that national states would emerge from war mak- preying on the civilian population: commandeering, raping, looting, tak-
ing, extraction, and capital accumulation. ing prizes. When demobilized, they commonly continued the same prac-
Instead, the people who controlled European states and states in the tices, but without the same royal protection; demobilized ships became
making warred in order to check or overcome their competitors and thus pirate vessels, demobilized troops bandits.
to enjoy the advantages of power within a secure or expanding territory. It also worked the other way: A king's best source of armed supporters
To make more effective war, they attempted to locate more capital. In the was sometimes the world of outlaws. Robin Hood's conversion to royal
short run, they might acquire that capital by conquest, by selling off their archer may be a myth, but the myth records a practice. The distinctions
assets, or by coercing or dispossessing accumulators of capital. In the long between "legitimate" and "illegitimate" users of violence came dear only
run, the quest inevitably involved them in establishing regular access to very slowly, in the process during which the state's armed forces became
capitalists who could supply and arrange credit and in imposing one form relatively unified and pennanent.
of reguJar taxation or another on the people and activities within their spheres Up 10 that point, as Braudel says, maritime cities and terrestrial lords
of control. commonly offered protection, or even sponsorship, to freebooters. Many
As the process continued, state makers developed a durable interest in lords who did not pretend to be kings, furthermore, successfully claimed.
promoting the accumulation of capital, sometimes in the guise of direct the right to levy troops and maintain their own armed retainers. Without
return to their own enterprises. Variations in the difficulty of collecting calling on some of those lords to bring their armies with them, no king
taxes, in the expense of the particular kind of armed force adopted, in the could fight a war; yet the same armed lords constituted the king's rivals
amount of war making required to hold off competitors, and so on resulted and opponents, his enemies' potential allies. For that reason, before the
in the principal variations in the forms of European states. It all began with seventeenlh century, regencies for child sovereigns reliably produced civil
the effort to monopolize the means of violence within a delimited territory wars. For the same reason, disarming the great stood high on the agenda
adjacent to a power holder's base. of every would-be state maker.
The Tudors, for example, accomplished that agenda through most of
England. "The greatest triumph of the Tudors," writes Lawrence Stone,
Violence and Government
What distinguished the violence producl-d by states from the violence d{'- was the ultimatt.'ly sUttt'ss{ul aSSl.'rfiun tit ;1 wy.11 ffillnupuly tit lIiult,n«' b<.lth public
livered by anyone else? In the rlln~ run, t'nUuKh to make tht> division bt.,. and prillatt', an achil'lIt'mt'nf whkh I'wftlundly "lh"I't1 nul nnly thl' nllllm' IIf pllli-
War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 175
174 Charles Tilly
tics but also the quality of daily life. There occurred a change in English habits that Eventually, European governments reduced their reliance on indirect rule
can only be compared with the further step taken in the nineteenth century, when by means of two expensive but effective strategies; (a) extending their of-
the growth of a police force finaUy consolidated the monopoly and made it ercective ficialdom to the local community and (b) encouraging the creation of police
in the greatest dties and the smallest villages. 3 forces that were subordinate to the government rather than to individual
patrons, distinct from war-making forces, and therefore less useful as the
Tudor demilitarization of the great lords entailed four complementary cam- tools of dissident magnates. In between, however, the builders of national
paigns; eliminating their great personal bands of armed retainers, razing power all played a mixed strategy; eliminating, subjugating.. dividing, con-
their fortresses, taming their habitual resort to violence for the settlement quering, cajoling.. buying as the occasions presented themselves. The buy-
of disputes, and discouraging the cooperation of their dependents and ten- ing manifested itself in exemptions from taxation. creations of honorific
ants. In the Marches of England and Scotland, the task was more delicate, offices. the establishment of claims on the national treasury, and a variety
for the Percys and Dacres, who kept armies and castles along the border, of other devices that made a magnate's welfare dependent on the mainte-
threatened the Crown but also provided a buffer against Scottish invaders. nance of the existing structure of power. In the long run, it all came down
Yet they, too, eventually fell into line. to massive pacification and monopolization of the means of coercion.
In France, Richelieu began the great disarmament in the 16205. With
RicheJieu's advice, Louis XIII systematically destroyed the castles of the
Prott'ction <15 Business
great rebel lords, Protestant and Catholic, against whom his forces battled.
incessantly. He began to condemn dueling.. the carrying of lethal weapons, In retrospect, the pacification, cooptation, or elimination of fractious rivals
and the maintenance of private armies. By the later 16205, RicheJieu was to the sovereign seems an awesome, noble, prescient enterprise, destined
declaring the royal monopoly of force as doctrine. The doctrine took an- to bring peace to a people; yet it followed almost ineluctably from the logic
other haU-eentury to become effective; of expanding power. If a power holder was to gain from the provision of
Once more the confficts of the Fronde had witnessed annies assembled by the protection, his competitors had to yield. As economic historian Frederic
"grands." Only the last of the regencies. the one after the death of Louis XIV, did Lane put it twenty-five years ago, governments are in the business of seIl-
not lead to anned uprisings. By that time Rkhelieu's principle had become a reality. ing protection ... whether people want it or not. Lane argued that the
Likewise in the Empire after the Thirty Years' War only the territorial princes had very activity of producing and controlling violence favored monopoly, be-
the right of levying troops and of maintaining fortresses.... Everywhere the raz- cause competition within that realm generally raised costs, instead of low-
ing of castles, the high cost of artillery, the attraction of court life, and the ensuing ering them. The production of violence, he suggested, enjoyed large econ-
domestication of the nobility had its share in this development. 4 omies of scale.
By the later eighteenth century, through most of Europe, monarchs con- Working from there, Lane distinguished between (a) the monopoly profit,
trolled permanent, professional military forces that rivaled those of their or lributt, coming to owners of the means of producing violence as a result
neighbors and far exceeded any other organized armed force within their of the difference between production costs and the price exacted from
own territories. The state's monopoly of large-scale violence was turning "customers" and (b) the prottetion rmf accruing to those customers - for
from theory to reality. example, merchants - who drew effective protection against outside com-
The elimination of local rivals, however, posed a serious problem. Be- petitors. Lane, a superbly attentive historian of Venice, allowed specifi-
yond the scale of a small city-state, no monarch could govern a population cally for the case of a government that generates protection rents for its
with his armed force alone, nor could any monarch afford to create a merchants by deliberately attacking their competitors. In their adaptation
professional staff large and strong enough to reach from him to the ordi- of Lane's scheme, furthermore, Edward Ames and Richard Rapp substi-
nary citizen. Before quite recently, no European government approached tute the apt word "extortion" for Lane's "tribute." In this model, preda-
the completeness of articulation from top to bottom achieved by imperial tion, coercion, piracy, banditry. and racketeering share a home with their
China. Even the Roman Empire did not come close. In one way or another, upright cousins in responsible government.
