You are on page 1of 20

Strat.

Change 19: 9–28 (2010)


Published online in Wiley Interscience
(interscience.wiley.com) DOI: 10.1002/jsc.855 RESEARCH ARTICLE

The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty


Years and Its Relation to Entrepreneurial Finance1
Ciarán mac an Bhaird
Dublin City University, Ireland

Many studies emphasize the


significance of two theoretical
approaches based on
E mpirical evidence suggests that cost-based considerations, firm-
specific characteristics, and owner-specific factors — such as desire
for control and managerial independence — are important determinants of
information asymmetry and capital structures of entrepreneurial firms.
agency theory. Empirical
evidence suggests that Keywords: capital structure, entrepreneurial finance, agency theory, information
financial capital structures of asymmetry, financial life cycle, profitability, collateral, firm characteristics,
entrepreneurial firms are owner preferences
determined by cost-based
considerations, firm-specific Introduction
characteristics, and owner- Most research on capital structure has focussed on public nonfinancial
specific factors, such as
corporations with access to U.S. or international capital markets . . . Yet even
desire for control and
40 years after the Modigliani and Miller research, our understanding of firms’
managerial independence.
financing choices is limited
Whilst firm owner
(Myers, 2001: 82)
preferences are paramount in
determining capital structure, Early studies of small venture financing frequently remarked that it was a ‘much
the common underlying factor ignored’ subject of research (Zignales, 2000). A belated realization of the significant
in accessing external finance economic contribution of SMEs has resulted in increased attention focused on the
is the alleviation of sector from policy-makers and academics. The earliest studies investigating SME
information asymmetries,
financing predominantly comprised government-sponsored surveys and reports,
which is relatively easier for
concentrating largely on potential deficiencies and obstacles to the sustainability and
firms with a high level of fixed
assets accessing debt development of the sector. These reports repeatedly addressed the provision of
markets. finance, and were instrumental in shaping and influencing policy. Academic research
on SME financing is a relatively more recent topic of investigation, and articles that
first emerged were largely descriptive, primarily considering differences between
SMEs and large firms (Walker and Petty, 1978; Bates and Hally, 1982; Ang, 1991).
These papers described general differences between small and large firms, including
ownership and management structures, financing, and access to capital markets, and
were not concerned with theory generation or theory testing per se. Subsequent
studies addressed this deficiency, employing theories developed in corporate finance
1
JEL classification codes: G32, G35.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


Strategic Change: Briefings in Entrepreneurial Finance DOI: 10.1002/jsc.855
10 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

as the basis for empirical studies of small venture financing vious research is then presented, categorized by two
(Daskalakis and Psillaki, 2008; Heyman et al., 2008; Mac approaches: the ‘firm characteristic’ approach and the
an Bhaird and Lucey, 2010). Results from these studies ‘owner characteristic’ approach. Practical implications of
confirm the relevance of capital structure theories for SME previous conceptual and empirical studies are then pro-
financing, albeit employing a different rationale than their posed. The paper concludes with a brief synopsis of results
corporate finance counterparts. of previous studies.
Expansion in research activity on the subject in the
past two decades has resulted in a burgeoning corpus of The trade-off theory and SME financing
material. Emerging initially from the UK (Chittenden Capital structure theory originates in the irrelevance prop-
et al., 1996) and the USA (Balakrishnan and Fox, 1993), ositions of Modigliani and Miller (1958) (often referred to
studies have also been conducted in Portugal (Esperanca as the ‘seminal’ work of Modigliani and Miller). In examin-
et al., 2003), Belgium (Manigart and Struyf, 1997; ing the effect of capital structure on the cost of capital, and
Heyman et al., 2008), Spain (Sogorb Mira, 2005; Garcia- therefore the market value of the firm, Modigliani and
Teruel and Martinez-Solano, 2007), Italy (Giudici and Miller (1958) demonstrate that under a number of assump-
Paleari, 2000), Sweden (Cressy and Olofsson, 1997; Berg- tions the source of financing employed has no effect on
gren et al., 2000), Taiwan (Fu et al., 2002), India (Ghosh, firm value. Modigliani and Miller conclude that firm value
2007), Germany (Audretsch and Elston, 1997; Elsas and is determined by the profitability and riskiness of its real
Krahnen, 1998), Australia (Cassar and Holmes, 2003; assets, and not by its capital structure. These propositions
Fitzsimmons and Douglas, 2006), Greece (Daskalakis and were based on a number of unrealistic assumptions, most
Psillaki, 2008), and Ireland (Mac an Bhaird and Lucey, notably the absence of corporate taxes, which Modigliani
2010). In light of the significant body of accumulated and Miller introduced into the model in 1963. Within the
research, it seems timely to analyze and evaluate previous tax system, interest payments on debt are allowable against
studies and consider the state-of-the-art of the literature. corporate tax, and so a firm with debt faces a lower corpo-
This paper is organized around theoretical perspec- rate tax bill than a similar all-equity financed firm ceteris
tives of firm financing, commencing with the origin of paribus. There is, however, a trade-off between the tax
capital structure theory; the irrelevance propositions of benefits of debt and potential costs of financial distress. A
Modigliani and Miller (1958). The objectives of this paper theoretical optimum is reached when the present value of
are threefold: to evaluate the relevance of capital structure tax savings due to further borrowing is just offset by
theories to SME financing; to synthesize and summarize increases in the present value of costs of distress. In accor-
empirical studies on the subject; and to present a number dance with the trade-off theory, firms have an optimal debt
of practical implications of previous conceptual and ratio which they attempt to maintain.
empirical studies. This paper examines universal theoreti- Applicability of the trade-off theory to the SME sector
cal concepts that are relevant to all SMEs, such as agency has been the focus of a number of studies (Heyman et al.,
and information asymmetries, and focuses on the SME 2008; López-Gracia and Sogorb Mira, 2008), although
financing literature. (A comprehensive overview of the the debt tax shield is as relevant for SMEs as it is
venture capital literature is provided by Wright and for publicly quoted firms. This is explained by consider-
Robbie, 1998 and Landstrom, 2008.) The paper proceeds ation of two factors central to trade-off theory: profit-
as follows: fundamental issues pertaining to SME financ- ability and financial distress. Research indicates that
ing are explained by outlining the relevance of theoretical smaller firms are not as profitable as larger firms (Pettit
propositions to the subject. Empirical evidence from pre- and Singer, 1985; Vos and Forlong, 1996; Michaelas

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 11

et al., 1999), and thus have less use for debt tax shields personal finances with the financing of the firm (Ang,
ceteris paribus. Additionally, Day et al. (1983) argue that 1992; Avery et al., 1998). Adverse effects of bankruptcy
the tax shield is less valuable to small firms as they are may thus have implications for the personal affairs of the
generally less capital-intensive. This is because smaller owner, particularly in firms with unlimited liability. In
firms adapt flexible production technologies in order to this case, ‘. . . consequences of business bankruptcy very
compete with larger companies operating with lower often leads to personal bankruptcy, and the impact of
average costs, maintaining an ability to respond swiftly to provisions for the transfer of management and ownership
changes in demand (Mills and Schumann, 1985). This to succeeding generations in a family enterprise’
relatively lower capital expenditure means that the debt (McMahon et al., 1993: 77). An additional onerous
tax shield is of lesser value to smaller firms. burden is the considerable negative effects on the owner’s
A second component of the trade-off theory is risk of reputation and self-esteem (Vos and Forlong, 1996).
financial distress. The ultimate consequence of financial Empirical evidence for the effect of bankruptcy costs in
distress is bankruptcy, and it is well established in the SMEs is inconclusive; Michaelas et al. (1999) state that
literature that ‘. . . young firms are more failure prone bankruptcy costs are not significant enough to prove a
than older ones’ (Cressy, 2006b: 103). Higher bankruptcy negative relationship between risk and gearing, although
rates in younger firms are indicative of the relatively higher Esperanca et al. (2003) find that bankruptcy costs are a
business risk that smaller firms face, which is attributed significant determinant of debt ratios. A caveat of these
to a number of factors. Firstly, smaller businesses may be studies is use of the coefficient of variation in profitability
overly dependent on a small number of customers (Hudson as a proxy for economic risk. This measure does not
et al., 2001). This is exacerbated by dependence of many encompass all aspects of risk for the SME owner, particu-
SMEs on a single product or service (Cambridge Small larly the proportion of personal wealth invested in the
Business Research Centre, 1992). These firms are particu- firm.
larly vulnerable to financial distress, as loss of their prin- Results of previous studies indicate that debt tax
cipal customer(s) would severely affect their chances of shields are not a first-order concern for firms opting for
survival. Secondly, nascent and early-stage firms are vul- debt finance. Jordan et al. (1998) and Sogorb Mira (2005)
nerable to problems of undercapitalization. This is aggra- report a relationship contrary to predictions of trade-off
vated by reduced access to external finance due to theory. This is explained by the effect of the amount of
information opacity, and lack of a trading history. Thirdly, tax paid on retained earnings, and consequently on the
smaller firms are exposed to economic shocks and adverse level of debt employed. Studies by Michaelas et al. (1999)
macroeconomic conditions, which are intensified by the and Bartholdy and Mateus (2008) find that tax rates do
absence of hedging instruments in their ‘financial portfo- not significantly influence the level of debt in SMEs. Col-
lio.’ Poorly diversified undercapitalized firms are particu- lective evidence suggests that firm owners are more con-
larly vulnerable under adverse macroeconomic cerned with the potential negative effects of assuming
conditions. more debt than the tax shield it confers.
The heightened business risk faced by younger, smaller
firms indicates a lower threshold of financial distress and
bankruptcy costs. The impact of bankruptcy costs for the Asymmetric information and signaling
SME owner has farther-reaching and more severe personal theories and SME financing
effects than in the case of a publicly owned company. This The Modigliani and Miller (1958) propositions were
is due to the well-documented integration of SME owners’ based on the assumption that corporate ‘insiders’ and

