You are on page 1of 32

Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

www.elsevier.com/locate/aos

The relation between cost-system design, managersÕ


evaluations of the relevance and usefulness of cost data,
and financial performance: an empirical
study of US hospitals
Mina J. Pizzini *

School of Management, University of Texas at Dallas, J043 Box 83688, Richardson, TX 75083-0688, United States

Abstract

This study examines the association between cost-system functionality, managersÕ beliefs about the relevance and
usefulness of cost data, and actual financial performance using a sample of 277 US hospitals. Results indicate that man-
agersÕ evaluations of the relevance and usefulness of cost data are positively correlated with the extent to which systems
can provide greater cost detail, better classify costs according to behavior, and report cost information more frequently.
However, only the ability to supply cost detail is favorably associated with measures of financial performance, including
operating margin, cash flow, and administrative expense. Interestingly, cost-system design was not associated with oper-
ating expense per admission, suggesting that accounting information had not yet been successfully used to manage clin-
ical costs.
Ó 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Introduction four critical attributes of cost-system design: the


level of detail provided, the ability to disaggregate
This study investigates associations between costs according to behavior, the frequency with
cost-system design, managersÕ beliefs about the rel- which information is reported, and the extent to
evance and usefulness of cost data, and actual which variances are calculated. The first attribute,
financial performance using a sample of 277 US the level of detail, refers to the systemÕs ability to
hospitals. Accounting literature identifies at least supply data about cost objects that vary in size
from entire divisions to individual products, com-
ponents, and services. Chenhall and Morris (1986),
*
Tel.: +1 972 883 6337; fax: +1 972 883 6822. Feltham (1977), Kaplan and Norton (1992), and
E-mail address: pizzini@utdallas.edu Karmarkar, Lederer, and Zimmerman (1990)

0361-3682/$ - see front matter Ó 2004 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.aos.2004.11.001
180 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

incorporated level of detail in their characteriza- Highly functional systems also cost more to imple-
tions of cost-system design. The second character- ment and administer; consequently, the benefits of
istic of cost-system design, the ability to such systems may not exceed their costs (Babad &
disaggregate costs according to behavior, closely Balachandran, 1993; Banker & Potter, 1993; Kar-
relates to the first. To supply detail, the system markar et al., 1990). Finally, contingency theory
must first separate and classify costs according to suggests that greater functionality is not a priori
behavior. Basic cost classifications explored in better. Rather, performance improvement is a
the literature include fixed/variable costs, direct/ function of the alignment between cost-system
indirect costs, and controllable/non-controllable functionality and the firmÕs operating environment
costs (Feltham & Xie, 1994; Johnson, 1992; Kar- (see Chenhall, 2003, for a review).
markar et al., 1990; Khandwalla, 1972). The third The US hospital industry is an ideal setting for
attribute, cost reporting frequency enables manag- investigating the performance effects of cost-sys-
ers to expediently address problems and identify tem design. The industry provides the opportunity
opportunities for improvement (Hilton, 1979; to sample from a large number of complex organi-
Karmarkar et al., 1990; Simons, 1987). The final zations that operate under similar circumstances
cost-system trait, variance analysis, highlights dif- and offer relatively standardized services. In the
ferences between budgeted and actual outcomes United States, expenditures for hospital care ex-
and seeks to explain such differences (Karmarkar ceeded $486 billion in 2002 and constituted almost
et al., 1990; Khandwalla, 1972; Simons, 1987). 5% of the gross domestic product (GDP). 1
More functional cost systems are those that can Healthcare literature overwhelmingly advocates
provide greater detail, better classify costs accord- the use of highly refined cost systems to enable
ing to behavior, report cost information more fre- hospital managers to respond to growing pressure
quently, and/or calculate more variances. to control costs in this rapidly changing industry
The conceptual model linking cost-system de- (e.g., Cooper & Suver, 1994; Chua & Degeling,
sign to performance is typically stated in terms of 1991; Hill & Johns, 1994; Young & Pearlman,
a causal chain in which more functional or refined 1993). Such advocacy is consistent with manage-
cost systems produce ‘‘better’’ (i.e., more relevant ment accounting research (e.g., Chenhall & Mor-
and useful) data that enhance managerial decision ris, 1986; Gordon & Narayanan, 1984; Hill,
making, and thereby lead to improved economic 2001; Khandwalla, 1972), which suggests that as
performance (e.g., Cooper & Kaplan, 1991; John- environmental uncertainty increases, decision
son, 1992; Shank & Govindarajan, 1993). Despite makers seek more information for planning and
the intuitive appeal of this rather basic premise, control. Yet, in practice, US hospital cost systems
there is little systematic evidence linking cost-sys- vary greatly in functionality, with many systems
tem design to economic performance. Analytical presumably lagging the new managerial informa-
models of single-firm settings find that more de- tion needs created by sweeping, industry-wide
tailed and frequent cost data are more useful in changes (Hill & Johns, 1994; Orloff, Littell, Clune,
decision making (Feltham, 1977; Hilton, 1979); Klingman, & Preston, 1990; Serb, 1997).
however, evidence in multi-firm settings indicates Empirical evidence on the performance implica-
that strategic behavior can bring about conditions tions of cost-system design is primarily limited to
in which less informative product-cost data are small-sample studies focused upon managersÕ be-
optimal (Banker & Potter, 1993; Callahan & Gab- liefs about a single aspect of cost-system design
riel, 1999; Gal-Or, 1987; Gal-Or, 1998; Gal-Or, (activity-based costing); and here, results are mod-
1993). Research on institutional theory and infor- est (e.g., Foster & Swenson, 1997; Ittner, Lanen, &
mation overload further suggests that managers Larcker, 2002; Krumwiede, 1998). Using data
may not effectively use the more detailed, disaggre-
gated, and voluminous data produced by highly 1
Statistics can be found at www.cms.hhs.gov/statistics/nhe
functional systems (Covaleski, Dirsmith, & Mich- and were compiled by Centers for Medicare and Medicaid
elman, 1993; Schick, Gordon, & Haka, 1990). Services, Office of the Actuary.
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 181

from 277 US hospitals, this study extends prior re- ciency; however, highly functional cost systems
search in several ways. First, rather than simply have not been used to significantly reduce clinical
identifying whether an organization has adopted expenditures.
a single costing technique, comprehensive survey The remainder of this paper proceeds as follows.
data provide a relatively objective, multidimen- The following section provides background on the
sional characterization of the functions a cost sys- US hospital industry. Then the paper reviews the
tem can perform. Second, the ability to link literature on cost-system design and develops the
descriptive data on cost-system design with actual hypotheses within the context of the hospital indus-
hospital-level financial data from external sources try. The next section describes the research meth-
permits some of the first direct tests of the relation ods, followed by an analysis of the results of
between specific cost-system attributes and actual statistical tests. The paper concludes with a sum-
economic outcomes. Third, the relatively large mary of the results and limitations of the study.
sample size and operational homogeneity of hospi-
tals enable powerful tests of the research question.
In contrast, prior studies relied predominantly on
Background on US hospital industry
small-sample field studies or moderate-size sam-
ples of firms in diverse industries (e.g. Shields,
In the US, the government is heavily involved in
1995; Swenson, 1995). Finally, this study adds to
the provision and regulation of healthcare; how-
the literature on contingency theory by measuring
ever, the US government still plays a much smaller
‘‘fit’’ between control system and organizational
role in the health sector when compared with the
context using both ‘‘selection’’ and ‘‘systems’’ ap-
governments of most other countries. Privately-
proaches (Selto, Renner, & Young, 1995, p. 679).
owned, nonprofit hospitals dominate the US hos-
Results indicate that managers find cost data to
pital market, accounting for approximately 60%
be more useful and relevant if supplied by systems
of all hospitals, while state and local govern-
that provide greater detail, better classify costs
ment-owned hospitals constitute only 22% of the
according to behavior, and provide cost informa-
market. The remaining 18% of US hospitals are
tion on a more frequent basis. However, actual
organized as for-profit investor-owned firms. 2
financial performance, as characterized by operat-
Hospitals of different ownership type and for-prof-
ing margins, cash flow per bed, and administrative
it status often compete in the same markets. Al-
cost control, is significantly and positively associ-
most 55% of the total US healthcare bill is
ated only with those systems that provide greater
funded from private sources including private
detail. There is some evidence that improved cost
insurers (33%), individuals (15%), and other pri-
classification capabilities can enhance cash flow
vate sources (6%). The US federal government
per bed; however, the performance effects of cost
pays for roughly 33% of healthcare expenditures
classification cannot be separated from the effects
primarily through its health insurance programs
of providing detail. Cost-system design was not
for individuals age 65 or older (Medicare) and cer-
associated with expense per admission, which re-
tain disadvantaged individuals (Medicaid). State
flects clinical resource consumption, and hence, is
and local governments cover another 13% of
controlled primarily by physicians, not hospital
healthcare expenditures. 3 Patient fees fund the
administrators. Performance tests that measured
cost-system functionality relative to hospitals with
similar strategies, structures, and environments
were consistent with tests that measured function- 2
Source: American Hospital Association website, www.
ality relative to all hospitals in the sample. Taken aha.org/aha/resource_center. Excludes federal government hos-
together, the results suggest that more functional pitals, which constitute only a small proportion of the market
and primarily serve veterans and active members of the
cost systems can help hospital administrators im- military.
prove non-clinical aspects of hospital operations, 3
Source: Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services
such as cash management and administrative effi- website, www.cms.hhs.gov/medicare.
182 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