every European government before the French Revolution relied on indi- This is how Lane's model worked; If a prince could create a sufficient
rect rule via local magnates. The magnates collaborated with the govern-
armed force to hold off his and his subjects' external enemies and to keep
ment without becoming officials in any slrong sense of the term, had some the subjects in line for SO megapounds but was able to extract 75 mega-
access to government-backed force, and exercised wide discretion within pounds in taxes from those subjt'Cts for that purpose, he Rained a tribute
their own territories; junkers. justices of Ihe peace, lords. Yet the same of (75- SO=) 25 ml'gapound:o>. If tht' IO·pt,und shart' tlf thuSt' taxes paid by
magnates were potential rivals, possibll' allies of a rebellious peopll'. one of tht> princes ml·rchant·subjt,(,ts KOlVl' him ols1'lurl.'d ilCt."t.'SS to world
176 O\arles Tilly War Making and State Making as Organiud Crime 177
markets at less than the IS-pound shares paid by the merchant's foreign 3. A stage in which merchants and landlords began to gain more from
competitors to thnr princes, the merchant also gained a Pr:otection rent of protection rents than governors did from tribute
(15- 10=) 5 pounds by virtue of his prince's greater effia~ncy. ~at rea- 4. A period (fairly recent) in which technological changes surpassed
soning differs only in degree and in scale from the r~aso~mg ~f violence- protection rents as sources of profit for entrepreneurs
wielding criminals and their clients. Labor racketeenng (10 WhiCh, for ex-
ample, a ship owner holds off trouble from longshoremen by means .of ~ In their new economic history of the Western world, Douglass North and
timely payment to the local union boss) ,:",000 o~ exactly the same pnno- Robert Paul Thomas make stages 2 and 3 - those in which state makers
pie: The union boss receives tribute f~r hIS no-s!"ke pressure on the long- created their monopolies of force and established property rights that per-
shoremen, while the ship owner aVOIds the strikes and slowdowns long- mitted individuals to capture much of the return from their own growth-
shoremen impose on his competitors. generating innovations - the pivotal moment for sustained economic growth.
Lane pointed. out the different behavior we might expect of the managers Protection, at this point, overwhelms tribute. If we recognize that the pro-
of a protection-providing government owned by tected property rights were mainly those of capital and that the develop-
ment of capitalism also facilitated the accumulation of the wherewithal to
1. Citizens in general operate massive states, that extension of Lane's analysis provides a good
2. A single self-interested. monarch deal of insight into the coincidence of war making, state making, and cap-
3. The managers themselves ital accumulation.
Unfortunately, Lane did not take full advantage of his own insight.
U cit:izens in general exercised effective ownership .o~ t~e govern~ent - 0 Wanting to contain his analysis neatly within the neoclassical theory of
distant ideal! - we might expect the managers to mlnuJUze protecbon costs industrial organization, Lane cramped his treatment of protection: treating
and tribute, thus maximizing protection rent. A single self-interest~ mon- alI taxpayers as "customers" for the "service" provided by protection-man.
arch, in contrast, would maximize tribute, set costs so as to accomphsh that ufacturing governments, brushing aside the objections to the idea of a forced
maximization of tribute, and be indifferent to the level of protection rent. sale by insisting that the "customer" always had the choice of not paying
If the managers owned the government, th~y ~oul~ tend to keep costs and taking the consequences of nonpayment, minimizing the problems of
high by maximizing their own wages, to m~mlz~ tnbute ov~r an.d above divisibility created by the public-goods character of protection, and delib-
those costs by exacting a high price from theIr subjects, and Iikew~ to be erately neglecting the distinction between the costs of producing the means
indifferent to the level of protection rent. The firs.t model appro~mates.a of violence in general and the costs of giving "customers" protection by
Jeffersonian democracy, the second a petty despotism, and the third a mil- means of that violence. Lane's ideas suffocate inside the neoclassical box
itary junta. . and breathe easily outside it. Nevertheless, inside or outside, they prop-
Lane did not discuss the obvious fourth category of owner: a dominant erly draw the economic analysis of government back to the chief activities
class. If he had, his scheme would have yielded interesting empirical cri- that real governments have carried on historically: war, repression, protec-
teria for evaluating claims that a given government was "~Iatively auton- tion adjudication.
omous" or strictly subordinate to the interests of a dom~n~nt class. Pre- More recently, Richard Bean has applied a similar logic to the rise of
sumably, a subordinate government would t~nd to maXlmlz.e monopoly European national states between 1400 and 1600. He appeals to economies
profits _ returns to the dominant class resulting .from the. dIfference be- of scale in the production of effective force, counteracted by diseconomies
tween the costs of protection and the price received. for It - as w~1I as of scale in command and control. He then claims that the improvement of
tuning protection rents nicely to the economic interests of the d0"':l~nt artillery in the fifteenth century (cannon made small medieval forts much
class. An autonomous government, in contrast, would ~en~ to maximIze more vulnerable to an organized force) shifted the curve of economies and
managers' wages and its own size as well and would be mdlffen:~t to pro- diseconomies to make larger armies, standing armies, and centralized gov-
tection rents. Lane's analysis immediately suggests fresh propositions and ernments advantageous to their masters. Hence, according to Bean, mili-
ways of testing them. tary innovation promoted the creation of large, expensive, well-anned. na-
Lane also speculated that the logic of the situation produced four succes- tional states.