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
12 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

‘outside’ investors were privy to symmetric information. take advantage of this superior information to the detri-
An alternative approach to capital structure theory is ment of outsiders. This view emphasizes the lack of opacity
based on the assumption of asymmetry of information, in the small firm sector, which is exacerbated by the rela-
i.e. that firm managers or ‘insiders’ possess private infor- tively high cost of compiling information on individual
mation about the firm that ‘outside’ uninformed investors firms, the limited and fragmented market for this infor-
do not. Thus, managers may use financial policy decisions mation, and difficulties in signaling to financial markets.
to reveal information about firms’ revenue streams and Because of increased information opacity, investments are
risk. Myers (1984) and Myers and Majluf (1984) present funded primarily by inside equity, including the firm
a pecking order model based on two primary assumptions: owner’s funds, as he has superior information on the firm.
that a firm’s managers know more about revenue streams Small firm owners thus try to meet their finance needs
and investment opportunities than outside investors, and from a pecking order of: first, their ‘own’ money (personal
that managers act in the interests of existing shareholders. savings and retained earnings); second, short-term bor-
Therefore, announcement of an equity issue to new inves- rowings; third, longer-term debt; and, least preferred of
tors will be viewed as a ‘bad’ signal, as investors perceive all, from the introduction of new equity investors (Cosh
that managers will only issue stock if they believe it to be and Hughes, 1994). Firms’ debt ratios comprise the
overvalued by the market. Underinvestment can be cumulative need for external finance over time (Myers,
avoided by funding investment projects with internal 1984; Myers and Majluf, 1984), and reflect variations in
funds. When internal funds are exhausted, debt is pre- factors such as initial capitalization, asset structure, profit-
ferred to external equity as it is less susceptible to under- ability, and rates of reinvestment. Garmaise (2001) states
valuation due to information asymmetries. When internal that this view of information asymmetries is more appro-
cash flow and safe debt are exhausted, the firm issues risky priate for established firms.
debt or convertibles before common stock (Myers, 1984). Numerous studies report SME financing patterns
There are two contrasting views in the literature on consistent with the pecking order theory, including Chit-
the source of information asymmetries in SME finance tenden et al. (1996), Hall et al. (2004), Voulgaris et al.
markets. One school of thought contends that external (2004), Baeyens and Manigart (2005), Gregory et al.
suppliers of finance have superior information on the (2005), Johnsen and McMahon (2005), Sogorb Mira
value of a firm’s investment projects and prospects for (2005), Ou and Haynes (2006), Daskalakis and Psillaki
survival, and therefore the SME bears the cost of informa- (2008), and Mac an Bhaird and Lucey (2010). These
tion asymmetries (Garmaise, 2001). This view is sup- studies emphasize that firms rely on internal equity and
ported by studies detailing the entrepreneur’s excessive external borrowing to finance operations and growth, and
optimism about business prospects (Cooper et al., 1988), only a very small number of firms employ external equity.
and the high non-survival rate among new firms Certain firms operate under a constrained pecking order,
(Audretsch, 1991; Cressy, 2006b). Additionally, survival and do not even consider raising external equity (Holmes
rates among bank-financed firms are higher than those and Kent, 1991; Howorth, 2001). Other studies indicate
among owner-financed firms (Reid, 1991), indicating that that the financing preferences of SMEs adhere to a modi-
financial institutions are more skilled than insiders in fied pecking order, such as the High Technology Pecking
appraising a firm’s chances of survival, particularly in Order Hypothesis (HTPOH) (Oakey, 1984; Brierley,
nascent and start-up firms. 2001; Hogan and Hutson, 2005). This theory propounds
The contrasting view is that insiders have greater that firms with a particular profile (high-technology firms
knowledge about a firm’s investment projects, and may with potential for high growth rates) prefer to finance

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 13

investment from internal equity, followed by external An alternative approach to explaining the apparent
equity, and finally debt, and is supported by empirical adherence of SMEs to the pecking order theory concerns
evidence. In seeking to explain the apparent adherence of preferences of the firm owner, or demand-side issues. One
firms in the SME sector to the pecking order theory, the reason for the observed hierarchy in financing patterns is
primary question is whether it is imposed by supply-side the relatively higher cost of external equity for smaller
factors, or if it is due to demand-side choices. firms. The process of raising capital through an Initial
One of the most frequently examined issues in SME Public Offering of common stock (IPO) is more expensive
financing addresses the supply of finance to the sector, and per share for SMEs due to the fixed costs of due diligence,
enquires whether there is a financing gap. Holmes and distribution, and securities registration (Berger and Udell,
Kent (1991) describe the financing gap as having two 1998). Despite the reduced cost and lesser diligence
components: a knowledge gap, whereby the firm owner requirements of obtaining a listing on markets specifically
has limited awareness of the appropriate sources of finance oriented towards smaller firms, such as the Alternative
and the relative advantages and disadvantages of each Investment Market (AIM), it remains a very costly process.
source; and a supply gap, whereby funds are either unavail- Additionally, empirical evidence suggests that the effect of
able to small firms, or the cost of debt to small firms underpricing is significantly more severe for smaller firms
exceeds the cost of debt to large firms. Authors in the field (Buckland and Davis, 1990; Ibbotson et al., 2001). Whilst
of economics and SME finance have concentrated on the the combination of these costs is an impediment to stock
latter, with two polarized views emerging. Stiglitz and market flotation, perhaps the greatest disincentive is the
Weiss (1981) present a model of credit rationing in resultant loss of control due to wider equity ownership.
markets with imperfect information in which ‘good’ proj- The latter factor, along with the interrelated issue of
ects are denied funding because of credit rationing. This managerial independence, is commonly cited as the
is viewed as an underinvestment problem, where equity primary reason for adherence of SMEs to the pecking
clears the market. The opposing theory of De Meza and order theory (Bolton, 1971; Chittenden et al., 1996;
Webb (1987, 2000) proposes that inability to discover risk Jordan et al., 1998). In some cases, desire for indepen-
characteristics of borrowers results in socially excessive dence is so great that SME owners eschew growth oppor-
levels of lending. Thus, the pooling of ‘good’ projects with tunities rather than relinquish control (Cressy and
‘poor’ projects results in a lower interest rate charged to Olofsson, 1997; Michaelas et al., 1998). This also applies
‘poor’ projects and credit rationing of ‘good’ projects. The to debt financing; Cressy (2006a) argues that the psycho-
central issue concerns market efficiency. Many papers logical costs of borrowing outweigh the benefits, as the
empirically investigate the subject of a financing con- small firm owner dislikes interference from debt provid-
straint in SMEs, both supporting (Fazzari et al., 1988, ers. In Cressy’s (2006a) model, as firms get larger and less
2000) and refuting (Levenson and Willard, 2000) the personal, aversion to bank interference diminishes,
phenomenon. Intervention to alleviate funding gaps due whereas in micro firms control aversion restricts the
to market inefficiencies, if they exist, or if intervention is amount borrowed. Desire to retain control and maintain
the proper response, is a question that has been compre- managerial independence varies with ownership structure
hensively discussed by academics, policy-makers, and and firm profile. Previous studies have shown that desire
practitioners. Although evidence for a persistent equity for control is greater in family firms, primarily for reasons
gap is inconclusive, Cressy (2002) opines that govern- of intergenerational transfer (Poutziouris, 2002; López-
ments across the globe will continue to intervene in SME Gracia and Sanchez-Andujar, 2007). The aspiration of
capital markets because of political considerations. retaining control may not be constant over the life cycle