bulk of expenditures in most nonprofit hospitals For example, physicians admit patients, prescribe
and in all for-profit hospitals (Eldenburg, Herma- all medications that hospital nurses administer,
lin, Weisbach, & Wosinska, 2004). Nonprofit pri- and specify which tests hospital technicians
vately-owned hospitals also receive significant perform.
donations, while nonprofit government-owned Given the prominence of the private sector in
hospitals obtain substantial government subsidies. US healthcare, researchers commonly use eco-
For-profit hospitals receive few donations and, un- nomics to analyze and understand the US health-
like their nonprofit counterparts, their income is care sector (for example, see Phelps, 2003,
taxed. Chapter 1). In fact, research in healthcare eco-
Despite differences in ownership and for-profit nomics provides strong empirical support for
status, US hospitals are strikingly similar in service the application of economic theory to the US
provision and organizational structure (Eldenburg healthcare sector. For example, several studies
et al., 2004). All hospitals provide essentially the have found that physicians and hospital adminis-
same basic set of services using standard methods. trators in the US respond to economic incentives
Across ownership types, hospitals are governed by in a rational manner and there is growing evi-
a board that is empowered to direct all hospital dence that agency theory explains the choice of
functions (Phelps, 2003). The board, which is gen- compensation contracts in healthcare organiza-
erally self-replicating (members elect their own tions (e.g., Brickley & Van Horne, 2002; DeBrock
successors), represents the interests of various & Arnould, 1992; Gaynor & Gertler, 1995; Gay-
stakeholders, including donors, community mem- nor & Pauly, 1990; Ittner, Larcker, & Pizzini,
bers, and shareholders. The board provides overall 2004; Lambert & Larcker, 1995; Lee, 1990).
strategic direction, but normally hires nonphysi- Empirical evidence also suggests that economic
cian professional administrators to manage the theory underlies hospitalsÕ strategic choices such
hospital. Senior hospital administers parallel their as location (Norton & Staiger, 1994; Wedig, Has-
counterparts in industry. san, & Sloan, 1989), investment (Krishnan, 2001),
One rather unique aspect of US hospitals, cost allocations (Eldenburg & Kallapur, 1997),
regardless of ownership type, is the distinction be- operating strategy, and tax-status (Picone, Chou,
tween hospital personnel and the medical staff of & Sloan, 2002). Following prior research on
physicians (Phelps, 2003). Hospitals employ both healthcare institutions, this paper draws heavily
administrative professionals and nonphysician upon economic theory to develop the research
clinical professionals (e.g., nurses and medical hypotheses. 6
technicians), but they do not generally employ
the physicians who are members of the medical
staff. Physicians gain entry to the medical staff
through a credentialing process controlled by the 6
Economic theories assume that individuals are rational
existing medical staff. 4 The hospital has no expli- and that successful firms make appropriate decisions in
cit contract with the medical staff, yet it is depen- designing control systems. A number of alternative theories
dent upon staff physicians to attract and care for suggest otherwise (see Luft & Shields, 2003, for a review); and,
hospital patients. Staff physicians direct patient several have used alternative theories to analyze management
care within hospitals, and in doing so, control control systems in healthcare (e.g., Abernethy & Chua, 1996;
Abernethy & Vagnoni, 2004; Chua & Degeling, 1991; Jones &
the use of hospital employees and facilities. 5 Dewing, 1997). However, systematic empirical evidence that US
hospitals conform to political, psychological and other non-
economic theories of behavior is quite limited. Conversely, a
4
Physicians apply to the hospital board for admission to the significant healthcare economics literature provides strong
medical and the board generally delegates responsibility for this empirical evidence that physician behavior and managerial
decision to existing medical staff (Phelps, 2003, p. 254). decisions in US hospitals conform to economic theory (e.g.,
5
By law, most care provided to patients must be performed Brickley & Van Horne, 2002; Eldenburg et al., 2004; Gaynor &
by a licensed physician or under the direction of a licensed Gertler, 1995; Gaynor & Pauly, 1990; Lambert & Larcker,
physician (Phelps, 2003, p. 254). 1995; Wedig et al., 1989).
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 183

Hypothesis development mined fixed amount based upon a patientÕs DRG


(e.g., Chua & Degeling, 1991; Preston, 1992). 7
Proposed benefits of greater functionality in hospital Lawrence (1990) hypothesized that actual financial
cost system design and operational performance would be higher for
hospitals that used systems that supplied greater
While there is little empirical evidence support- detail; however, her empirical tests did not support
ing associations between cost-system design and this hypothesis.
performance, the extant literature suggests that
cost systems can be used to enhance both financial Classify costs according to behavior. The ability to
and operational performance. Each individual ele- disaggregate costs and classify them according to
ment of cost-system design potentially improves their behavior directly supports the ability to pro-
the relevance and usefulness of cost data. More- vide useful detailed cost information. For example,
over, in the hospital setting, the cost system as a to aggregate costs by procedure, direct costs must
whole can potentially mitigate agency problems. be traced to the procedure, and indirect fixed and
variable costs must be allocated to the procedure.
Proposed benefits of individual cost system design This requires the system to classify costs as di-
elements rect/indirect and fixed/variable. If this cost classifi-
Level of detail. Management accounting literature cation is arbitrary, than the detailed cost data will
generally contends that an important feature of a not be useful; however, if the system can meaning-
cost system is its ability to provide sufficient detail fully classify costs according to behavior, detailed
and flexibility to allow costs to be analyzed for dif- cost data should be useful. In fact, several
ferent purposes (e.g., Karmarkar et al., 1990; researchers contend that correctly identifying cost
Shank & Govindarajan, 1993). Chenhall and Mor- behavior is the first step in supplying accurate cost
ris (1986) proposed that systems that can isolate information at all levels of detail (Cooper & Kap-
the effects of specific events on different functions lan, 1991, Chapter 5; McGown, 1998; Shank &
are of greater use to managers in uncertain envi- Govindarajan, 1993, Chapter 10; Swenson,
ronments. FelthamÕs (1977) analytical model sup- 1995). 8 Classifying costs according to behavior
ported these assertions, finding that the expected is particularly important in the hospital industry,
payoff from decisions based upon more detailed which is characterized by large amounts of facil-
information is generally greater than that from ity-related support and joint costs (e.g., buildings
decisions based on more aggregated information. and sophisticated equipment shared by many
In hospitals, managers face various decisions users) that cannot be directly and easily traced to
regarding the services (procedures, tests, diagno- individual services. In CoombsÕs (1987) field study
ses, etc.) provided, the customers (patients) receiv- of two Swedish hospitals, both administrators and
ing these services, the individuals (physicians,
nurses, therapists, etc.) providing these services,
and the groups (private insurance companies, gov- 7
DRG categories, which reflect the nature and intensity of
ernment agencies, individuals, etc.) that pay for the hospital services, can essentially be thought of as the
the services. Unless the system can identify and hospitalÕs ‘‘products.’’ Hence, DRG-level costing enables hos-
aggregate costs for these cost objects (i.e., provide pital managers to assess the profitability of its ‘‘products.’’
8
However, a very complex method for classifying costs is
sufficient detail) with reasonable accuracy, manag- not necessarily a prerequisite for supplying useful detailed
ers will not be able to make well-informed deci- information (Bromwich & Hong, 1999; Datar & Gupta, 1994;
sions on related issues (Comerford & Abernethy, Noreen, 1991). Even if cost classification is not highly accurate,
1999; Covaleski et al., 1993; Evans, Hwang, & detailed cost data can still be useful (Merchant & Shields, 1993).
Nagarajan, 1995). The ability to specify the costs Hill (2001) contends that hospitals with procedure-level cost
systems will have better information for decision making than
of individual diagnostic-related groups (DRG) is those without such systems, even if the procedure-level system
particularly relevant because Medicare and many uses a relatively unsophisticated method to assign costs to
private insurers reimburse hospitals a predeter- procedures (e.g., the ratio of costs to charges).
184 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