sive stages in the general history of capitalism:

1. A period of anarchy and plunder . Hiltory Talks


2. A stage in which tribute takers attracted cust~mers and e~tabhsht."lJ Bean's summary does nut ~tand ur to historil'al !t('Ntiny. A:4 II moltlt'rof
their monupulit.'S by struAAlinK tn l"T\'ilh' t'xcluSlvl', substantial states practin', tht' shift to infantry-h..lrkt'd artillery llj"KI'1l of furtiflt'l1 !ili"1l II("·
War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 179
178 Charles Tilly
standing mobilizers of capital. Both the trade and the capital served the
curred only during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Artillery did purposes of ambitious rulers. Bya circuitous route, that observation brings
improve during the fifteenth century, but the invention of new fortific~­ us back to the arguments of Lane and Bean. Considering that both of them
tions, especially the traa ilalienne, rapidly countered the advantage of ar~­ wrote as economic historians, the greatest weakness in their analyses comes
lery. The arrival of effective artillery came too late to have mused the 10- as a surprise: Both of them understate the importance of capital accumu-
crease in the viable size of states. (However, the increased cost of fortifications lation to military expansion. As Jan de Vries says of the period after 1600:
to defend against artillery did give an advantage to states enjoying larger
fiscal bases.) Looking back, one cannot help but be struck by the seE'mingly symbiotic relation-
Nor is it obvious that changes in land war had the sweeping influence ship existing between the state, military power, and the private economy's effi-
Bean attributes to them. lhe increasing decisiveness of naval warfare, which ciency in the age of absolutism. Behind every successful dynasty stoOO an array of
occurred simultaneously, could well have shifted the military advantage to opulent banking families. Access to such bourgeois resources proved crucial to the
princes' state-building and centralizing policies. Princes also needed direct access
small maritime powers such as the Dutch Republic. Furthermore, although to agricultural resources, which coukl be mobilized only when agricuttural produc-
many city-states and other microscopic entities disappeared into larger p0- tivity grew I'M an effectillt' administrative and military power existed to enforce the
litical units before 1600, such events as the fractionation of the Habsburg princes' claims. But the lines of causation also ran in the opposite direction. Suc-
Empire and such facts as the persistence of large but loosely knit Poland cessful state-buiJding and empire-buiJding activities plus the associated tendency
and Russia render ambiguous the claim of a significant increase in geo- toward co~ntration of urban population and government expenditure, offered
graphic scale. In short, both Bean's proposed explanation and his state- the private economy unique and invaluable opportunities to capture economies of
ment of what must be explained raise historical doubts. scale. These economies of scale occasionaUy affected industrial production but were
Stripped of its technological determinism, nevertheless, Bean's logic pro-- most signifICant in the development of trade and finance. In addition, the sheer
vides a useful complement to Lane's, for different military formats do cost pressure of cental government taxation did as much as any other economic force to
substantially different amounts to produce and do provide substantially channel peasant production into the market and thereby augment the opportuni-
different ranges of control over opponents, domestic and foreign. After ties for trade creation and economic specialization. s
1400 the European pursuit of larger, more permanent, and more costly Nor does the "symbiotic relationship" hold only for the period after 1600.
varieties of military organization did, in fact, drive spectacular increases in For the precocious case of France, we need only consider the increase in
princely budgets, taxes, and staffs. After 1500 or so, princes who managed royal expenditures and revenues from 1515 to 1785. Although the rates of
to create the costly varieties of military organization were, indeed, able to growth in both regards accelerated appropriately after 1600, they also rose
conquer new chunks of territory. substantially during the sixteenth century. After 1550, the internal Wars of
The word. "territory" should not mislead us. Until the eighteenth cen- Religion checked the work of international expansion that Francis I had
tury, the greatest powers were maritime states, and naval warfare re- begun earlier in the century, but from the 16205 onward Louis xm and
mained crucial to international position. Consider Fernand Braudel's roll Louis XIV (aided and abetted, to be sure, by Richelieu, Mazarin, Colbert,
call of successive hegemonic powers within the capitalist world: Venice and other state-making wizards) resumed the task with a vengeance. "As
and its empire, Genoa and its empire, Antwerp-Spain, Amsterdam-HoI- always," comments V. G. Kiernan, "war had every political recommenda-
land, London-England, New York-the United States. Although Branden- tion and every financial drawback. "6
burg-Prussia offers a partial exception, only in our own time have such Borrowing and then paying interest on the debt accounts for much of
essentially landbound states as Russia and China achieved preponderant the discrepancy between the two curves. Great capitalists played crucial
positions in the world's system of states. Naval warfare was by no means parts on both sides of the transaction: as the principal sources of royal
the only reason for that bias toward the sea. Before the later nineteenth credit, especially in the short term, and as the most important contractors
century, land transportation was so expensive everywhere in Europe that in the risky but lucrative business of collecting royal taxes. For this reason,
no country could afford to supply a large army or a big city with grain and it is worth noticing that
other heavy goods without having efficient water transport. Rulers fed ma-
jor inland centers such as Berlin and Madrid on.ly at gr~a.t effort and at for practical purposes the national debl began in the reign of Francis I. Following
considerable cost to their hinterlands. The exceptional effiCiency of water- the loss of Milan, the key 10 northern Italy, on 'september 15, 1522, Francis I bor-
ways in the Netherlands undoubtedly gave the Dutch great advantages at lOwed 200,000 francs ... al 12.5 pt'm.'Ol frum tht' rnl'rchanls of Paris, to intensify
peace and at war. the war aKainsl Charll'S V. Adminish'fI'd I:>y lhl' dly Il:lll/l'rnmt'nl. this loan ina",-
Ruratro Ihl' famuus Sl'ril'S 1I/I:>Ilnd.~ 1:>,1!<l'lJ oIn n'Vl!ntll'~ frum lh., '·i.rilal and knllwn
Access to water mattered in another important way. Thos(' metropolises 11'1 rmlt'S sur /'IMld d,' ViII,·!
on Braudel's list were all major ports, Rreat centers of wmmerct', and out·
J80 Charles Tilly War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 181
(The government's failure to pay those rerdt!S, incidentally, helped align the
Parisian bourgeoisie against the Crown during the Fronde, some twelve Wlut Do Sf;tles Do?
decades later.) By 1595, the national debt had risen to 300 million francs; As should now be clear, Lane's analysis of protection fails to distinguish
despite governmental bankruptcies, C\llT'ency manipulations, and the among several different uses of state-eontrolled violence. Under the gen-
monumental rise in taxes, by Louis XIV's death in 1715 war-induced bor- eral heading of organized violence, the agents of states characteristically
rowing had inflated the total to about 3 billion francs, the equivalent of cany on four different activities:
about eighteen years in royal revenues.' War, state apparatus, taxation,
and borrowing advanced in tight cadence. 1. War making: Eliminating or neutralizing their own rivals outside
Although France was precocious, it was by no means alone. "Even more the territories in which they have dear and continuous priority as
than in the case of France," reports the ever-useful Earl J. Hamilton, wielders of force
2. State making: Eliminating or neutralizing their rivals inside those
the national debt of England originated and has grown during major wars. Except territories
for an insignificant cany-over from the StUilrts, the debt began in 1689 with the
3. Protection: Eliminating or neutralizing the enemies of their clients
reign of William and Mary. In the words of Adam Smith, "it was in the war which
began in 1688, and was conduded by the treaty of Ryswick in 1697, that the foun- 4. Extraction: Acquiring the means of carrying out the first three ac-
dation of the present enormous debt of Great Britain was first laid."9 tivities - war making, state making, and protection

Hamilton, it is true, goes on to quote the mercantilist Charles Davenant, The third item corresponds to protection as analyzed by Lane, but the other
who complained in 1698 that the high interest rates promoted by govern- three ~Iso involve the application of force. They overlap incompletely and
ment borrowing were cramping English trade. Davenant's complaint sug- to vanous degrees; for example, war making against the commercial rivals
gests, however, that England was already entering Frederic Lane's third of the local bourgeoisie delivers protection to that bourgeoisie. To the ex-
stage of state-capital relations, when merchants and landowners receive tent that a population is divided into enemy classes and the state extends
more of the surplus than do the suppliers of protection. its favors partially to one class or another, state making actually reduces
Until the sixteenth century, the English expected their kings to live on the protection given some classes.