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
14 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

of the firm, however, and may change for reasons such as Letterie, 2008). These studies report that the amount of
change of lifestyle or lack of a successor, for example. equity invested by the firm owner in a venture is a signal
Fitzsimmons and Douglas (2006: 79) state that ‘. . . there of the owner’s belief that the venture will succeed, and
may come a point where the stress and responsibility of reduces the likelihood of incurring increased risk ex
decision making, coupled with the entrepreneur’s realisa- post, as:
tion that he/she lacks critical market, industry or manage-
ment information, causes the entrepreneur to switch from Willingness to put your own money into a venture is a
autonomy preference to autonomy aversion.’ Further pretty effective test of its worth and a high personal
studies report that reluctance to employ external equity stake is a powerful incentive to good stewardship
from new investors is dependent on sector, finding that (Black et al., 1996: 73)
owners of firms in the high-technology sector are willing
to cede control in return for equity capital (Hogan and
Hutson, 2005). Moreover, willingness to employ external Agency theory and SME financing
equity may be contingent on added capabilities of the Integrating theories of finance, agency, and property
equity provider. For example, firm owners are willing to rights, Jensen and Meckling (1976) outline a nexus of
employ external equity from new investors in return for relationships in publicly listed companies which could be
managerial input and non-financial competencies (Giudici characterized as principal–agent relationships. Firms’
and Paleari, 2000; De Bettignies and Brander, 2007). security holders (debtholders and equityholders) are seen
Researchers in the corporate finance literature propose as principals, and firms’ management as agent, managing
that firms overcome potential information asymmetry the principals’ assets. The principal–agent relation may be
problems by signaling to the financial markets through costly, because if both are utility maximizers ‘. . . there is
issuing debt or equity. Notwithstanding fundamental dif- a possibility that the agent will not always conduct busi-
ferences in the nature of public and private debt and ness in a way that is consistent with the best interest of
equity markets, researchers assert that SMEs overcome the principals’ (Jensen and Meckling, 1976: 308). Con-
information opacity by signaling to funders. Bester (1985) flicts between debtholders and equityholders arise because
and Besanko and Thakor (1987) state that provision of of the uneven nature of payoffs in debt contracts. Once
personal assets by the firm owner as collateral for business debtholders have advanced capital to equityholders, the
loans may be interpreted as having a signaling function. latter have an incentive to take on riskier projects than
Conversely, Coco (2000) and Manove et al. (2001) state intended by the debtholders, an effect known as the ‘asset
that collateral is used by financial institutions to protect substitution effect.’
against credit exposure, rather than as a signaling mecha- The effect of agency costs is more pronounced if busi-
nism. This view is supported by Hanley and Crook (2005: nesses are small because information asymmetries are
417), finding that ‘. . . the “menu approach” that under- greater (Hand et al., 1982). Unique characteristics of
pins signalling models as lacking in realism.’ SMEs increase the potential for agency costs, including
This evidence does not completely reject the role of ‘alternative organisational forms, absence of publicly
signaling in SME financing, however. A number of studies traded shares, risk taking tendency of entrepreneurs,
find that funders’ willingness to provide finance to SMEs limited personal wealth of firm owners and shortened
is positively related to the financial commitment of the expected duration for the firm’ (Ang, 1991: 4), ‘conflicts
firm owner to the venture, particularly the amount of in perception regarding the intentions of the entrepreneur,
personal finance invested (Storey, 1994a; Blumberg and the heightened probability of failure, and credibility of

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 15

commitments and signals made by owners with limited Hyytinen and Vaananen, 2006). A demand-side conse-
wealth holdings’ (Keasey and Watson, 1993: 41). Agency quence of adverse selection is that borrowers may be reluc-
costs are not constant across all firms; potential agency tant to apply for loans in the belief that their application
costs increase with intangibility of assets, as growth options will be rejected (Kon and Storey, 2003).
increase and asset specificity rises (Gompers, 1995). Fur- Debt providers seek to minimize potential agency
thermore, incentives and opportunities for the owner- costs arising from moral hazard by employing a number
manager to gamble with outside investors’ claims are of lending techniques. Baas and Schrooten (2006) propose
greatly enhanced when the firm becomes financially dis- a classification of four methods: asset-based lending,
tressed (Keasey and Watson, 1993). financial statement lending, small business credit scoring
Application of agency theory to the SME sector (transactions-based or ‘hard’ techniques), and relationship
focuses on the relationship between firm owners and sup- lending (a ‘soft’ technique). Lending to SMEs by financial
pliers of external capital. Suppliers of private equity seek institutions is frequently ‘collateral-based’ (Kon and
to minimize agency costs by employing a number of tech- Storey, 2003: 45), and firms report that lack of security
niques at frequent stages in the investment process. At the offered is the primary reason cited for refusal of a term
outset, venture capitalists conduct extensive due diligence loan (Basu and Parker, 2001; Ayadi, 2008). Empirical
(Manigart et al., 1997). Throughout the investment evidence from a number of countries indicates the perva-
process further control mechanisms are employed, includ- siveness in use of asset-based techniques to advance debt.
ing: use of convertible securities, syndication of invest- For example, Black et al. (1996) find that the ratio of loan
ment, and staging capital investment (Gompers, 1995), size to collateral exceeds unity for 85% of small business
which is the most effective mechanism a venture capitalist loans in the UK, and Berger and Udell (1990) report that
can employ (Sahlman, 1990). Shorter duration between over 70% of all loans to SMEs are collateralized. Provision
funding rounds increases the effectiveness in monitoring of collateral fulfills a number of roles for financial institu-
the firm. Intensity of monitoring is negatively related to tions: it provides an asset for the bank in the event of
expected agency costs, and the venture capitalist always project failure (Bartholdy and Mateus, 2008); it provides
retains the ultimate answer to agency problems: ‘. . . aban- an incentive for commitment to the entrepreneur and
donment of the project’ (Gompers, 1995: 1462). attenuates moral hazard (Boot et al., 1991); it provides a
Whilst venture capital is an important source of signal to the bank that the entrepreneur believes the
finance for a limited number of SMEs, debt is by far the project will succeed (Storey, 1994a); it mitigates informa-
most commonly used source of external capital (Binks and tion asymmetries, and thus reduces credit rationing
Ennew, 1998; Cole, 2008). Potential agency costs are (Besanko and Thakor, 1987); it may also help in the
greater in the SME sector than in the corporate sector renegotiation of loans under financial distress (Gorton
(Vos and Forlong, 1996), partly because reliable informa- and Kahn, 2000). A unique feature of SME debt markets
tion on SMEs is rare and costly to obtain for financial is the personal commitment of the firm owner. Personal
intermediaries (Baas and Schrooten, 2006). Potential guarantees and provision of personal assets as collateral are
problems arising from agency relationships with debt pro- important for firms seeking to secure business loans (Ang
viders consist of moral hazard, and adverse selection. et al., 1995; Avery et al., 1998). These commitments are
Adverse selection arises at loan origination when providers akin to quasi-equity, but as they are not recorded in the
of debt have difficulty in discriminating between ‘good’ business financial statement, the owner’s contribution to
and ‘bad’ investment projects, resulting in financing con- the firm is underestimated (Ang, 1992). Pledging ‘outside’
straints for small businesses (Stiglitz and Weiss, 1981; collateral is even more effective in countering problems of