physician clinic managers expressed strong interest that the more timely the information, the greater
in systems that could better associate clinical activ- the value of an information system. Karmarkar
ities with resource consumption. et al. (1990) used timeliness to characterize cost-
Another important cost categorization is the system design, and they considered timeliness to
distinction between controllable and noncontrolla- be indicative of the ‘‘elaborateness’’ of a cost
ble costs because it aids principals in performance system.
evaluation (Feltham & Xie, 1994). In US hospitals,
the ability to identify functions that fall under a Variance analysis. Proponents of variance analysis
managerÕs control is particularly crucial because contend that it aids in managerial decision making
hospital managers typically have less control over by identifying corrective managerial actions (e.g.,
basic business functions such as pricing, services Johnson & Kaplan, 1987; Shank & Govindarajan,
offered, and service delivery than their counter- 1993). Budgetary control, which forms that basis
parts in other sectors. For example, if cost data of variance analysis, may be appropriate for the
showed that emergency medicine was not profit- hospital setting because uncertainty in both task
able, the hospital could not simply turn people technology (Ouchi, 1979) and output (Cooper,
away, raise prices, or shut down the emergency Hayes, & Wolf, 1981) renders administrative mon-
room. itoring difficult. Moreover, the prevalence of fixed-
price contracting (i.e., fixed reimbursements based
Frequency of cost reports. Cost-reporting fre- upon a DRG, patient-day, or procedure) should
quency enables managers to expediently address make variance analysis very well suited for hospi-
problems and identify opportunities for improve- tals because such contracts force hospitals to ac-
ment. Chenhall and Morris (1986) measured the cept the risk of unexpected costs and utilizations
frequency of cost reports and contended that more (Abernethy & Stoelwinder, 1996; Lawrence,
frequent reporting provides managers with feed- 1990; Preston, 1992). By specifying cost targets
back on decisions and information on recent and measuring performance in relation to these
events that they can use to guide future courses targets, managers can use variance analysis to allo-
of action. Chenhall and Morris found that more cate resources to clinical units and measure their
frequent reporting was believed to be particularly performance. In particular, instead of directly
useful to managers who operate in highly uncer- monitoring physicians, hospital managers can
tain environments, such as hospitals. In response investigate variances among amounts charged by
to increased pressure to control costs, hospital physicians to DRG-defined groups as compared
administrators in CoombsÕ (1987) field study to hospital or industry standards (Covaleski
sought to increase the frequency with which they et al., 1993).
received control information. Eldenburg (1994)
empirically examined whether more frequent Potential benefits of a cost system as a whole:
reporting of cost information to hospital physi- reduction in agency conflicts
cians could induce cost-conscious behavior. How- Conflicts between hospital board and hospital man-
ever, contrary to her hypothesis, higher reporting agers. Most hospitals are nonprofit entities. The
frequency was not significantly associated with nonprofit organizational form eliminates conflicts
lower costs. between donors and residual claimants (Fama &
More frequent reporting may also indicate that Jensen, 1983a); however, it does not eliminate
information is provided on a more timely basis. agency problems between donors and other inter-
For example, if cost information is reported nal agents, namely managers (Fama & Jensen,
monthly rather than quarterly, managers can ad- 1983b). Unlike for-profit entities, donors cannot
dress concerns that arise between quarters, rather align managersÕ interests with their own by offering
than wait until the end of the quarter. Hilton managers an equity stake. Thus, donors rely on ac-
(1979) modeled the value of an information system tive, independent boards to monitor nonprofit
in a cost-volume-profit decision setting and found managers and ensure that managers take actions
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 185

consistent with the interests of donors and external problems, hospitals must have a cost system that
stakeholders. Consistent with the growing empha- provides appropriate data.
sis on cost containment in the healthcare sector,
board members are increasingly using cost, profit, Potential drawbacks of greater cost-system
and operational data to monitor managerial per- functionality
formance (Brickley & Van Horne, 2002; Molinari,
Hendryx, & Goodstein, 1997). More functional The aforementioned benefits associated with
systems can better associate costs with a managerÕs greater functionality implicitly assume that more
actions and decisions, and therefore, produce mea- functional cost systems produce more relevant cost
sures that contain more information about a man- data, which managers use to make performance-
agerÕs effort. enhancing decisions. Yet, research has not estab-
lished whether managers find data produced by
Conflicts between management and healthcare pro- highly functional cost systems more relevant and
viders. Physicians play a critical role in determin- useful. Nor has extant research convincingly dem-
ing hospital resource use (Pauly & Redisch, 1973) onstrated that more useful cost data lead to deci-
and, consequently, hospital financial performance sions that positively affect a firmÕs objective
(Feinglass, Martin, & Sen, 1991). 9 Yet, hospital function. Furthermore, even if more functional
managers typically have no explicit control over cost systems lead to better managerial decisions,
physicians because most US physicians are not the benefits of those decisions may not offset costs
employed by the hospitals at which they practice. associated with a more functional cost system.
Moreover, physician and hospital incentives are Each of these concerns is discussed below.
not well aligned because hospital physicians are
usually compensated based upon the volume of Limited evidence that greater functionality leads
services provided, while hospitals increasingly face to ‘‘better’’ cost data
fixed-price contracts (Eldenburg, 1994; Pauly & While many contend that more functional cost
Redisch, 1973). 10 Cost data can potentially be systems provide ‘‘better’’ cost data (i.e., more rele-
used instead of an explicit contract to control phy- vant and useful), this is difficult to empirically sub-
sician behavior (Covaleski et al., 1993). Specifi- stantiate because the ‘‘true’’ costs of products and
cally, Eldenburg (1994) and Evans et al. (1995) services are unknown (Christensen & Demski,
found that presenting physicians with data on their 1997; Dopuch, 1993). Evidence regarding the qual-
own costs, along with comparative cost and oper- ity of data produced by more functional systems is
ational information, provides some incentive for limited to analytical studies of overhead alloca-
physicians to modify their behavior. However, to tions, and here, results are mixed (Banker & Pot-
use cost data to mitigate physician-hospital agency ter, 1993; Bromwich & Hong, 1999; Christensen
& Demski, 1997; Datar & Gupta, 1994; Noreen,
1991). 11 Institutional theory suggests that hospi-
tals may adopt refined cost systems simply to con-
9
Physician control over admissions and in-hospital treat- form to societal expectations of acceptable
ment led Pauly and Redisch (1973) to characterize hospitals as practice, and thereby gain external credibility and
physician cooperatives designed to maximize physicianÕs clinical validation (Covaleski et al., 1993). In such cases,
efficiency and income. Chilingerian and Sherman (1990)
estimate that physicians directly influence up to 80% of all
hospital expenditures.
10 11
Medicare and a growing number of private payers Banker and Potter (1993) and Datar and Gupta (1994)
reimburse hospitals a fixed amount based upon the diagnos- demonstrate that greater complexity in allocation schemes
tic-related-group (DRG) into which an illness can be catego- introduces classification, measurement, and other errors that
rized, regardless of how much it costs the hospital to care for can actually reduce data accuracy. Others show that greater
the illness. Conversely, Medicare and most other payers functionality leads to greater accuracy only if fairly restrictive
reimburse most hospital physicians on a fee-for-service basis, conditions are met (Bromwich & Hong, 1999; Christensen &
i.e., based upon the amount of service provided. Demski, 1997; Noreen, 1991).
186 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