revenues from their own property and to levy taxes only for war. G. R. War making, state making, protection, and extraction each take a num-
Elton marks the great innovation at Thomas Cromwell's drafting of Henry ber of ~onns. Extraction, f~r instance, ranges from outright plunder to reg_
YlJI's subsidy bills for 1534 and 1540: "1540 was very careful to continue ular tribute to bureaucratized laxation. Yet aU four depend on the state's
the real innovation of 1534, namely that extraordinary contributions could tendency to monopolize the concentrated means of coercion. From the per-
be levied for reasons other than war:'IO After that point as before, how- spectives of those who dominate the state, each of them - if carried on
ever, war making provided the main stimulus to increases in the level of eff~vely :- g~nerally ~nforces the others. Thus, a state that successfully
taxation as well as of debt. Rarely did debt and taxes recede. What A. T. eradicates Its Internal nvals strengthens its ability to extract resources, to
Peacock and J. Wiseman call a "displacement effect" (and others some- wa~e war, and to prot~ct its chief supporters_ In the earlier European ex-
times call a "ratchet effect") occurred: When public revenues and expen- penence, broadly speaking. those supporters were typically landlords armed
ditures rose abruptly during war, they set a new, higher floor beneath retainers of the monarch, and churchmen. '
which peacetime revenues and expenditures did not sink. During the Na- Each of the major uses of violence produced characteristic fonos of or·
poleonic Wars, British taxes rose from 15 to 24 percent of national income ganization War making yielded armies, navies, and supporting services.
and to almost three times the French level of taxation. 11 State making produced durable instruments of surveiJIance and control
True, Britain had the double advantage of relying less on expensive land within the te~tory. Protection n:lied on the organization of war making
forces than its Continental rivals and of drawing more of its tax revenues and state making but .added to It an apparatus by which the protected
from customs and excise - taxes that were, despite evasion, significantly called forth. the prot~on that wa.s their due, notably through courts and
cheaper to coUect than land taxes, property taxes, and poll taxes. Never- repre~ntah~e assembhes. ~xt~action brought fiscal and accounting struc-
theless, in England as well as elsewhere, both debt and taxes rose enor- tures mto bemg. The orgamzatlon and deployment of violence themselves
mously from the seventeenth century onward. They rose mainly as a func- account for much of the characteristic structure of European states.
tion of the increasing cost of war making. The general rule seems to have operated like this: The more costly the
.~vity, all other things being equal. the greater was the organizational
reSidue. To the extent, for exampit', that a Kivt'n Kuvcmmcnl invested in
lal'Ke standing armies - a vt'ry CU!'ltly. if effective, ml.'anM of war making-
182 Owles Tilly War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 183

>< ExTon
the bureaucracy created to service the army was likely to become bulky.
Furthermore, a government building a standing army while controUing a
! +
small population was likely to incur greater costs, and therefore to build a
bulkier structure, than a government within a populous country. Branden·
burg-Prussia was the classic case of high cost for available resources. The
w"Tn g

Prussian effort to build an army matching those of its larger Continental Pmtron • Stotf M.k;ng
neighbors created an immense structure; it militarized and bureaucratized
much of German social life.
In the case of extraction, the smaller the pool of resources and the less
commercialized the economy. other things being equal, the more difficult In a~ ideal~zed sequen~, a gre.at lord made war so effectively as to become
was the work of extracting resources to sustain war and other governmen- donun~t 10 a substanllal temtory, but that war making led to increased
tal activities; hence, the more extensive was the fiscal apparatus. England extraction of the means of war - men, arms, focxl, lodging. transportation
illustrated the corollary of that proposition, with a relatively large and com· supplies, andlor ~h~ money to buy them - from the population within tha~
mercialized pool of resources drawn on by a relatively small fiscal appa- temt~ry. The buiJdmg up of war-making capacity likewise increased the
ratus. As Gabriel Ardant has argued, the choice of fiscal strategy probably capa~ty, to ~xtract. The very activity of extraction, if successful, entailed
made an additional difference. On the whole, taxes on land were expen- the ell,mmanon, neutral~zation, or cooptation of the great lord's local rivals;
sive to collect as compared with taxes on trade, especially large flows of thus, It led to state making. As a by-product, it created organization in the
trade past easily controlled checkpoints. Its position astride the entrance to fonn of tax~o~lectio.n agencies, police forces, courts, exchequers, account
the Baltic gave Denmark an extraordinary opportunity to profit from cus· ~eeJ>C:rs; thus It agam l~ to state making. To a lesser extent, war making
toms revenues. ~kewlse led to st~te makmg through the expanSion of military organization
With respect to state making (in the narrow sense of eliminating or neu- ItseU, as a standIng army. war industries, supporting bureaucracies, and
tralizing the local rivals of the people who controlled the state), a territory (rather later) schools grew up within the state apparatus. All of these struc.
populated by great landlords or by distinct religious groups generally im- tures c~ecked potential rivals and opponents. In the course of making war,
posed larger costs on a conqueror than one of fragmented power or ho- extracting resources, and building up the state apparatus, the managers of
mogeneous culture, This time, fragmented and homogeneous Sweden. with states formed alliances with specific social classes. The members of those
its relatively small but effective apparatus of control, illustrates the corol- clas~ loaned resources, provided technical services, or helped ensure the
lary. compliance of the rest of the population, all in return for a measure of
Finally, the cost of protection (in the sense of eliminating or neutralizing ~rotection against their own rivals and enemies. As a result of these mul.
the enemies of the state makers' clients) mounted with the range over which tipl,e strat~gic choices, a distinctive state apparatus grew up within each
that protection extended. Portugal's effort to bar the Mediterranean to its major section of Europe.
merchants' competitors in the spice trade provides a textbook case of an
unsuccessful protection effort that nonetheless built up a massive struc- How Stat~ Formed
tu....