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
16 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

moral hazard, as the firm owner may place a greater value determinant in inducing a bank to extend a loan. Empiri-
on the asset than the market valuation. The borrower’s risk cal evidence suggests additional benefits of relationship
preference incentives are limited as the likelihood increases lending, including lower interest rates (Berger and Udell,
that he will feel the loss personally (Mann, 1997), even if 1995; Keasey and Watson, 2000), lower collateral require-
personal commitments represent ‘. . . only a small frac- ments (Elsas and Krahnen, 1998), access to increased
tion of the value of the loan’ (Berger and Udell, 1998: amounts of finance, and protection against credit crunches
639). An important aspect of the collateral-based lending (Berger and Udell, 1998). The importance of lending
technique is enforceability of the lender’s collateral claims relationships for provision of finance to the sector is
in the event of default, as the power of collateral ulti- emphasized by studies highlighting the destructive effects
mately depends on whether the priority rights of lenders on relationship lending of the consolidation of the banking
are upheld in bankruptcy (Berger and Udell, 2006). Prob- sector through mergers (Cole, 1998; Berger and Udell,
lems in enforcing collateral rights are more prevalent in 2002), making it too costly for banks to provide relation-
countries with underdeveloped financial infrastructures, ship-based services (Berger and Udell, 1998); and by
compelling SMEs to rely on leasing, supplier credit, and resultant changing practices within banks, such as making
development banks (Beck and Demirguc-Kunt, 2006). lending decisions centrally (Berger and Udell, 2006).
The greatest disadvantage of asset-based lending tech- Additional techniques employed by financial institu-
niques is that they do not fully overcome problems of tions to advance debt include financial statement lending
moral hazard and adverse selection, because not all firm and credit scoring. The former technique entails basing
owners have equal access to collateral (Storey, 1994b). the lending decision on financial statements of the firm,
This is especially true for high-technology start-ups and and is thus dependent on the strength of the balance sheet
capital-intensive projects where the loans required are and income statements of applicants (Baas and Schrooten,
typically large (Storey, 1994b; Ullah and Taylor, 2005). 2006). Credit scoring lending techniques augment data
Another disadvantage of this lending technique lies in the provided in financial statements with additional informa-
monitoring and legal costs (Chan and Kanatas, 1985), tion, such as the creditworthiness and financial history of
which may be passed on to SMEs in the form of higher the firm owner, to predict probability of repayment
lending charges. Because of these drawbacks, Baas and (Frame et al., 2001). The effectiveness of this technique is
Schrooten (2006) contend that the asset-based lending based on the quality of available data (Baas and Schroo-
technique is generally used as a substitute for relationship ten, 2006). These latter approaches require more analyti-
lending if the term of the relationship is short. cal skills and monitoring than asset-based lending
Relationship lending is based on ‘soft’ information approaches (Berger and Udell, 1998), and are more costly
generated by a bank’s experience with a lender through to administer. Berry et al. (2004: 118) conclude that the
‘continuous contact with the firm and the firm owner in approach adopted by lending institutions ‘. . . varies from
the provision of financial services’ (Berger and Udell, case to case’, and ultimately depends on the availability
1998: 645). As a firm becomes established and develops and cost of acquiring information.
a trading and credit history, reputation effects alleviate the Recent developments in recommendations on banking
problem of moral hazard (Diamond, 1989), facilitating laws and regulations issued by the Basel Committee on
borrowing capacity. Studies emphasize the importance of Banking Supervision (the Basel II Accord) may have
relationship lending in funding SMEs (Berger and Udell, implications for lending to the SME sector (Ayadi, 2008).
1995; Cole, 1998), and Hanley and Crook (2005) state The agreement proposes adoption of more risk-sensitive
that a pre-existing reputation is the single most important minimum capital requirements for banks. Financial

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 17

institutions may therefore assign more importance to the of financial life cycle models include studies by Fluck et
relative riskiness of borrowers, and will require more al. (1998) and Gregory et al. (2005). The former study
information than heretofore. This will place greater report- finds that, contrary to predictions of the financial growth
ing and disclosure requirements on SMEs, although ‘safer’ life cycle model, external sources of finance exceed inter-
firms may benefit from lower interest rates and greater nal sources for the youngest firms. Furthermore, Fluck et
access to loans. Smaller, riskier SMEs may face greater al. (1998) find that the contribution of the firm owner
difficulty in sourcing debt finance, higher interest rates, increases initially and then decreases in firms over 12 years
and greater collateral requirements (Tanaka, 2003). old. The initial increase in use of insider financing is
explained by firm owners employing retained earnings for
investment because of potential difficulties in raising
The financial growth life cycle approach external finance explained by the monopoly-lender theory
More recently, SME researchers have considered firm (Rajan, 1992). The subsequent decrease in use of internal
financing through a stage model or life cycle approach, sources is explained by older firms sourcing increasing
viewing development of the firm as a linear sequential amounts of external debt due to reputation effects
process through a number of stages. This approach origi- (Diamond, 1989). Results from a study by Gregory et al.
nates in economics literature (Penrose, 1952, 1959; (2005) partially support the model, although they con-
Rostow, 1960), and is commonly used to describe pro- clude that the financial growth life cycle cannot be encom-
gression of the successful firm through growth phases. passed in a ‘one size fits all’ universally applicable model.
Adopted by researchers in corporate finance, and pre-
sented as a descriptive concept in early textbooks (Weston
and Brigham, 1970), it outlines sources of finance typi- Empirical evidence of determinants
cally available at various growth stages of the firm, along of SME financing
with potential financing problems that may arise at each Previous empirical studies on SME financing can gener-
stage. Applying this model to SME financing, Berger and ally be categorized as ‘firm characteristic’ or ‘owner char-
Udell (1998) present firms on a size/age/information con- acteristic’ studies, depending on the level of analysis. A
tinuum, and describe the increasing array of financing number of studies employ a multi-level approach, com-
options available to the firm as it grows. Their financial bining firm and owner characteristics. These approaches
growth life cycle model incorporates changes in availabil- differ substantially with respect to the means of data col-
ity of information and collateral in describing sources of lection, methods of analysis employed, and presentation
finance available to firms over time. Berger and Udell of findings.
(1998) thus conceptualize the sequencing of funding over
the life cycle of the firm centered on information opacity ‘Firm characteristic’ studies
and following a financial pecking order. Smaller, more The majority of ‘firm characteristic’ studies adopt the
informationally opaque firms are depicted to the left side positivist approach applied in corporate finance, develop-
of the continuum, relying on ‘. . . initial insider finance, ing and testing multivariate regression models utilizing
trade credit, and/or angel finance’ (Berger and Udell, panel data (Daskalakis and Psillaki, 2008; Heyman et al.,
1998: 622). As firms advance along the continuum, they 2008; López-Gracia and Sogorb Mira, 2008). Data is
gain access to increased sources of external debt and generally sourced from secondary sources, such as the
equity. Ultimately, firms may access greater amounts of Dun and Bradstreet database (Hall et al., 2004). These
capital in public debt and equity markets. Empirical tests studies investigate the extent to which debt ratios are

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
18 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

determined by firm characteristics, commonly employing firms become increasingly reliant on retained profits. Fur-
short-term, long-term, and total debt ratios as dependent thermore, a number of researchers emphasize that the
variables (López-Gracia and Sogorb-Mira, 2008). Despite relationship between source of finance and age is more
being the most important source of investment finance complex, in particular that patterns of financing over time
for SMEs, studies employing internal equity as the depen- are not necessarily linear (Fluck et al., 1998). This consti-
dent variable are rare (Ou and Haynes, 2006; Mac an tutes a more sophisticated investigation of firm financing,
Bhaird and Lucey, 2010). ‘Firm characteristic’ studies are surmounting the assumption of linearity in financial
commonly representative of a broad range of sectors, and growth life cycle models.
sample sizes are typically large (Sogorb Mira, 2005). Not- Profitability: Coefficients for the relationship between
withstanding significant inter- and intra-industry differ- debt and profitability in previous studies are typically
ences, a number of consistent results have emerged. negative (Bartholdy and Mateus, 2008; Daskalakis and
Firm size: Results from previous studies indicate a Psillaki, 2008; Heyman et al., 2008), indicating that firms
positive relationship between long-term debt and size employ debt finance when retained profits are insufficient
(Daskalakis and Psillaki, 2008; Heyman et al., 2008; for investment requirements. These results are consistent
López-Gracia and Sogorb-Mira, 2008; Mac an Bhaird and with the pecking order theory, and emphasize the impor-
Lucey, 2010), which is consistent with the view that tance of profitability in financing the sector, as retained
smaller firms are offered, and employ, less long-term debt profits are the most important source of finance for SMEs
due to scale effects (Cassar and Holmes, 2003). This posi- (Ou and Haynes, 2006; Cole, 2008).
tive relationship may also be accounted for by collateral Asset structure: Empirical evidence from previous
effects, as the natural logarithm of total assets is com- studies indicates a positive relationship between use of
monly employed as a proxy variable for size. Firms with long-term debt and asset structure (Daskalakis and Psil-
a greater amount of collateralizable assets have capacity laki, 2008; Heyman et al., 2008; Mac an Bhaird and
for higher long-term debt ratios ceteris paribus, and tend Lucey, 2010), supporting the proposition that asset struc-
to match maturity of debt with that of assets (Bartholdy ture is the principal determinant of access to external
and Mateus, 2008). finance for SMEs (Bartholdy and Mateus, 2008). Results
In contrast, results from previous studies indicate a reveal a negative relationship between short-term debt and
negative relationship between use of short-term debt and fixed assets (Hall et al., 2004; Johnsen and McMahon,
size (Esperanca et al., 2003; Hall et al., 2004). This finding 2005; Sogorb Mira, 2005), suggesting that firms’ short-
is consistent with the view that smaller firms are heavily term debt is secured on other (short-term) collateral, or
reliant on short-term debt (Garcia-Teruel and Martinez- unsecured. These results suggest inter-industry differences
Solano, 2007), and may result from firms being unwilling in capital structures, as firms in industries typified by
or unable to employ long-term debt because of relatively greater levels of collateralizable assets have the capacity for,
higher transaction costs. and may employ, greater levels of debt than firms with a
Firm age: Empirical evidence from previous studies higher concentration of intangible assets (Brierley and
indicates that debt (both short-term and long-term) is Kearns, 2001). Indeed, intra-industry capital structures
negatively related with age (Bartholdy and Mateus, 2008; may be more comparable than inter-industry capital
López-Gracia and Sogorb-Mira, 2008; Mac an Bhaird and structures (Harris and Raviv, 1991). Empirical evidence
Lucey, 2010). This suggests a pattern of financing consis- of sectoral effects is mixed, with studies both supporting
tent with the pecking order theory, as firms become less (Michaelas et al., 1999; Hall et al., 2000) and failing to
reliant on external funding over time as debt is retired and support this hypothesis. Examples of the latter include