hospital managers are unlikely to find the informa- system. Implementing a new system often entails
tion produced by more functional cost systems to consulting, training, and software expenses. Com-
be useful. plex systems typically incur higher data collection,
processing, and management costs (Babad & Bal-
Limitations on the usefulness of ‘‘better’’ cost data achandran, 1993; Banker & Potter, 1993). Surveys
Even if more functional systems produce ‘‘bet- in the hospital industry suggest that the cost of
ter’’ cost data, such data may not necessarily lead such systems is a major impediment to their use
to improved firm performance. In fact, more infor- (Counte & Glandon, 1988; Hill & Johns,
mative cost data can actually hinder performance. 1994). 12 While the extant literature acknowledges
This has been demonstrated in multi-firm settings the costs of highly functional systems, it largely
characterized by strategic behavior (Gal-Or, ignores such costs in investigating the performance
1987; Gal-Or, 1998; Gal-Or, 1993). Banker and effects of functionality. Analytical models gener-
Potter (1993) specified demand conditions under ally do not address such costs (Banker & Potter,
which it was optimal for firms to use a relatively 1993; Feltham, 1977; Hilton, 1979), and few
simple system. Callahan and Gabriel (1999) found empirical studies use performance measures that
that firms competing on the basis of product differ- reflect the actual cost of administering the system
entiation (characterized as a Bertrand duopoly) (Ittner et al., 2002; Lawrence, 1990).
did not benefit from increased product-cost accu- In summary, there are several potential limita-
racy. The risk of information overload also sug- tions to cost-system functionality. However,
gests that managers may be constrained in their underlying economic theory suggests that the po-
ability to effectively use data produced by more tential benefits of more functional systems can
functional cost systems. Information that is too overcome these limitations. In particular, the pro-
detailed, disaggregated, and/or voluminous poten- posed benefits of individual cost-system design ele-
tially reduces decision-making effectiveness (see ments, the potential to reduce agency problems,
Schick et al., 1990, for a review). and the need for more information created by
Finally, some researchers contend that variance the rapidly changing hospital industry suggest
data specifically is not useful for managerial deci- the following hypotheses:
sion making. They argue that interdependence be-
tween variances may produce measurement errors, H1a. Cost-system functionality is positively associ-
that variance analysis lacks information on the ated with managersÕ beliefs about the rele-
causes of cost overruns, and that variances provide vance and usefulness of cost data in hospitals.
incentives to pursue short-term cost reduction over H1b. Cost-system functionality is positively associ-
continuous improvement (e.g., Bastable & Bao, ated with actual financial performance in
1988; Cheatham & Cheatham, 1996; Cooper & hospitals.
Kaplan, 1992; Mak & Roush, 1996). Others have
used political theories of organization to criticize Contingency theory and cost-system design
the application of budgeting, which underlies var-
iance analysis, to the hospital sector. For example, The previous discussion posits that the absolute
Abernethy and Vagnoni (2004), Covaleski and level at which a cost-system functions is directly
Dirsmith (1986), and Kurunmäki (1999) suggest
that budgeting potentially serves to establish, dis-
tribute, and maintain power within hospitals, 12
In a 1992 survey on hospital cost systems, the majority of
and therefore, undermines the role that variance respondents who did not use procedure-level cost systems
analysis plays in performance-enhancing decisions. indicated that they did not have such systems due to resource
constraints, expense, or the concern that costs would outweigh
the benefits (Hill & Johns, 1994). Similarly, Counte and
The costs of greater functionality Glandon (1988) found that 53% of respondents had not
The potential benefits of a more highly func- upgraded their systems due to resource constraints, while 38%
tional cost system may not exceed the costs of that feared the costs would not exceed the benefits.
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 187

correlated to a firmÕs performance. However, con- cause they can potentially spread the fixed costs of
tingency theory contends that a firmÕs strategy, system development over more beds (Hill, 2001).
organizational structure, and environment dictate Other important structural variables include for-
its choice of control system (see Chenhall, 2003, profit status and hospital district membership.
for a review). Any associated benefits or draw- For-profit hospitals, which have the explicit goal
backs are a function of the degree of alignment be- of increasing ownersÕ wealth, are expected to
tween the design of a firmÕs cost system and the implement more elaborate cost systems to aid in
specific set of circumstances the firm faces. Bene- this endeavor. 13 Hospitals that are organized by
fits or drawbacks are not solely attributable to hospital districts can potentially subsidize opera-
the absolute level of cost-system functionality. tions with funds obtained from local taxes. Thus,
Consistent with contingency theory, hospital district hospitals may have less incentive to control
cost-system design has been found to vary system- costs and, consequently, less need for highly func-
atically with internal, organizational factors and tional cost systems. 14
external, environmental factors (e.g., Counte & A firmÕs external environment also has been
Glandon, 1988; Hill, 2001; Hill & Johns, 1994; found to influence cost-system design in the hos-
Lawrence, 1990). For purposes of discussion, I pital and other industries (Hill, 2001; Khand-
group determinants of hospital cost-system design walla, 1972). Hospitals that operate in markets
into three categories: strategic, structural, and with strong competition and/or significant pene-
environmental. tration from managed-care organizations (MCOs)
Although there is little empirical research link- face greater external pressure to control costs and
ing organizational strategy to control-system de- therefore require more extensive and detailed cost
sign in hospitals, research in other industries information (Hill, 2001; Lawrence, 1990). 15 Sim-
generally contends that strategy influences con- ilarly, hospitals that treat a large proportion of
trol-system design (see Langfield-Smith, 1997, for patients covered by Medicare or managed-care
a review). Using PorterÕs framework (1980, plans will face greater external pressure to con-
1985), strategy can be measured along two dimen- trol costs, because these payers often impose
sions: product differentiation and low-cost produc- the risk of cost overruns upon the hospital
tion. Hospitals pursuing a differentiation strategy through the use of fixed-price reimbursement
are expected to focus resources on clinical care to contracts. Such hospitals will likely need more
the detriment of administrative systems, such as functional cost systems to control costs. Taken
the cost system. Conversely, hospitals emphasizing together, literature on contingency theory and
cost control will have more functional cost systems hospital cost-system design suggests the following
because managers will require more information hypotheses:
for monitoring costs.
Structural determinants include case mix, teach-
ing affiliation, size, and whether a hospital is a
member of a multi-hospital system. Prior studies 13
Hill (2001) found that during the 1980s, for-profit
have found positive associations between these hospitals were less likely to adopt more functional cost systems
determinants and cost-system functionality than their nonprofit counterparts, presumably because for-
(Counte & Glandon, 1988; Hill & Johns, 1994; profit hospitals could better avoid the Medicare revenue
constraints of that period. However, she speculated that during
Lawrence, 1990). Case mix measures the severity the 1990s, managed care would place increased pressure on for-
of cases treated. Teaching hospitals, which typi- profits to control costs.
cally treat more severe cases, are more complex 14
Hospital districts, typically found in rural areas, are
organizationally due to their research and educa- municipal entities composed of elected officials. Hospital
tional responsibilities. As complexity increases, district commissioners have the power to levy taxes to subsidize
operations.
so does the need for cost information (Karmarkar 15
Managed-care organizations (MCOs) often impose strict
et al., 1990). Larger hospitals and system hospitals cost-control measures on hospitals and negotiate lower prices
will benefit more from functional cost systems be- than other insurers.
188 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