Thus, the sheer size of the government varied directly with the effort This ~nalysis, if co~, has two st.rong implications for the development
devoted to extraction, state making, protection, and, especially, war mak· of nation~1 states. First, POPul~r resistance to war making and state making
ing but inversely with the commercialization of the economy and the ex- made a dlffe~nce, When ordmary people resisted vigorously, authorities
tent of the resource base, What is more, the relative bulk of different fea- made concessions: guarantees of rights, representative institutions, courts
tures of the government varied with the cost/resource ratios of extraction, oi appea~. Those concessio,ns, in their tum, constrained the later paths of
state making, protection, and war making. In Spain we see hypertrophy of wa~ making and sta.te makmg, To be sure, alliances with fragments of the
Court and courts as the outcome of centuries of effort at subduing internal ":,,~ng. class greatly Increased the effects of popular action; the broad mo-
enemies, whereas in Holland we are amazed to see how small a fiscal ap- bilizallon of gent~ against Charles I helped give the English Revolution of
paratus grows up with high taxes within a rich, commercialized economy, 1640 a far greater Impact on political institutions than did any of the mul-
Oearly, war making. extraction, state making. and protection were in- tiple rebellions during the Tudor era.
terdependent. Speaking very, very generally, the classic European state- Second, the relative balance amonp; war makinp;, prott"CIion, extraction.
making experience followed this causal pattern: and state making sip;nificantly affloctt'd thl' tlTKani)'''tinn u( thl' litatl'li that
184 Charles Tilly War Mning and State Making as Organized Crime 1&5
emerged from the four activities. To the extent that war making went on m.onopo~ the means of violence, and thereby increased his return from
with relatively little extraction, protection, and state making. for example, mbute, continued on a larger scale into the logic of war. Early in the pro-
military forces ended up playing a larger and more autonomous part in cess, external and internal rivals overlapped to a large degree. Only the
national politics. Spain is perhaps the best European example. To the ex- establishm~nt.of large perimeters of control within which great lords had
tent that protection, as in Venice or Holland, prevailed over war making. checked ~ ovals sharpened the line between internal and external George
extraction, and state making, oligarchies of the protected classes tended to Modelski sums up the competitive logic cogently:
dominate subsequent national politics. From the relative predominance of
state making sprang the disproportionate elaboration of policing and sur- GI~I power ... stren~thened those states that attained it relatively to all other
veillance; the Papal States illustrate that extreme. Before the twentieth cen- political and other orga~~ons. Wh~t is. more, other states competing in the global
tury, the range of viable imbalances was fairly small. Any state that failed power gam~ developed .slmllar orgamzatlonal forms and similar hardiness: they too
to put considerable effort into war making was likely to disappear. As the became natIon-states - In a defensive reaction, because forced to take issue with or
twentieth century wore on, however, it became increasingly common for to ~nfro~t a g~bal power, as France confronted Spain and later Britain, or in inti-
tatiO~ o.f I~ obvIOUS success and effectiveness, as Germany followed the example
one state to lend, give, or seD war-making means to another; in those cases, of Bntaln In Weltmacht, or as earlier Peter the Great had rebuilt Russia on Dutch
the recipient state could put a disproportionate effort into extraction, pro-- p~pts and examples. Thus not only Portugal. the Netherlands. Britain and the
tection, and/or state making and yet survive. In our own time, clients of Uruted States became nation-states. but also Spain, France, Germany, Russia and
the United States and the Soviet Union provide numerous examples. Japan. The short, ~.nd the most parsimonious, answer to the question of why these
This simplified model. however, negiects the external relations that shaped sU~ed where most of the European efforts to build states failed" is that they
every national state. Early in the process, the distinction between "inter- were eIther global powers or successfully fought with or against them. U
nal" and "external" remained as unclear as the distinction between state
power and the power accruing to lords allied with the state. Later, three This logic of international state making aets out on a large scale the logic of
interlocking influences connected any given national state to the European local aggrandizement. The external complements the internal.
network of states. First, there were the flows of resources in the fonn of If we allow that fragile distinction between "internal" and "external"
loans and supplies, especially loans and supplies devoted to war making. state-maki.ng processes, then we might schematize the history of European
Second, there was the competition among states for hegemony in disputed state ma.ki~~ as thr;.e stages: (a) The. differential success of some power
territories, which stimulated war making and temporarily erased the dis- holders In external struggles estabhshes the difference between an "in-
tinctions among war making, state making. and extraction. Third, there ternal" .a~d an "external" arena for the deployment of force; (b) "external"
was the intermittent creation of coalitions of states that temporarily com- competition ~nerates "internal" state making; (c) "external" compacts
bined their efforts to force a given state into a certain fonn and position among states mfluence the fonn and locus of particular states ever more
within the international network. The war-making coalition is one exam- powerfully. I". this perspective, state<ertifying organizations such as the
ple, but the peace-making coalition played an even more crucial part: From League of Nations and the United Nations simply extended the European-
1648, if not before, at the ends of wars aU effective European states c0- based process to the ~o~ld as.a whole. Whether forced or voluntary, bloody
alesced temporarily to bargain over the boundaries and rulers of the recent ~r peaceful, decoloruzation sl11lply completed that process by which exist-
beUigerents. From that point on, periods of major reorganization of the 109 states leagued to create new ones.
European state system came in spurts, at the settlement of widespread The extension of the Europe-based state-making process to the rest of
wars. From each large war, in general, emerged fewer national states than the world, however, did not result in the creation of states in the strict
had entered it. European i~age. Broadly speaking. internal struggles such as the checking
of great n:glonal lords and the imposition of taxation on peasant villages
War as International Relations produced Important organizational features of European states: the relative
lubordination of military power to civilian control, the extensive bureau-
In these circumstances, war be<:ame the nonnal condition of the interna- aacy of fiscal surveillance, the representation of wronged interests via pe-
tional system of states and the nonnal means of defending or enhancing a tition and parliament. On the whole, states ~Isewhere developed differ-
position within the system. Why war? No simple answer will do; war as a ently .. T~e most telling feature of that difference appears in military
potent means served more than one end. But surely part of the answer orga".lzatlon. Europea~ state~ built.up their military apparatuses through
goes back to the central mechanisms of state making: The very logic by IUS~alRed strugglt's With their sub'l"l't populoltil1ns and by means of se-
which a local lord extended or defended the perimeter within which ht, ~lVe extension uf pmtl'C1illn tu di(ft'n'nl d"SM'~ within thuM' pupuu-
186 Charles Tilly War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 187

tions. The agreements on protection constrained the rulers themselv~s, 11. Peter Mathias, The Tronsfomudion of Eng/lind: Essays in thr Economic lind SociDl
making them vulnerable to courts, to assemblies, to withdrawals of credit, History of England in /he Eigh/Mlth Cm/lfry (New York: Oxford University Press,
1979), p. 122.
services, and expertise.