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 19

Balakrishnan and Fox (1993), who conclude that firm- to operating risk as measured by volatility in earnings
specific characteristics are more important than structural (Michaelas et al., 1999; Esperanca et al., 2003). This indi-
characteristics of industry, and Jordan et al. (1998), who cates that bankruptcy costs are not sufficiently large to
find that financial and strategy variables have greater deter risky SMEs from employing additional debt, par-
explanatory power than industry-specific effects. ticularly short-term debt. Furthermore, these results may
Growth: Consistent with the observation that high- indicate ‘distress’ borrowing, particularly in adverse mac-
growth firms typically have a large external financing roeconomic conditions (Jordan et al., 1998). A notable
requirement (Gompers and Lerner, 2003), results of pre- feature of these studies is the difficulty in calculating an
vious studies indicate a positive relationship between appropriate variable for bankruptcy costs.
growth and debt ratios (Sogorb Mira, 2005; Daskalakis In summary, empirical investigations of firm charac-
and Psillaki, 2008). Evidence suggests that the nature of teristic determinants of SME capital structures reveal a
funding for growth (short-term or long-term) is depen- number of consistent results; for example, positive rela-
dent on asset structure. Firms investing in firm-specific or tionships between debt finance and growth; and between
intangible assets are typically financed by external equity long-term debt and tangible assets; and negative relation-
(Brierley and Kearns, 2001). They have difficulty access- ships between debt finance and profitability; and between
ing long-term debt, and may resort to short-term debt as debt and firm age. There are also a number of conflicting
an alternative (Hall et al., 2000; Johnsen and McMahon, results, however, such as relationships between short-term
2005). debt and firm size, and short-term debt and tangible
Non-debt tax shields: Lack of empirical evidence assets. Notable features of previous studies are the lack of
indicating the relevance of tax advantages of debt may be statistical significance, and the low explanatory power of
partly explained by the significant negative relationships a number of models, especially in models employing
between debt and non-debt tax shields (Michaelas et al., short-term debt as a dependent variable. These shortcom-
1999; Sogorb Mira, 2005; López-Gracia and Sogorb- ings prompt researchers to seek further explanations for
Mira, 2008). Use of non-debt tax shields lessens the SME financing, employing alternative methodologies and
importance of the debt tax shield, and consequently the analysis techniques.
level of debt employed. By employing non-debt tax shields
such as investment credits or accelerated depreciation ‘Owner characteristic’ studies
costs, firms seek to avoid distress costs or other adjustment The influence of firm owners’ business goals, objectives,
costs which ‘. . . may be more important in particular and preferences on SME financing is understated, as wit-
instances’ (López-Gracia and Sogorb-Mira, 2008: 119). nessed by the relative paucity of published papers employ-
These results imply that firms with higher levels of tan- ing this approach. Variables examined in previous studies
gible assets can maintain higher levels of debt, supporting investigating the influence of ‘owner characteristics’ on a
the secured-debt view propounded by Smart et al. (2007) firm’s capital structure may be delineated by two
and Bartholdy and Mateus (2008). approaches: (1) a firm owner’s personal characteristics,
Operating risk: Given the importance of retained such as age, gender, race, education, and previous business
profits as a source of investment finance in SMEs (Cole, experience, and (2) a firm owner’s preferences, business
2008), it is hardly surprising that the coefficient of varia- goals, and motivations. Data for studies adopting these
tion in profitability is commonly used as a proxy for approaches are typically sourced from interviews and
operating risk. Results from previous studies indicate that postal questionnaires, and are commonly analyzed employ-
the level of debt employed by SMEs is positively related ing descriptive and non-parametric techniques. Sample

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
20 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

sizes are generally smaller than those in quantitative the firm owner is willing to invest in the venture (Bruns
studies employing panel data, resulting in limitations to and Fletcher, 2008). This is most important in the start-
the generalizability of results. up and nascent stages (Berger and Udell, 1998; Fluck
Personal characteristics investigated in ‘owner char- et al., 1998; Ullah and Taylor, 2007), when wealth con-
acteristic’ studies include race (Scherr et al., 1993; straints may contribute to the commonly experienced
Hussain and Matlay, 2007; Salazar, 2007), gender (Brush, problem of undercapitalization. Despite the importance
1992; Carter and Rosa, 1998; Boden and Nucci, 2000; of personal wealth of the firm owner to SME financing,
Coleman and Cohn, 2000), tertiary education (Cassar, empirical studies on the relative influence of this variable
2004), age (Romano et al., 2001), and years of business on the capital structure of SMEs are rare due to the sensi-
experience (Coleman and Cohn, 2000; Cassar, 2004), tive nature of the data.
amongst others. Whilst researchers generally do not find A further approach adopted in ‘owner characteristic’
significant empirical evidence supporting the proposition studies is to examine the influence of firm owners’ prefer-
that firm owners’ personal characteristics determine the ences, motivations, and business goals on firm financing.
source of financing employed (Cassar, 2004), a number These studies seek to explain SME capital structures with
of significant results have emerged. For example, Cha- reference to non-financial factors, including desire for
ganti et al. (1995) find that women are more likely to control, managerial independence, motivation for being
employ internal than external equity; Romano et al. in business, business goals, financial objective function,
(2001) discover that older business owners are less likely and propensity for risk (Jordan et al., 1998; Michaelas et
to employ external equity; Scherr et al. (1993) find that al., 1998; Romano et al., 2001). Evidence indicates that
owners’ age is negatively related with debt, and also that these factors may be more important than firm character-
more debt is obtained if the owner is married and less istic factors in explaining SME financing (Barton and
if he is black. Coleman and Cohn (2000) test if firm Matthews, 1989; Norton, 1990; Jordan et al., 1998),
owners’ age, education, years of experience, prior experi- particularly the desire to retain managerial control and
ence in a family-owned business, and gender influence independence. Furthermore, the primary financial objec-
the capital structure decision, and find education of the tive of small firm owners is maximization of net income
firm owner to be the sole significant variable. In summary, (LeCornu et al., 1996), which is consistent with the goal
although evidence suggests that personal characteristics of maintaining control of the firm.
of the firm owner may influence financing choice in
SMEs, the bulk of empirical evidence indicates that these
variables are not of primary importance (Carter and Conclusion
Rosa, 1998). Whilst authors have expressed the view that the Modigli-
Perhaps the single most important ‘owner character- ani–Miller theorem is empirically incorrect (Jensen, 1993)
istic’ variable directly related to SME financing is personal and perhaps unsuitable for application to the SME sector,
wealth of the firm owner. Personal wealth of the entrepre- empirical evidence indicates the importance of two theo-
neur influences the rate of business start-ups (Evans and retical approaches adopted from the corporate finance
Jovanovic, 1989; Fairlie, 1999), and its use is dependent literature: agency theory, and theories based on informa-
on the firm owner’s: (a) propensity for risk, (b) wealth tion asymmetries. Over half a century after the Modigli-
relative to the capital requirements of the firm, and (c) ani–Miller proposition, and following almost two decades
availability of external sources of finance. The latter may, of academic research on SME financing, a number of
in turn, be dependent on the amount of personal equity consistent results suggest the following conclusions:

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 21

1. SMEs are generally funded in a manner consistent there are a number of outstanding issues that are unre-
with the pecking order theory, i.e. in the order of: first, solved. (Whilst a number of scholars suggest that venture
internal funding (firm owner’s funds and retained capital rather than ‘financial aspects’ offer a more promis-
earnings); second, debt finance; third, external equity ing avenue of research (Blackburn, 2009), a number of
from new investors, which is the least desired form of issues are pertinent for all firms, regardless of the means
financing. The primary rationale for this preference is of financing employed.) A significant impediment to
the firm owner’s desire to retain control of the firm and researching these and other issues is the lack of compre-
maintain managerial independence. A second consid- hensive databases containing complete data. Databases,
eration is cost, as debt finance is generally less expen- such as exist, are either incomplete, or are not representa-
sive than external equity from new investors. tive of the total population. The paucity of comprehen-
2. SMEs applying for debt finance must typically satisfy sive, reliable data on small ventures will be exacerbated
funders’ requirements to overcome potential agency- with the introduction of the EU Administrative Burdens
related costs of moral hazard. Financial institutions Exercise, which is likely to reduce the availability of pub-
commonly employ asset-based lending techniques. lished accounting data in countries where such informa-
Although funders also employ alternative techniques, tion is presently readily available. This issue may be
such as relationship lending, and seeking personal overcome by employing methodologies such as question-
guarantees, firms that do not have access to lien-free naire and interview data collection. These methods facili-
collateralizable assets have greater difficulty in access- tate examination of issues such as the process of raising
ing debt finance ceteris paribus. finance and how it is influenced by factors such as past
3. Resourcing of SMEs generally follows a financial experience with financiers, pledging of personal guaran-
growth life cycle. This model incorporates elements of tees to secure debt finance, percentage of the firm owner’s
agency and information-asymmetry theories, and wealth invested in the firm, issues of succession in family
models financing across a life cycle continuum (Berger firms, and a number of other potentially important factors.
and Udell, 1998). Employing this approach, firm This approach also enables a more in-depth examination
financing generally follows the following trajectory. At of how incremental financing decisions of SME owners
start-up, access to finance is typically limited, and is change through successive developmental stages of the
largely dependent on the resources of the firm owner, firm, and facilitates development of more sophisticated
friends, and family. This includes equity and ‘quasi- financial growth life cycle models.
equity’, as debt finance for the firm is often secured on
the personal assets of the firm owner. As the firm grows
and matures, finance is increasingly sourced from References
retained profits, as reliance on the personal funds of Ang JS. 1991. Small business uniqueness and the theory of
the firm owner, friends, and family diminishes. As financial management. The Journal of Small Business Finance
firms progress along the later stages of the life cycle 1: 1–13.
continuum, increased amounts and sources of funding Ang JS. 1992. On the theory of finance for privately held firms.
are typically available. Progression along the life cycle The Journal of Small Business Finance 1: 185–203.
continuum is dependent on the firm owner’s growth
Ang JS, Wuh Lin J, Tyler F. 1995. Evidence on the lack of
objectives, and desire to retain control of the firm. separation between business and personal risks among small
Notwithstanding the significant increase in academic businesses. The Journal of Small Business Finance 4: 197–
research of SME financing over the past two decades, 210.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
22 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

Audretsch DB. 1991. New firm survival and the technological Berger AN, Udell GF. 1998. The economics of small business
regime. Review of Economics and Statistics 73: 441. finance: the roles of private equity and debt markets in the finan-
Audretsch DB, Elston JA. 1997. Financing the German Mit- cial growth cycle. Journal of Banking and Finance 22: 613–673.
telstand. Small Business Economics 9: 97–110. Berger AN, Udell GF. 2002. Small business credit availability
Avery RB, Bostic RW, Samolyk KA. 1998. The role of personal and relationship lending: the importance of bank organisa-
wealth in small business finance. Journal of Banking and tional structure. Economic Journal 112: F32–F53.
Finance 22: 1019–1061. Berger AN, Udell GF. 2006. A more complete conceptual
Ayadi R. 2008. SME financing in Europe: measures to improve framework for SME finance. Journal of Banking and Finance
the rating culture under the new banking rules. Paper pre- 30: 2945–2966.
sented at the Société Universitaire Européenne de Recherches Berggren B, Olofsson C, Silver L. 2000. Control aversion and
Financiéres, Palais du Luxembourg, Paris. the search for external financing in Swedish SMEs. Small Busi-
Baas T, Schrooten M. 2006. Relationship banking and SMEs: ness Economics 15: 233–242.
a theoretical analysis. Small Business Economics 27: 127– Berry A, Grant P, Jarvis R. 2004. European bank lending to the
137. UK SME sector. International Small Business Journal 22:
Baeyens K, Manigart S. 2005. Follow on financing of venture 115–130.
capital backed companies: the choice between debt, equity, Besanko D, Thakor AV. 1987. Collateral and rationing: sorting
existing and new investors. Working Paper 06/362, Faculty of equilibria in monopolistic and competitive credit markets.
Economics and Business Administration, Ghent University, International Economic Review 28: 671.
Belgium.
Bester H. 1985. Screening vs. rationing in credit markets with
Balakrishnan S, Fox I. 1993. Asset specificity, firm heterogeneity
imperfect information. American Economic Review 75:
and capital structure. Strategic Management Journal 14: 3–
850–855.
16.
Binks MR, Ennew CT. 1998. Private businesses and their
Bartholdy J, Mateus C. 2008. Financing of SMEs: an asset side
banks. Forum of Private Business Bank Survey 1998. University
story. Paper presented at the Société Universitaire Européenne
of Nottingham Business School.
de Recherches Financiéres, Palais du Luxembourg, Paris.
Black J, De Meza D, Jeffreys D. 1996. House prices, the supply
Barton SL, Matthews CH. 1989. Small firm financing: implica-
of collateral and the enterprise economy. The Economic Journal
tions from a strategic management perspective. Journal of
106: 60–75.
Small Business Management 1–7.
Basu A, Parker SC. 2001. Family finance and new business Blackburn R. 2009. Researching small firms and entrepreneur-
start-ups. Oxford Bulletin of Economics & Statistics 63: ship: trends and future challenges. Presentation to State Uni-
333–358. versity Higher School of Economics, Moscow.

Bates J, Hally DL. 1982. The Financing of Small Business. Sweet Blumberg BF, Letterie WA. 2008. Business starters and credit
and Maxwell: London. rationing. Small Business Economics 30: 187–200.

Beck T, Demirguc-Kunt A. 2006. Small and medium-size enter- Boden RJ, Nucci AR. 2000. On the survival prospects of men’s
prises: access to finance as a growth constraint. Journal of and women’s new business ventures. Journal of Business Ventur-
Banking & Finance 30: 2931–2943. ing 15: 347–362.

Berger AN, Udell GF. 1990. Collateral, loan quality, and bank Bolton CR. 1971. Report of the Committee of Inquiry on Small
risk. Journal of Monetary Economics 25: 21–42. Firms. London, Cmnd. 4811.

Berger AN, Udell GF. 1995. Relationship lending and lines of Boot AWA, Thakor AV, Udell GF. 1991. Secured lending and
credit in small firm finance. The Journal of Business 68: default risk: equilibrium analysis, policy implications and
351–381. empirical results. Economic Journal 101: 458.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 23

Brierley P. 2001. The Financing of Technology-based Small Firms: Cole RA. 2008. What do we know about the capital structure
A Review of the Literature. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, of privately held firms? Evidence from the surveys of small
Spring. business finances. Small Business Administration, Washing-
Brierley PG, Kearns A. 2001. The financing patterns of new ton, DC.
and old economy firms in the UK. Bank of England Discus- Coleman S, Cohn R. 2000. Small firms’ use of financial lever-
sion Paper. age: evidence from the 1993 National Survey of Small Busi-
Bruns V, Fletcher M. 2008. Banks’ risk assessment of Swedish ness Finances. Journal of Business and Entrepreneurship 12:
SMEs. Venture Capital 10: 171–194. 87–103.