H2a. Managers’ beliefs about the relevance and Table 1


usefulness of cost data are positively associ- Descriptive statistics comparison of sample means to national
averages
ated with the degree to which cost-system
functionality is aligned with the hospital’s National averages Sample means
strategy, structure, and external environment. Beds 185 272
H2b. Actual financial performance is positively Case mix 1.27 1.40
For profit 18.3% 7.2%
associated with the degree to which cost-sys- System members 39.5% 41.2%
tem functionality is aligned with the hospital’s Teaching hospitals 22.7% 36.8%
strategy, structure, and external environment. Medicare 51.6% 52.7%
Metropolitan 62.8% 67.7%

Research method
tion sufficient to characterize cost-system
Data functionality. External data on financial perfor-
mance and control variables were available for
The hypotheses are tested using survey data col- 277 of the 313 hospitals. Table 1 presents descrip-
lected in conjunction with fellow researchers at the tive statistics for the 277-hospital sample and all
University of PennsylvaniaÕs Wharton School of US hospitals. The sample is predominantly com-
Business and the Hospital Financial Management posed of metropolitan hospitals that are larger
Association (HFMA). The initial questionnaire than the national average and treat relatively more
was based upon the extant literature and inter- complex cases. Compared to all US hospitals, the
views with financial managers from five hospitals. sample contains more teaching hospitals (36.8%
The survey was then reviewed by personnel from vs. 24.5%) and fewer for-profit hospitals (7.2%
HFMA, and modified as required. We sent the vs. 15.4%). 17
survey to financial managers at 1703 hospitals.
Personnel at HFMA distributed 1042 surveys to Cost-system functionality measures
members in September 1997, and the business
school researchers sent another 661 surveys to hos- The survey asked 20 questions relating to cost-
pitals that were not included in the HFMA mail- system attributes. The responses were standardized
ing. 16 After two months, surveys were mailed a to a common scale, and factor analysis was used to
second time to hospitals that did not respond to reduce the dimensionality of the questions. 18 Four
the initial mailing. factors emerged with eigenvalues in excess of one,
We received 385 completed surveys from Octo- with the factor solution retaining 65% of the total
ber 1997 through January 1998. Sixteen surveys variation in the data (Table 2). Following ortho-
were rendered undeliverable and returned uno- gonal rotation, the four factors are: DETAIL,
pened because the contact could not be located CLASSIFY, FREQUENT, and VARIANCE.
or the hospital had closed. Consequently, person-
nel at 1687 of the 1703 hospitals actually received
the surveys. Of these, 385 responded, yielding a 17
The sample may be skewed towards larger hospitals and
22.8% response rate. Eleven specialty hospitals teaching hospitals because such hospitals have greater active
were eliminated because their activities were not representation in HFMA, the industry group that helped to
comparable to acute-care facilities. Of the remain- distribute the survey.
18
Calculating the functionality measures from multiple
ing 374 responses, 313 surveys provided informa-
items should reduce the error associated with any single-item
measure. Some of the hospitals failed to respond to all survey
questions. Rather than exclude these hospitals from the
16
We generally addressed the surveys to the Chief Financial analysis, missing values were imputed prior to the factor
Officer, the Controller, or the Chief Executive Officer. However, analysis. Following Beal and Little (1975), the missing data
lower-ranking individuals in the accounting or finance func- were imputed using conditional means obtained from a stepwise
tions often responded to the surveys. ordinary least squares regression.
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 189

Table 2
Factor structure correlations following orthogonal rotationa,b,c
DETAIL CLASSIFY FREQUENT VARIANCE Questionsd
Customize 0.55 . . . The cost accounting system can easily customize
reports to the specification of users
By payer 0.86 . . . To what extent does system provide data that
allow you to analyze costs by payer?
By contract 0.84 . . . To what extent does system provide data that
allow you to analyze costs by contract?
By physician 0.82 . . . To what extent does system provide data that
allow you to analyze costs by physician?
By procedure 0.74 . . . To what extent does system provide data that
allow you to analyze costs by procedure?
Per diem 0.75 . . . To what extent does system provide data that
allow you to analyze costs on a per diem basis?
By patient 0.85 . . . To what extent does system provide data that
allow you to analyze costs per patient?
Direct/indirect . 0.72 . . Does your cost system have a formalized method
of distinguishing direct and indirect costs?
Controllable . 0.77 . . Does your cost system have a formalized method
of distinguishing fixed and variable costs?
Fixed/variable . 0.55 . . Does your cost system have a formalized method
of distinguishing control/non-controllable costs?
Track F/V . 0.64 . . How sophisticated is method used to tracked fixed
and variable costs?
Use RCC . 0.63 . . To what extent is RCC used to estimate the costs
of individual services and procedures?
Frequent1 . . 0.83 . How often does the cost accounting system report
information to senior managers?
Frequent2 . . 0.85 . How often does the cost accounting system report
information to middle managers?
Frequent3 . . 0.79 . How often does the cost accounting system report
information to clinical managers?
Frequent4 . . 0.76 . How often does the cost accounting system report
information to nursing staff?
Frequent5 . . 0.77 . How often does the cost accounting system report
information to medical staff?
Efficiency variance . . . 0.68 Does your system calculate efficiency variances?
Mix variance . . . 0.58 Does your system calculate case mix variances?
Price variance . . . 0.76 Does your system calculate price variances?
Cronbach Alpha 0.93 0.83 0.88 0.53
a
‘‘.’’ Indicates correlation of less than 0.50.
b
Only factors with eigenvalues in excess of 1.0 were included. The lowest eigenvalue of included factors was 1.24 for the VARI-
ANCE construct.
c
DETAIL––the level of detail provided by the system. CLASSIFY––the systemÕs ability to classify costs according to behavior.
FREQUENT––the frequency with which cost information is disseminated throughout the organization. VARIANCE––the type and
number of variances calculated.
d
Questions were recoded, if necessary, such that higher values indicate greater functionality. For example, Use RCC was recoded
so that higher values indicate less use of RCC, and thus, greater functionality. All questions and response scales are included in the
Appendix.

DETAIL encompasses the extent to which the sys- costs according to their behavior and the method-
tem can accumulate costs at various levels of detail ology used to classify costs. FREQUENT captures
(e.g., per patient, per diem, etc.). CLASSIFY mea- the frequency with which cost-system reports are
sures the degree to which the system can classify distributed to various administrative and clinical
190 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

Table 3
Comparison of mean values of functionality constructsa for hospitals that received JCAHO accreditation and those that did not
Not JCAHO, accredited (n = 23) JCAHO, accredited (n = 270) t-Statistica,b
DETAIL –0.830 0.080 31.23***
CLASSIFY –0.498 0.046 11.93***
FREQUENT –0.206 0.030 2.03*
VARIANCE –0.262 0.041 3.51**
*p < 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided).
a
Functionality constructs are calculated by taking the means of standardized responses to questions that loaded greater than 0.50
on a single factor from the factor analysis (Table 2). The actual responses were standardized to a mean of 0 and standard deviation of
1. DETAIL––the level of detail provided by the system. CLASSIFY––the systemÕs ability to classify costs according to behavior.
FREQUENT––the frequency with which cost information is disseminated throughout the organization. VARIANCE––the type and
number of variances calculated.
b
Two-sample t-statistic for test of hypothesis that values of functionality constructs for accredited hospitals are greater than those
of non-accredited hospitals. Results are similar if control variables for hospital structure and market conditions are included by using a
logistical regression.