12. George Modelski. "The Long Cycle of Global Politics and the Nation State"
To a larger degree, states that have come into being recently through
Comparlltive Studies in Society fmd History 20 (1978): 231. '
decolonization or through reallocations of territory by dominant states. have
acquired their military organization from outside, without the same mter- Bibliography
nal forging of mutual constraints betwee~. rulers and ruled. To t~e e.xtent Ames, Edward, and Richard T. Rapp. "The Birth and Death of Taxes: A Hypothe-
that outside states continue to supply military goods and expertise to re- sis." Jourrull of falnomic History 37 (1977): 161-78.
turn for commodities, military alliance or both, the new states harbor pow· Ardent, Gctbriel. "Financial Policy and Economic Infrasln.lcture of Modem States
erful. unconstrained organizations that easily overshadow all other orga- and Nations." In TM FDnnlltion of NationJJ.l Stales in Western Eu~, edited by
nizations within their territories. To the extent that outside states guarantee Charles Tilly. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975.
their boundaries, the managers of those military organizations exercise ex· BacHe, Bertrand. udivdopptmnrt poIitique. 2nd ed. Paris: Economia, 1980.
b'aordinary power within them. The advantages of military power become Badie, Bertrand, and Pierre Birnbaum. SocioIog~ de rEtat. Paris: Bernard Grassel
1979. •
enormous, the incentives to seize power over the state as a whole by me~ns
of that advantage very strong. Despite the great place that war making Bayar:d' Franroise. "Fennes et trait& en France dans Ia premiere moitie du XVlle
slkle.(premiere esquisse 1631-1653)," Bullnin du Cnrtn d'Histoirr, Eamomique
occupied in the making of European states,. the old ~tional states ~~ Eu- tf Soda/ede la Region Lyonna~, no. 1(1976): 45-80.
rope almost never experienced the great disproportton between mIh~ry Bean, Richard. "War and the Birth of the Nation State." Journal of Eo:momic History
organization and all other fonns of organization that seems the fate of client 33 (1973): 203-21.
states throughout the contemporary world. A century ago, Europeans might Blockmans, W. P. "A Typology of Representative Institutions in Late MedievaJ
have congratulated themselves on the spread of civil govemm~nt through- Europe." Journal of ~iml/ History 4 (1m): 189-215.
out the world. In our own time, the analogy between war making and state Blok, Anton. Thr Mafia of a Sici/illn Village, J860-J96O: A. Stuilyof Viofmt PtIlSQnl
making. on the one hand, and organized crime, on the other, is becoming EnlrtprtnnlTS. Oxford: Blackwell. 1974.
tragically apt. Sooney, Richard. PoIitialJ CJumge IIndt'r Richt/~u and MillArin. J624-J661. Oxford:
Oxford University Press, 1978.
Braudel. Femand. LR Miditmana rt Ie monde mfditemmkn II fipoqut dt Philippe II.
Notes 2d ed. 2 vols. Paris: Annand Colin, 1%6.
1. Arthur L. Stinchcombe, Cons/ructing SodIiI 'l'Morin (New York: Harcourt, Brace Civilisation materiel/e, irom:mr.it, rt atpi/lI/isme, XVe-XVllIe sii'l:k. 3 vols. Paris:
& World, 1968), p. ISO; italics in the original. Annand Colin, 1979.
2. Femand Braudel, LA MMitrmmtt rt ~ mondr mMitemmhn II l'ipotJue de PhiliW Braun. Rudolf. "Taxation. Sociopolitical Structure, and State-Building: Greal Britain
II (Paris: Armand Colin, 1%6), vol. 2, pp. 88-89. an~ Brandenburg+Prussia." In TM Formalian of NlItional Slates in Wtstt'rtf.Europt.
3. Lawrence Stone, The Crisis oftM Aristocrm:y (Oxford: Oarendon Press, 1965), p. edited by Charles Tilly. Princeton. N.j.: Prin~ton University Press, 1975.
200. "Steuem und Staatsfinanzierung als Modemisierungsfaktoren:,Ein deutsch-
4. Dietrich Gerhard, Old Europt: A Study ofCon/inuity, 1000-1800 (New York: Ac- engiischer Vergleich." In Studien zum &ginn dtr modernen Wtlt, e,:tited by Rein.
ademic Press, 1981), pp. 124-25. hard Koselleck. Stuttgart: K1ett-Colta, 1977. /
5. Jan de Vries, The Economy of Europt in lin Age of Crisis, 16OO-J750 (Cambridge: Cameiro, Robert. "Political Expansion as an Expression of the Prirkiple of Com-
Cambridge University Press, 1976). petitive Exclusion! In Origins of the Statr, edited by Ronald Coh~n and Elman
6. V. G. Kiernan, S/ll/e lind Society in Europt", 1550-1650 (Oxford: Blackwell, 1980), R. Service. Philadelphia: Institute for the Study of Human Issues~ 1978.
p. 104. For French finances, see Alain Guery, "Les Finances de la Monarchic Carsten, F. L. The Origins of Prussia. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1954. \
Franc;aisc sous I'Ancien Regime," Anna/es Economies, Sodttts, Civilisations 33 (1978), Chapman, Brian. Police State. London: Pall Mall, 1970.
p.227. Opolla, Carlo M. Guns, Sails, and Empires: Trchnalogicallnncroalion lind /Iu: fArly Phases
7. Earl J. Hamilton, "Origin and Growth of the National Debt in France and En· of European Expansion 1400-1700. New York: Pantheon Press, 1965.
gland," in Studi in ouore di Gino Luzzoto (Milan: Giuffre, 1950), vol. 2, p. 254. Clark, .Sir George. "The Social Foundations of States." In The New Cambridge Modern
8. Ibid., pp. 247, 249. HIstOry, vol. 5. The Ascendancy of Frllnet:, 1648-88, edited by F. L Carsten. Cam-
9. Jbid., p. 254. bridge: Cambridge University Press, 1969.
10. G. R. Elton, "Taxation for War and Pea~ in Early-Tudor England," in War 111101 Cooper, J. P. "Diff('ren~s betw~n EnAJillh and Cllntil\\'nt,,1 Guvernm('nls in the
Economic Ckvtlopmrut: Essays in Memory of David loslin, cd. J. M. Winter (Cam Early.St,vl'nl('l.'nth Ct'ntury:'ln H~i/lIi" 111,,1 tl", Nr/II,.,III,,,I.'. l"tlit,"tI by J. S. Bnlml,.y
bridge: Cambridp;e University Press, 1975). p. 42. and E. II. Kussm,'nn. I.lIndun: ( h,lltu Ie Wimlll.~. IW1II
War Making and State Making as Otgani%ed Crime 189
188 Charles Tl1ly
'The Concept of Order and the Northern Rising. 1569." PtlSt and Prtstnt 60
"General Introduction." In ~ NnD OImbridgr Modtrn History, vol. 4, 17It' Dt- (1973): 49--83.
diM of Sp2in tmd Thirty YtlIr$ Wllr, 1609-58159, edited by J. P. Cooper. Cam- John. A. H. "Wars and the British Economy. 1700--1763." Economic History Rtvitw.
bridge: Cambridge University Press, 19'70. . . 2d ser., 7 (1955): 329-44.