Brush CG. 1992. Research on women business owners: past Cooper AC, Woo CY, Dunkelberg WC. 1988. Entrepreneurs’
trends, a new perspective and future directions. Entrepreneur- perceived chances for success. Journal of Business Venturing 3:
ship: Theory & Practice 16: 5–30. 97–108.

Buckland R, Davis EW. 1990. The pricing of new issues on the Cosh A, Hughes A. 1994. Size, financial structure and profit-
unlisted securities market: the influence of firm size in the ability: UK companies in the 1980s. In Hughes A, Storey DJ
context of the information content of new issue prospectuses. (eds), Finance and the Small Firm. Routledge: London.
The British Accounting Review 22: 207. Cressy R. 2002. Funding gaps: a symposium. The Economic
Cambridge Small Business Research Centre. 1992. The State of Journal 112: F1–F16.
British Enterprise. Department of Applied Economics, Univer-
Cressy R. 2006a. Determinants of small firm survival and
sity of Cambridge.
growth. In Casson M, Yeung B, Basu A, Wadeson N (eds),
Carter S, Rosa P. 1998. The financing of male- and female- The Oxford Handbook of Entrepreneurship. Oxford University
owned businesses. Entrepreneurship & Regional Development Press: Oxford.
10: 225–241.
Cressy R. 2006b. Why do most firms die young? Small Business
Cassar G. 2004. The financing of business start-ups. Journal of Economics 26(2): 103–116.
Business Venturing 19: 261–283.
Cressy R, Olofsson C. 1997. The financial conditions for
Cassar G, Holmes S. 2003. Capital structure and financing of Swedish SMEs: survey and research agenda. Small Business
SMEs: Australian evidence. Accounting and Finance 43: Economics 9: 179–194.
123–147.
Cruickshank D. 2000. Competition in UK Banking: A Report to
Chaganti R, Decarolis D, Deeds D. 1995. Predictors of capital the Chancellor of the Exchequer. HMSO: London.
structure in small ventures. Entrepreneurship Theory and Prac-
tice 20: 7–18. Daskalakis N, Psillaki M. 2008. Do country or firm factors
explain capital structure? Evidence from SMEs in France and
Chan Y-S, Kanatas G. 1985. Asymmetric valuations and the Greece. Applied Financial Economics 18: 87–97.
role of collateral in loan agreements. Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking 17: 84–95. Day TE, Stoll HR, Whaley RE. 1983. Taxes, Financial Policy
and Small Business. Lexington Books: Lexington, MA.
Chittenden F, Hall G, Hutchinson P. 1996. Small firm growth,
access to capital markets and financial structure: review of De Bettignies J-E, Brander JA. 2007. Financing entrepreneur-
issues and an empirical investigation. Small Business Economics ship: bank finance versus venture capital. Journal of Business
8: 56–67. Venturing 22: 808–832.

Coco G. 2000. On the use of collateral. Journal of Economic De Meza D, Webb DC. 1987. Too much investment: a problem
Surveys 14: 191. of asymmetric information. The Quarterly Journal of Economics
102: 281–292.
Cole RA. 1998. The importance of relationships to the avail-
ability of credit. Journal of Banking & Finance 22: 959– De Meza D, Webb DC. 2000. Does credit rationing imply insuf-
977. ficient lending? Journal of Public Economics 78: 215–234.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
24 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

Diamond DW. 1989. Reputation acquisition in debt markets. Garcia-Teruel PJ, Martinez-Solano P. 2007. Short-term debt in
Journal of Political Economy 97: 828–862. Spanish SMEs. International Small Business Journal 25:
579–602.
Elsas R, Krahnen JP. 1998. Is relationship lending special? Evi-
dence from credit-file data in Germany. Journal of Banking and Garmaise MJ. 2001. Informed Investors and the Financing of
Finance 22: 1283–1316. Entrepreneurial Projects. EFMA 2001 Lugano Meetings.

Esperanca JP, Gama APM, Gulamhussen MA. 2003. Corporate Ghosh S. 2007. Bank debt use and firm size: Indian evidence.
debt policy of small firms: an empirical (re) examination. Small Business Economics 29: 15–23.
Journal of Small Business and Enterprise Development 10:
Giudici G, Paleari S. 2000. The provision of finance to innova-
62–80.
tion: a survey conducted among Italian technology-based
Evans DS, Jovanovic B. 1989. An estimated model of entrepre- small firms. Small Business Economics 14: 37–53.
neurial choice under liquidity constraints. Journal of Political
Gompers PA. 1995. Optimal investment, monitoring, and the
Economy 97: 808–827.
staging of venture capital. The Journal of Finance 50:
Fairlie RW. 1999. The absence of the African-American owned 1461–1489.
business: an analysis of the dynamics of self-employment.
Gompers PA, Lerner J. 2003. Equity financing. In Acs Z,
Journal of Labor Economics 17: 80.
Audretsch DB (eds), Handbook of Entrepreneurship Research.
Fazzari SM, Hubbard RG, Petersen BC. 1988. Financing con- An Interdisciplinary Survey and Introduction. Kluwer Academic
straints and corporate investment. Brookings Papers on Eco- Publishers: Dordrecht.
nomic Activity 141–206.
Gorton G, Kahn J. 2000. The design of bank loan contracts.
Fazzari SM, Hubbard RG, Petersen BC. 2000. Investment cash The Review of Financial Studies 13: 331.
flow sensitivities are useful: a comment on Kaplan and Zin-
Gregory BT, Rutherford MW, Oswald S, Gardiner L. 2005. An
gales. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115: 695–705.
empirical investigation of the growth cycle theory of small firm
Fitzsimmons JR, Douglas EJ. 2006. Entrepreneurs and funding financing. Journal of Small Business Management 43:
decisions: evidence from Australian SMEs. International 382–392.
Journal of Entrepreneurship and Small Business 3: 76–91.
Hall G, Hutchinson PJ, Michaelas N. 2000. Industry effects on
Fluck Z, Holtz-Eakin D, Rosen HS. 1998. Where does the the determinants of unquoted SMEs’ capital structure. Inter-
money come from? The financing of small entrepreneurial national Journal of the Economics of Business 7: 297–312.
enterprises. Metropolitan Studies Program Series. Occasional
Hall G, Hutchinson P, Michaelas N. 2004. Determinants of the
Paper No. 191, Center for Policy Research, Maxwell School of
capital structures of European SMEs. Journal of Business
Citizenship and Public Affairs, Syracuse University, Syracuse.
Finance & Accounting 31: 711–728.
Frame WS, Srinivasan A, Woosley L. 2001. The effect of credit
Hand JH, Lloyd WP, Rogow RB. 1982. Agency relationships
scoring on small-business lending. Journal of Money, Credit
in the close corporation. Financial Management 11: 25–30.
and Banking 33: 813–825.
Hanley A, Crook J. 2005. The role of private knowledge in
Fritsch M. 1993. The role of small firms in West Germany. In
reducing the information wedge: a research note. Journal of
Acs ZJ, Audretsch DB (eds), Small Firms and Entrepreneurship:
Business Finance & Accounting 32: 415–433.
An East-West Perspective. Cambridge University Press:
Cambridge. Harris M, Raviv A. 1991. The theory of capital structure. The
Journal of Finance XLVI: 297–355.
Fu T-W, Ke M-C, Huang Y-S. 2002. Capital growth, financing
source and profitability of small businesses: evidence from Heyman D, Deloof M, Ooghe H. 2008. The financial structure
Taiwan small enterprises. Small Business Economics 18: of private held Belgian firms. Small Business Economics 30:
257–267. 301–313.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 25

Hogan T, Hutson E. 2005. Capital structure in new technol- LeCornu MR, McMahon RGP, Forsaith DM, Stanger AMJ.
ogy-based firms: evidence from the Irish software sector. 1996. The small enterprise financial objective function. Journal
Global Finance Journal 15: 369–387. of Small Business Management 1–14.
Holmes S, Kent P. 1991. An empirical analysis of the financial Levenson AR, Willard KL. 2000. Do firms get the financing
structure of small and large Australian manufacturing enter- they want? Measuring credit rationing experienced by small
prises. The Journal of Small Business Finance 1: 141–154. businesses in the U.S. Small Business Economics 14: 83–94.