personnel and proxies for the timeliness with cost-system functionality is accreditation by the
which the system can report on recent events and Joint Commission on the Accreditation of Health-
provide feedback (Chenhall & Morris, 1986; care Organizations (JCAHO). The JCAHO is an
Eldenburg, 1994; Karmarkar et al., 1990). VARI- independent agency that evaluates the operational
ANCE measures the number of variances the sys- efficiency of US hospitals. 20 Some of the specific
tem calculates. 19 areas the JCAHO examines include organizational
The questions were designed to be as objective improvement initiatives, leadership initiatives,
as possible, although we could not completely management of information, and management of
ignore subjective assessments. The goal was to human resources. 21 Thus, it is expected that hos-
understand what kind of analysis and functions pitals with systems that meet accreditation stan-
the system could actually perform. dards also have more functional cost systems. As
Each factor represents a different dimension of shown in Table 3, the standardized values of all
cost-system functionality, which is measured using four functionality measures are significantly greater
the average standardized responses to questions for hospitals that have received JCAHO accredi-
loading greater than 0.50 on a single construct tation than those that have not. The difference is
(see the Appendix for exact questions and their especially significant (p < 0.001, one-sided) for the
coding). CronbachÕs coefficient alphas range from DETAIL and CLASSIFY constructs.
0.53 to 0.93 (Table 2) and thus indicate that the re- The remaining proxies for cost-system function-
sponses used to calculate each functionality con- ality are based upon individual survey questions
struct are internally consistent. To further (see the Appendix for exact questions and coding).
establish that the four cost-system design con- One proxy is the extent to which a hospitalÕs cost
structs actually capture a systemÕs functional capa- system differs from that used to comply with Medi-
bility, they are correlated with measures that proxy care reporting requirements (denoted differs from
for cost-system functionality. The first proxy for Medicare). Systems designed to comply with min-
imum Medicare cost-reporting requirements pro-

19 20
The questions that load on the VARIANCE factor have Accreditation reports are available on the JCAHOÕs
dichotomous (0, 1) responses. Technically, dichotomous website: www.JCAHO.org.perfrep.
21
responses should not be included in a factor analysis. If While the JCAHO is responsible for attesting to the
variance questions are removed, the factor solution gives three quality of care, most of the measures address operational
factors with similar loadings to those reported when the efficiency. This has prompted many hospitals to forgo the
variance questions are included. voluntary accreditation process (Burda, 2002).
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 191

Table 4
Pearson correlations of functionality constructs with proxies for functionalitya,b
Differs from Medicare (n = 300) Accuracy (n = 304) Allocation bases (n = 304) Timely (n = 304)
DETAIL 0.42 0.42 0.54
CLASSIFY 0.54 0.35 0.61
FREQUENT 0.31
VARIANCE 0.28
a
All correlations are statistically significant at the 0.001 level (two-sided).
b
Proxies for cost-system functionality were computed from the following questions: Differs from Medicare: ‘‘To what extent is you
organizationÕs cost accounting system different from the Medicare cost reporting system? (1 = same, 7 = completely different).
Accuracy: ‘‘The cost accounting system provides accurate data.’’ (1 = strongly agree, 7 = strongly disagree). Allocation bases: ‘‘In
allocating costs in revenue departments to a specific procedure, how many separate bases does your hospital use?’’ (N/A, 1, 2–3, 4–6,
>6). Timely: ‘‘Users receive information from the cost accounting function in a timely manner.’’ (1 = strongly agree, 7 = strongly
disagree). Functionality constructs are described in notes to Table 3.

vide very little information that is relevant for The proxy variable, allocation bases, measures
managerial decision making (Evans, Hwang, & the number of separate bases used to allocate costs
Nagarajan, 1997; Meeting & Harvey, 1998; Tsel- from revenue-producing departments to specific
epis, 1989; West & Balas, 1996). 22 Accordingly, procedures. A larger number of allocation bases
many hospitals have either augmented the Medi- suggests greater homogeneity within individual
care cost-reporting system or developed a separate cost pools and a stronger association between
system to manage costs. Thus, the more a hospi- activities that give rise to the costs in the pools
talÕs cost system differs from the Medicare report- and the activities used to allocate these costs. It
ing system, the more functional it is expected to be. is expected that cost systems that can provide high
As shown in Table 4, the DETAIL, CLASSIFY, levels of detail and meaningfully classify costs will
and VARIANCE constructs are all significantly use more allocation bases (Cooper & Kaplan,
(p < 0.001, two-sided) and positively correlated 1991, Chapter 5). Consistent with this premise,
with the variable differs from Medicare. In particu- allocation bases is positively and significantly
lar, the DETAIL and CLASSIFY correlations are (p < 0.001, two-sided) correlated with DETAIL
0.42 and 0.54 respectively. The next proxy vari- (r = 0.54) and CLASSIFY (r = 0.61). Finally, the
able, accuracy, is calculated from survey partici- survey asks participants to rate the timeliness with
pantsÕ ratings of the accuracy of cost-system which the cost system provides data. This question
data. Both DETAIL and CLASSIFY are posi- is reflected in the variable, timely, which is posi-
tively (r = 0.42 and 0.35, respectively) and signifi- tively and significantly correlated with FRE-
cantly (p < 0.001, two-sided) correlated with QUENT (r = 0.31, p < 0.001). 23
accuracy (Table 4). This suggests that systems that
can provide more detailed cost information are not
simply assigning costs arbitrarily to various cost
23
objects. Furthermore, consistent with the asser- Note that only FREQUENT is correlated with timely
tions of activity-based costing proponents, the because I do not expect the other functionality constructs
(DETAIL, for e.g.) to contribute to the timeliness with which
managers reported that systems that could better
data are reported. Conversely, FREQUENT is not correlated
classify costs according to behavior were more with the following functionality proxies, differs from Medicare,
accurate (Cooper & Kaplan, 1991, Chapter 5). accuracy, and allocation bases because it is not expected that
more frequent reporting of cost data would contribute to the
extent to which a system differs from Medicare, system
22
Medicare reimbursements received from the US Govern- accuracy, or the number of allocation bases used. Similarly,
ment average close to 50% of a hospitalÕs total revenues. To the extent to which variances are calculated is not expected to
obtain these reimbursements, hospitals must file a Medicare influence accuracy, nor is it expected to relate to the number of
Cost Report. allocation bases.
192 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

Performance measures Although a nonprofit hospitalÕs objective is not


the accumulation of residual profits, financial vari-
ManagersÕ beliefs about cost system data and ables are still important in evaluating manage-
actual performance help determine whether more mentÕs success in meeting hospital objectives. 25
functional cost systems provide more relevant cost In his classic characterization of the nonprofit hos-
data, which managers can potentially use to make pital, Newhouse (1970) reasoned that a nonprofit
performance-enhancing decisions. hospitalÕs mission is to maximize the quantity
and quality of service subject to a zero-budget con-
straint and that revenues in excess of expenses are
Managers’ beliefs about the relevance and
reinvested in facilities to improve quality and ac-
usefulness of cost data
cess. More recently, Prince (1998) contended that
The relevance of cost data is measured by com-
steady operating profits are necessary to make
paring managersÕ beliefs about the need for cost
ongoing investments in equipment and facilities
information to the information actually supplied
simply to keep pace with the rapid advancements
by the cost system. The survey asks hospital man-
in medical technology. Consistent with both New-
agers to rate the importance of cost information in
house and Prince, Nelson, Rust, Zahorik, and
performing ten managerial activities, including
Rose (1992) found that patient beliefs about qual-
performance evaluation, contract negotiation,
ity were positively associated with financial perfor-
budgeting, and pricing (see the Appendix for ques-
mance. The importance of financial performance
tions and coding). The survey also requests that
in hospitals is further evidenced by the recent trend
managers specify the extent to which the existent
toward the use of financial measures in evaluating
cost system provides information that can be used
hospital executives (Early & Cleverly, 1995; Moli-
to perform these 10 managerial activities. I take an
nari et al., 1997). 26 Brickley and Van Horne
average of the differences between managersÕ rat-
(2002) found that financial performance (return
ings of: (1) the importance of cost information in
on assets) was positively associated with CEO
performing an activity and (2) the extent to which
pay and negatively associated with CEO turnover
the system actually provides information for per-
in nonprofit hospitals. Moreover, the turnover/
forming the activity. The smaller the difference,
performance relation appeared stronger in non-
the closer the system is to supplying all of a man-
profit hospitals than in for-profit hospitals.
agerÕs information needs. To calculate a measure
Perhaps even more important than the direct
of relevance (denoted relevant), the differences
pay-for-performance link is the opportunity for
are subtracted from the maximum difference so
managers to materially increase their wealth by
that the larger the value of relevant, the better
moving to larger, higher-paying hospitals (Leone
the system meets mangersÕ needs. The usefulness
& Van Horne, 1999). Finally, in the US, many
of cost-system information is measured with a sin-
nonprofit hospitals actively compete with for-prof-
gle question that asks respondents to rate the ex-
it hospitals. In such instances, Duggan (2002)
tent to which users rely on cost-system data to
found that nonprofit hospitals mimic the behavior
make decisions (use).
of their for-profit counterparts.