Davis, Lance E. "Ifs a Long, Long Road to Tipperary, or Reflectlon~~n Or~nlz.e?, Kiernan, V. G. "Conscription and Society in Europe before the War of 1914-18."
Violence, Protection Rates, and Related Topics: The New Pohtical History. In War lind Soddy: Historical Essays in Honour and Mtmory of J. R. Wtsttrn, 1928-
loumal of Economic History 40 (1980): 1-16. .' J971, edited by M. R. D. Foot. London: Elek Books, 1973.
[)ent, Julian. Crisis in Fi,rall(%: Crown, Fin/meiers, lind Socrtly In Sevenl«nth.ctntury Slaltand Society in £uropt, 1550-1650. Oxford: Blackwell. 1980.
Fran«. Newton Abbot, United Kingdom: David &; Charles, 1973. van KIaveren, Jacob. "Die historische Erscheinung der Korruption." Vinttljahr-
Dickson, P. G. M. Tht Firrancial RnJolution in Englllnd: A Study in tM OnJtlapmtnt of schrift fUr Sc:zial- und Wirtsdlaftsgtsdiichlt 44 (1957): 289-324.
Public Cmfit. 1688-1756. London: St. Martin's Press. 1967. "Fiskalismus - Merkantilismus - Korruption: Drei Aspekte der Finaltt- und
Elton, G. R. "Taxation (or War and Peace in Early-Tudor England." In War and Wirtschahspolitik wihrend des Ancien Regime." Vintdjahrsdrrift fUr SozitU- UM
Economic Dtvtlopmtnt: Essilys in Mtrnory of David loslin, edited by J. M. Winter. Wirlsdul{tsgtsdtidlte 47 (1960): 333-53.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1975. .. . Ladero Quesado, Miguel Angel. "Les finances royales de Castille a Ia veille des
Finer, Samuel E. "State-building. State Boundaries, and Border Control. Social temps modernes:' AnnDlts Eronomies. Soci8b, Civilisations 25 (19'10): 775--88.
Sdmct In{ormgtUm 13 (1974): 79-126. .. " Lane, Frederic C. "Force and Enterprise in the Creation of Oceanic Commerce." In
"State- and Nation-Building in Europe: The Role of the Military. In .Tht For- Tht TtJsks of Economic History (Supplemental issue of the Journal of ELXmOmic His-
mation of NatioMI StattS in Western EurDpt, edited by Charles Tilly. Pnnceton, tory 10 (1950)), pp. 19-31.
N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1975. . "Economic Consequences of Organized Violence." TournaI of Economic History
Fueter, Edward. GtS€hichtt dts turopaiS€htn SlaattnsysttnlS von 1492-1559. MUnich: 18 (1958): 4OJ-17.
Oldenbourg. 1919. . 'The Economic Meaning of War and Protection." In Vmict' lind History: Tht
Gerhard, Dietrich. Old Europt: A Study of Conlinufty, 1000-J8OO. New York: Aca- O:Hltdtd Pllpas of Fmftrii: C. Lmt. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University
demic Press, 1981. Press, 1966; originally 1942.
Gooch. John, Armies in Europt. London: Routledge &; Kegan Pa,ul, 1980. . ''The Role of Government in Economic Growth in Early Modem Ttmes." Jour-
Guenee. Bemard. "Y a-t-i1 un Etat des XIVe et XVe si~des?' AnnDles Ecor!omltS, tuJl of Eanwmic History 35 (1975): 8-17; with comment by Douglass C. North
SodtftS. Civilislltions 36 (1981): 399-406. and Robert Paul Thomas, pp. 18-19.
Guery, Alain. "Les finances de la monarchie (rancaise sous rAnden Regime. An- Levi, Margaret. 'The Predatory Theory of Rule." In Tht Microfoundations of MIlrn>-
rralts £amomits, Sociitb, Civilisillions 33 (1978). 216-39. sociology, edited by Michael Hechter. Philadelphia: Temple University Press,
Hale, J. R. "Armies, Navies, and the Art of War:' In Tht NnD Olmbridgr M~"" 1983.
History, vol. 2, Tht Rtformation 1520-J559, edited by G. R. Elton. Cambndge: Ludtke, AU. "Genesis und Durchsetzung des modernen Staates: Zur Analyse von
Cambridge University Press, 1968. . ' HelTSChaft und Verwaltung." Archiv fur SozialgtsChichtt 20 (1980): 470-91.
"Armies Navies and the Art of War" (sic). In Tht Ntw Cllmbrrdgt Modtrn Hrs- Lyons, G. M. "Exigences militaires et budgets milit"ires aux U.S.A." Rtvut Frlln-
lory. vol: 3, Tht Counter-RtformJltion and Prict RnroIution, 1559-J61O, edited by aJist de Sociologie 2 (1961): 66-74.
R. B. Wernham. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1968. " Mathias, Peter. '7axation and Industrialization in Britain, 1700-1870." In Tht
Hamilton, Earl J. "Origin and Growth of the N"lional Debt in France and England. Transformation of England: £ssays in tM Economic and 50cUJf History of England in
In S'udi in onore di Gino uW/to, vol. 2. Milan: Giuffre, 1950. tht £ightttnth Ctntury, edited by Peter Mathias. New York.: Oxford University
Harding. Robert R. A1Jlllomy of a Puwtr Elite: 1lrt Provincial Govtrnors of f.IIrly Modnn Press. 1979.