Howorth CA. 2001. Small firms’ demand for finance: a research López-Gracia J, Sanchez-Andujar S. 2007. Financial structure
note. International Small Business Journal 19: 78–86. of the family business: evidence from a group of small Spanish
firms. Family Business Review 20: 269–287.
Hudson M, Smart A, Bourne M. 2001. Theory and practice in
SME performance measurement systems. International Journal López-Gracia J, Sogorb-Mira F. 2008. Testing trade-off and
of Operations and Production Management 21: 1096–1115. pecking order theories financing SMEs. Small Business Eco-
nomics 31: 117–136.
Hussain J, Matlay H. 2007. Financing preferences of ethnic
minority owner/managers in the UK. Journal of Small Business Mac an Bhaird C, Lucey B. 2010. Determinants of capital
and Enterprise Development 14: 487–500. structure in Irish SMEs. Small Business Economics
Hyytinen A, Vaananen L. 2006. Where do financial constraints (forthcoming).
originate from? An empirical analysis of adverse selection and Manigart S, Struyf C. 1997. Financing high technology startups
moral hazard in capital markets. Small Business Economics 27: in Belgium: an explorative study. Small Business Economics 9:
323–348. 125–135.
Ibbotson RG, Sindelar JL, Ritter J. 2001. Initial public offer- Manigart S, Wright M, Robbie K, Desbrieres P, De Waele K.
ings. In Chew DHJ (ed.), The New Corporate Finance. Where 1997. Venture capitalists’ appraisal of investment projects: an
Theory Meets Practice, 3rd edn. McGraw Hill-Irwin: New York. empirical European study. Entrepreneurship: Theory & Practice
Jensen MC, Meckling WH. 1976. Theory of the firm: manage- 21: 29.
rial behaviour, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal Mann RJ. 1997. The role of secured credit in small business
of Financial Economics 3: 305–360. lending. The Georgetown Law Journal 86: 1–44.
Johnsen PC, Mcmahon RGP. 2005. Cross-industry differences Manove M, Padilla AJ, Pagano M. 2001. Collateral versus
in SME financing behaviour: an Australian perspective. Journal project screening: a model of lazy banks. RAND Journal of
of Small Business and Enterprise Development 12: 160– Economics 32: 726–744.
177.
McMahon RGP, Holmes S, Hutchinson PJ, Forsaith DM.
Jordan J, Lowe J, Taylor P. 1998. Strategy and financial policy 1993. Small Enterprise Financial Management. Theory and
in UK small firms. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting Practice. Harcourt Brace: San Diego.
25: 1–27.
Michaelas N, Chittenden F, Poutziouris P. 1998. A model of
Keasey K, Watson R. 1993. Small Firm Management. Owner- capital structure decision making in small firms. Journal of
ship, Finance and Performance. Blackwell: Oxford. Small Business and Enterprise Development 5: 246–
Keasey K, Watson R. 2000. Interest rate premia on UK small 260.
firm bank borrowings: a research note. Journal of Business Michaelas N, Chittenden F, Poutziouris P. 1999. Financial
Finance & Accounting 27: 247–259. policy and capital structure choice in UK SMEs: empirical
Kon Y, Storey DJ. 2003. A theory of discouraged borrowers. evidence from company panel data. Small Business Economics
Small Business Economics 21: 37–49. 12: 113–130.

Landstrom H. 2008. Handbook of Research on Venture Capital. Mills DE, Schumann L. 1985. Industry structure with fluctuat-
Edward Elgar: Cheltenham. ing demand. American Economic Review 75: 758.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
26 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

Modigliani F, Miller MH. 1958. The cost of capital, corporation Romano CA, Tanewski GA, Smyrnios KX. 2001. Capital struc-
finance and the theory of investment. The American Economic ture decision making: a model for family business. Journal of
Review 48: 261–297. Business Venturing 16: 285–310.

Myers SC. 1984. The capital structure puzzle. The Journal of Rostow WW. 1960. The Stages of Economic Growth. Cambridge
Finance 39: 575–592. University Press: Cambridge.

Myers SC. 2001. Capital structure. Journal of Economic Perspec- Sahlman WA. 1990. The structure and governance of venture-
tives 15: 81–102. capital organizations. Journal of Financial Economics 27: 473.

Myers SC, Majluf NS. 1984. Corporate financing and invest- Salazar M. 2007. The Effect of Wealth and Race on Start-Up Rates.
ment decisions when firms have information that investors Small Business Association: Washington, DC.
do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13(2): 187– Scherr FC, Sugrue TF, Ward JB. 1993. Financing the small firm
221. start-up: determinants of debt use. The Journal of Small Busi-
Norton E. 1990. Similarities and differences in small and large ness Finance 3: 17–36.
corporation beliefs about capital structure policy. Small Busi- Smart SB, Megginson WL, Gitman LJ. 2007. Corporate Finance.
ness Economics 2: 229–245. Thomson South-Western: Mason.
Oakey RP. 1984. Finance and innovation in British small inde- Sogorb Mira F. 2005. How SME uniqueness affects capital
pendent firms. Omega International Journal of Management structure: evidence from a 1994–1998 Spanish data panel.
Science 12: 113–124. Small Business Economics 25: 447–457.
Ou C, Haynes GW. 2003. Uses of equity capital by small Stiglitz JE, Weiss A. 1981. Credit rationing in markets with
firms — findings from the surveys of small business finances imperfect information. The American Economic Review 71:
(for 1993 & 1998). 14th Annual Conference on Entrepreneur- 393–410.
ial Finance and Business Ventures. De Paul University,
Storey DJ. 1994a. New firm growth and bank financing. Small
Chicago.
Business Economics 6: 139–150.
Ou C, Haynes GW. 2006. Acquisition of additional equity
Storey DJ. 1994b. Understanding the Small Business Sector.
capital by small firms — findings from the National Survey
Routledge: London.
of Small Business Finances. Small Business Economics 27:
157–168. Tanaka M. 2003. The macroeconomic implications of the New
Basel Accord. CESifo Economic Studies 49: 217–232.
Penrose ET. 1952. Biological analogies in the theory of the firm.
American Economic Review 42: 804. Ullah F, Taylor P. 2005. The impact of science park and incuba-
tor location on the finance opportunities of technology-based
Penrose ET. 1959. The Theory of the Growth of the Firm. John
small firms. In During W, Oakey R, Kauser S (eds), New
Wiley & Sons, Ltd: New York.
Technology-Based Firms in the New Millennium. Elsevier:
Pettit RR, Singer RF. 1985. Small business finance: a research Oxford.
agenda. Financial Management 14: 47–60.
Ullah F, Taylor P. 2007. Are UK technology-based small firms
Poutziouris PZ. 2002. The financial affairs of smaller family still finance constrained? The International Entrepreneurship
companies. In Fletcher DE (ed.), Understanding the Small and Management Journal 3: 189–203.
Family Business. Routledge: London.
Vos E, Forlong C. 1996. The agency advantage of debt over the
Rajan RG. 1992. Insiders and outsiders: the choice between lifecycle of the firm. Entrepreneurial and Small Business Finance
informed and arm’s-length debt. The Journal of Finance XLVII: 5: 193–211.
1367–1400.
Voulgaris F, Asteriou D, Agiomirgianakis G. 2004. Size and
Reid GC. 1991. Staying in business. International Journal of determinants of capital structure in the Greek manufacturing
Industrial Organization 9(4): 545–556. sector. International Review of Applied Economics 18: 247–262.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
The Modigliani–Miller Proposition After Fifty Years 27

Walker EW, Petty WJI. 1978. Financial differences between Weston JF, Brigham EF. 1970. Managerial Finance. Dryden
large and small firms. Financial Management Winter: 61– Press: New York.
66.
Wright M, Robbie K. 1998. Venture capital and private equity:
a review and synthesis. Journal of Business Finance and Account-
Watson R, Wilson N. 2002. Small and medium size enterprise
ing 25(5&6): 521–570.
financing: a note on some of the empirical implications of a
pecking order. Journal of Business Finance & Accounting 29: Zingales L. 2000. In search of new foundations. The Journal of
557–579. Finance 55(4): 1623–1653.

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc
28 Ciarán mac an Bhaird

BIOGRAPHICAL NOTE

Ciarán mac an Bhaird is a lecturer of Business


and Management, and Chair of the undergraduate
degree programs at Fiontar, Dublin City University,
Ireland.

Correspondence to:
Ciarán mac an Bhaird
Fiontar, Dublin City University
Dublin 9, Ireland
email: ciaran.macanbhaird@dcu.ie

Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. Strategic Change


DOI: 10.1002/jsc

You might also like