Actual financial performance


Hospital financial performance is assessed 25
Financial performance is a key factor in HCIAÕs deter-
with objective, publicly available information. 24 mination of the ‘‘Top 100’’ hospitals. Five of the eight measures
used to determine the ‘‘Top 100’’ are financial or operational
( ‘ ‘ 100 To p Ho s p i t a l s : B e nc h ma r k s f or Su c ce s s , ’ ’
www.HCIA.com).
24 26
While the quality of care is of utmost importance, it not According to a 1997 Hay Group Survey, 59% of nonprofit
used as a performance measure because escalating healthcare hospitals and 92% of for-profit hospitals use a performance
costs (and not concerns with quality) prompted the redesign of incentive for senior executives that includes financial measures
cost systems. (Fralicx & Liccione, 1997).
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 193

Table 5
Sample means and Pearson correlations for financial performance measuresa,b (number of observations)
N Mean Cash flow Administrative expense Expense per admit
Profit margin 272 4.72% 0.627 (272)*** 0.078 (272) 0.213 (272)***
Cash flow 277 46,590 0.060 (277) 0.050 (276)
Administrative expense 277 11.90% 0.053 (276)
Expense per admit 276 4,199
a
*p < 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided).
b
Profit margin–operating profit margin (%). Operating profit as a percentage of operating revenue. Excludes funds from charitable
contributions and other non-operating revenue. Cash flow––cash flow per bed. Administrative expense––administrative expense ratio.
Administrative expense divided by total operating expense. Expense per admit––operating expense per case-mix adjusted admission.

Data on hospital profitability and cost control cost systems. The administrative expense ratio
come from the SDC Platinum Hospital Industry (administrative expense) is the ratio of administra-
Database. 27 Given the importance of investment tive expenses to total operating expenses, and it
to a hospitalÕs objective function, I selected two measures managementÕs ability to control expenses
measures of profitability that reflect funds avail- that are not directly related to patient care. Elden-
able on an ongoing basis to reinvest and service burg et al. (2004) used the administrative expense
debt: operating profit margin (operating margin) ratio to predict CEO turnover. Case-mix adjusted
and cash flow per bed (cash flow). 28 Both mea- operating cost per adjusted admission (expense per
sures exclude funds obtained from charitable con- admit) is a measure of the hospitalÕs average total
tributions and other non-operating additions to cost for delivering care on a per unit basis, ad-
income; and therefore, they provide a clear picture justed for severity (HCIA, 1997, p. 150). 30
of the hospitalÕs underlying operations. 29 As
shown in Table 5, operating margin and cash flow Control variables
per bed are highly correlated (r = 0.63). However,
both performance measures are retained because As discussed during the development of the
operating margin includes a major non-cash ex- hypotheses relating to contingency theory, various
pense, depreciation, which serves as a barometer elements of a hospitalÕs structure, strategy and
for medical technology. One way a hospital man- environment potentially influence cost-system de-
ager can improve operating margin is to forgo sign. Of these variables, those that also have been
quality-improving investments in medical technol- found to influence performance are included as
ogy that increase depreciation expense. control variables. Structural control variables are
Two measures of hospital costs are included be- size, case mix, teaching status, for-profit status,
cause cost control is typically cited as one of the and system membership. Prior research has found
primary reasons hospitals adopt more functional positive relations between size and costs (Elden-
burg, 1994; Lawrence, 1990). Size is measured by
27
SDC Platinum is a proprietary product of the Securities
the number of available beds set up and staffed
Data Company. SDC obtains information for its hospital (beds). Case mix (denoted case mix) is expected
database from HCIA, Inc. to be positively associated with profitability and
28
All three profitability measures are significantly and cost measures, as more severe cases typically gen-
positively correlated with a hospitalÕs index of predictive erate higher costs and higher margins (Lawrence,
creditworthiness. The index of predictive creditworthiness is
HCIAÕs comprehensive, quantitative assessment of a hospitalÕs
future financial viability.
29 30
Similar results (in terms of statistical significance) are Admissions are adjusted by multiplying the number of
obtained if operating margin and cash flow per bed are replaced acute care discharges by a factor that inflates it to include
with operating revenue per admission, net income margin, and inpatient acute care, inpatient nonacute care, and outpatient
cash margin. HCIA, Inc. uses cash flow margin in its evaluation care. Case-mix adjustments account for differences in complex-
of the ‘‘Top 100 Hospitals’’. ity, according to the Medicare case mix.
194 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

1990). Teaching hospitals (denoted teach, where nual survey. The Health Care Financing Associa-
1 = teaching hospital, 0 otherwise) are expected tion reports wage indices on its website.
to have higher costs due to the added expenses InterStudy Publications calculates MCO penetra-
associated with teaching, research, and use of the tion as the number of MCO enrollees in an area di-
latest technology. For-profit hospitals (denoted vided by the areaÕs population. The variable
for profit, where 1 = for-profit, 0 otherwise) are managed is determined from a survey question
predicted to have higher profitability and lower about payer mix (see the Appendix).
costs, consistent with their goal of increasing
ownersÕ wealth. Hospitals that are members of Correlations among measures of cost-system
multi-hospital systems (denoted system, where functionality and control variables
1 = system member, 0 otherwise) are also likely
to attain higher performance because they can Table 6 contains a correlation matrix of the cost-
attract more capable managers, share knowledge system measures and control variables. Because the
across facilities, negotiate shared purchase agree- four cost-system design constructs relate to the
ments with suppliers, obtain quantity discounts, same system, they are significantly and positively
and negotiate more favorable labor contracts correlated. The variables DETAIL and CLAS-
(Lawrence, 1990). 31 SIFY are highly correlated (r = 0.68). However,
Controls for environmental factors include this correlation seems reasonable because the ex-
measures of competition (denoted competition), tent to which a system can classify costs (CLAS-
MCO penetration (denoted MCO penetration), SIFY) affects the level of detail the system can
the local wage level (denoted wage), and payer provide (DETAIL). 32 Several control variables
mix. Competition is expected to be negatively are also highly correlated with each other. Size is
associated with all performance measures, as hos- significantly correlated with case mix (r = 0.69)
pitals in highly competitive environments typically and the teaching indicator variable (r = 0.55) be-
have lower operating margins and greater incen- cause large teaching institutions treat the most
tive to control costs. MCO penetration is expected complex cases. Competition is significantly corre-
to bring down local price levels. The wage index lated with HMO penetration (r = 0.54) and the
accounts for geographic differences in the cost of wage index (r = 0.58). However, all control vari-
living and price levels. Payer mix is captured by ables are retained to ensure a conservative and ro-
the percentage of revenues received from managed bust test of the relation between performance and
care (denoted managed) and Medicare (denoted functionality. 33
Medicare). Both measures are expected to be neg-
atively associated with financial performance.
All control variables come from the SDC Plati- Results
num Database, except for competition, wage, MCO
penetration, and managed. Competition is calcu- The hypotheses are tested by examining rela-
lated as one minus the sum of squared market tions between managersÕ beliefs about cost data
shares based upon beds in a county using data from and actual financial performance and both the
the American Hospital AssociationÕs (AHA) an- absolute level of cost-system functionality and
the extent to which cost-system functionality is