Frana. New Haven. Conn.: Yale University Press. 19'78. Michaud, Claude. "Finan~ et guerres de religion en France." ~ trHistoirt
Hechter, Michael, and William Brustein. "Regional Modes of Production ~nd Pat- Mcdmtttl Conttmporai~28(1981): 572-96.
terns of State Fonnalion in Western Europe." Ammo," Journal of Sociology 85 Modelsld, George. 'The Long Cycle of Global Politics and the Nation-Slate." Com-
(1980): 1061-94. . parative Sludits in Soddy and History 20 (1978): 214-35.
Hintze, Otto. SllIlIt lind Verfassung: Gtsammtltt Abhandlungtn zur allgrmtlntn Vtrfas- Nef, John U. WtJr and Humlln ProgrtSS: An Essay on 1M RiM of Industrial CivililJltion.
sungsgtsChichlt. Edited by Gerhard Oestreich. Gottingen:Vandenhoeck &; Ru- Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1952.
precht, 1962; originally 1910. . . Industry and Gototmmmt in Franctand England, J540-J640.lthaca. N.Y.: Cornell
Howard, Michael. War in European History. Oxford: Oxford University Press. 1976. University Press. 1965; originally 1940.
James, M. E. Changt and Continuity in t~ Tudor North: Tilt RiM of Thomas First Lcrd North, Douglass C. and Robert Paul Thomas. The Rise of t~ WtS'trn World: A NnD
Wharton. Borthwick Papers no. ZJ. York: SI. Anthony's Press, 1965. Economic History. Cimbridge: Cambridgt' Univt'r'lIity rress. 1973.
'The First Earl of Cumberland (1493--1542) and the Decline of Northern Feu- O'Donnell. Guillermo. "Compuatiw Iti.stvr;":il fUJnUlIKMUl uf the Stlte Ap~ratu'
dalism." Northtrn History 1 (1966): 43--69.
190 Charles TIlly War Making and State Making as Organized Crime 19J
and Socio-economic Change in the Third World." Intn'lflltiolflll 5«:i41 SdClU Wijn,~. W. "Military Forces. and Wa~are 1610-48:' In Tht Nnu Clmbridgt Modern
IOllmal32 (1980): 717-29. HiSlory. vol. 4, Tht Dtc~'"t of Splin and tltt Thirty YtQrs War 1609-58159, edited
Parker. Geoffrey. Tht Army of fumdm tmd tltt spltnish RDad J567-J659. Cambridge: . .by J. P. Coo~r. Can.'bndge: Cambridge University Press, 1970.
Cambridge University Press, 1972. Wi.lliam~, Pe~. .Rebeillon and Revolution in Early Modem England." In War and
Peacock, Alan T., and Jack Wiseman. T1rt Growth of Public E:cpmdituft in 11ft Uniltd ~: HlStoneal £ssoys in Honollr and Mnnory of/. R. Wtsttrn, 1928-J9n ed"
Kingdom. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Prt>SS, 1961. lted by M. R. D. Foot. London: E1ek Books, 1973. '
Poggi, Gianfranco. T1rt Dtvtlopmnrt of 1M MJNUm slalt: A Sociologiad lnlrodlldiml. Wolfe, ~artinp' . 1M Fisal systnn of Rmaissana Frana. New Haven, Conn' YaJe Uni.
Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press. 1978. verslty ress, 1972. ..
Polisensky, Josef V. Wllr IlrulSoridy in Ellropt, J6J8-1648. Cambridge: Cambridge Zolberg. Aristide R. "Strategic Interactions and the Formation of Modem States:
University Press, 1978. France and England." IllttrnQtional5«:i41 Sdtna JOllrnal32 (1980): 687-716.
Pounds, Norman J. G., and Sue Simons Ball. "Core"Areas and the Development of
the European States System:' AmUlls of tlit !\ssoriQtion of Amtriam Gtographm
54 (1964): 24--40.
Ramsey, G. D. Tht City of london in lnttrnQtional Po/ilics III tlit ACC'tSSion of Eliznbeth
Tudor. Manchester: Manchester University Press, 1975.
Redlich, Fritz. Tht Gtnnan Military EnltrpriSt'r and His Work fora. 2 vols. Wiesbaden:
Steiner, 1964-65. Vitrttljahrschrift fUr Sozial· und Wirtschaftsgtsehichtt, Beiheften
47,48.
Riemersma, Jelle C. "Govemmentlnfluence on Company Organization in Holland
and England (1550-1650)." Tht Tasks of Eronomic History (Supplemental issue
of the Journal of Eronomic History 10 (1950)), pp. 31-39.
Romano, Salvatore Francesco. Storia dtlla mafia. Milan: Sugar, 1963.
Rosenberg. Hans. BUmlurnacy, Aristocnrqt and Autocnrcy: Tnt Prussian Exptrima, J660-
J8J5. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1958.
Russett, Bruce M. Wlu!t Price Vigilanct? Tht Burdtns of National r:Jtfrnst. New Haven,
Conn.: Yale University Press, 1970.
Schelling. Thomas C. "Economics and Criminal Enterprise:' Tht l'Jlblic lnltrtsl 7
(1967): 6J-78.
Steensgaard, Niels. Tht Asidn TnuJt Rtvolution of tM StvcItnnth Ct'nIUry: Tht &1st
India Compltnies and tilt Dtdint of tM QlrllVlln Trtldts. Chicago: University of Chi-
cago Press, J974.
Stein, Arthur A., and Bruce M. Russett. "Evaluating War: Outcomes and Co~
quences." In Handbook of PoIitiall Conflict: 1'Mory lind lUstardl. edited by Ted
Robert GUrT. New York: Free Press, 1980.
Stinchrombe, Arthur L Construding 5«:i4/ 'TMorUs. New York: Harcourt, Brace &:
World, J968.
Stone, Lawrence. "State Control in Sixteenth--Cenlury England:' Economic History
RnJitw 17 (1947): 103-20.
Tht Crisis oftlit Aristocracy, J558-J641. Oxford: Oarendon Press, 1%5.
Tenenti, Alberto. Piracy and lltt Dtclint of Vtniu, 1580-J6J5. Berkeley: University of
California Press, J967.
Torsvik, Per, ed. MobiliU/tion, Ctnttr·Ptriphery strudures and Nation-Building: A Vol·
umt ill Commemoration of slein Rollin. Bergen: Universitetsforlaget, 1981.
de Vries, Jan. "On the Modernity of the Dutch Republic." lournal of Economic History
33 (1973):·J91-202.
Tht Eamomy of Europe in an Agt of Crisis, J6OO-J750. Cambridge: Cambridftt·
University Press, 1976.
"Barges and Capitalism: Passenger Transportation in the Dutch Economy, 1632-
1839," A.A.G. Blfdraxtlt 21 (1978): 33-398.

You might also like