31
These variables also potentially control for managerial
32
skill (Fralicx & Liccione, 1997; Lawrence, 1990; Leone & Van Both measures were retained because factor analysis of
Horne, 1999). This poses a concern if more capable managers, the relevant survey questions gave two different constructs.
who enable hospitals to achieve better performance, are also Using factor scores from the orthogonal rotation, which gives
more likely to update hospital cost systems. Specifically, larger uncorrelated constructs, yields similar results in tests of the
hospitals, system hospitals, and for-profit hospitals are expected research question.
33
to attract more sophisticated managers, and they are expected None of the independent variables has a variance inflation
to achieve better financial performance. factor in excess of 3.0 in any of the reported regressions.
Table 6

M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210


Pearson correlations of functionality constructs and control variablesa,b (N = 277)
FREQUENT CLASSIFY VARIANCE Beds Case mix For profit System Competition Wages MCO penetration Managed Medicare
DETAIL 0.34*** 0.68*** 0.39*** 0.34*** 0.39*** 0.05 0.23*** 0.29*** 0.14** 0.23*** 0.19*** 0.08
FREQUENT 0.26*** 0.31*** 0.12** 0.14** 0.09 0.16*** 0.06 0.01 0.04 0.04 0.11*
CLASSIFY 0.34*** 0.28*** 0.34*** 0.03 0.17*** 0.33*** 0.17*** 0.25*** 0.20*** 0.12*
VARIANCE 0.21*** 0.28*** 0.09 0.18*** 0.22*** 0.09 0.14** 0.13** 0.09
Beds 0.71*** 0.09 0.11* 0.42*** 0.22*** 0.31*** 0.24*** 0.36***
Case mix 0.10 0.22*** 0.51*** 0.26*** 0.38*** 0.35*** 0.41***
For profit 0.16*** 0.04 0.03 0.01 0.02 0.05
System 0.17*** 0.02 0.05 0.06 0.07
Competition 0.52*** 0.55*** 0.45*** 0.47***
Wages 0.57*** 0.42*** 0.35***
MCO 0.46*** 0.32***
penetration
Managed 0.42***
a
*p < 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided).
b
DETAIL––the level of detail provided by the system. CLASSIFY––the systemÕs ability to classify costs according to behavior. FREQUENT––the frequency with
which cost information is disseminated throughout the organization. VARIANCE––the type and number of variances calculated. Size––total number of beds set up and
staffed divided by 1000. Mix––Medicare case-mix index. For profit––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a for-profit entity, and zero otherwise. System––an
indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is part of a multi-hospital system and zero otherwise. Teach––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a teaching hospital
and zero otherwise. Competition––calculated as 1––sum of squared market shares, based upon beds in a county. Wages––Medicare wage index for MSA or state. MCO
penetration––MCO penetration. The number of MCO enrollees in an MSA divided by the areaÕs population. Managed––percentage of revenue received from managed
care. Medicare––percentage of revenue received from Medicare.

195
196 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

aligned with a hospitalÕs strategy, structure, and Table 7


environment. Association between absolute level of cost-system functionality
and managersÕ evaluations of the relevance and usefulness of
cost dataa,b
The level of cost-system functionality
Relevant Use

In tests of the level of functionality, variables Intercept 2.074*** (7.73) 0.447*** (0.76)
DETAIL 0.141*** (3.05) 0.274*** (2.72)
capturing managersÕ beliefs and actual perfor- CLASSIFY 0.081* (1.73) 0.039 (0.38)
mance are regressed on the four cost-system attri- FREQUENT 0.098*** (2.73) 0.112 (1.43)
butes (DETAIL, CLASSIFY, FREQUENT, and VARIANCE 0.026 (0.63) 0.073 (0.82)
VARIANCE) and the control variables. The re- Control Variablesc
sults for managersÕ beliefs about the relevance Beds 0.420* (1.96) 0.074 (0.16)
and usefulness of cost data are contained in Table Case mix 0.299* (1.73) 0.143 (0.38)
7. Both models are significant (p > 0.001) and the System 0.167*** (2.97) 0.122 (0.99)
Medicare 0.004 (1.72) 0.002 (0.40)
adjusted r-squareds are 0.228 and 0.125 for rele-
7.25*** 4.03***
vant and use respectively. 34 The coefficient on DE- Adj. R2 0.228 0.125
TAIL is positive and highly significant (p < 0.01, N 277 277
two-sided) for both measures. The coefficients for a
*p < 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), *** (2-sided), t-
CLASSIFY and FREQUENT are positively and statistics in ( ).
b
significantly associated with data relevance Relevant––ManagersÕ perceptions regarding the extent to
(p < 0.10 and p < 0.01, two-sided, respectively), which managers believe that cost data meets their information
needs. Use––ManagersÕ perceptions regarding the extent to
but neither is associated with usefulness. However,
which they rely on cost data to make decisions. See Appendix
recall that DETAIL and CLASSIFY are highly (p. A-2) for questions used to calculate relevant and use.
correlated (r = 0.68). If DETAIL is eliminated DETAIL––the level of detail provided by the system. CLAS-
from either model, the coefficients on CLASSIFY SIFY––the systemÕs ability to classify costs according to
and FREQUENT increase in significance in the behavior. FREQUENT––the frequency with which cost infor-
mation is disseminated throughout the organization. VARI-
relevant regression (p < 0.01, two-sided), and they
ANCE––the type and number of variances calculated.
become significant in the use regression (p < 0.05, c
Only statistically significant control variables are included
two-sided). Because all the variables are standard- in table. Control variables used in the regression are as follows:
ized, one can interpret the coefficients on the Size––total number of beds set up and staffed divided by 1000.
DETAIL construct, for example, as follows: a Mix––Medicare case-mix index. For profit––an indicator vari-
able that is 1 if the hospital is a for-profit entity, and zero
1-standard deviation increase in DETAIL is asso-
otherwise. System––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital
ciated with a 0.14-standard deviation increase in is part of a multi-hospital system and zero otherwise. Teach––
relevance and a 0.27-standard deviation increase an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a teaching
in usefulness of cost data. The VARIANCE con- hospital and zero otherwise. Competition––calculated as 1––
struct is not associated with managersÕ beliefs sum of squared market shares, based upon beds in a county.
Wages––Medicare wage index for MSA or state. MCO pene-
about data relevance or usefulness. This result is
tration––MCO penetration. The number of MCO enrollees in
consistent with claims that traditional variance an MSA divided by the areaÕs population. Managed––percent-
analysis is not a useful management tool (e.g., age of revenue received from managed care. Medicare––per-
Bastable & Bao, 1988; Cheatham & Cheatham, centage of revenue received from Medicare.

34
WhiteÕs (1980) test indicates no evidence of heteroskedas- 1996; Cooper & Kaplan, 1992; Mak & Roush,
ticity. Shapiro and Wilk (1965) tests indicate that the residuals 1996), and that budgeting is not well suited to hos-
are not distributed normally; however, histograms and normal pital environments (Abernethy & Vagnoni, 2004;
probability plots indicate the residuals are close to normal. Covaleski & Dirsmith, 1986; Kurunmäki, 1999).
Elimination of observations with the greatest influence, as
measured by the change in a regression coefficient when an
The relevance and usefulness of cost-system
observation is omitted from the analysis (DFBETA), had no data are critical to the assertion that cost-system
material impact on the results. design can be used to enhance financial perfor-
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 197

Table 8
a,b
Association between the absolute level of cost-system functionality and financial performance
Operating profit Cash flow Administrative expensec Expense per admitc
Intercept 8.874* (1.92) 16,598 (0.66) 9.518*** (4.265) 2,070*** (3.36)
DETAIL 1.264** (1.97) 11,899*** (3.36) 0.555* (1.77) 83 (0.75)
CLASSIFY 0.257 (0.40) 135 (0.04) 0.287 (0.92) 11 (0.10)
FREQUENT 0.515 (1.06) 814 (0.30) 0.086 (0.36) 15 ( 0.18)
VARIANCE 0.809 (1.46) 19,264** (2.53) 0.820*** (3.02) 48 (0.51)
Control variablesd
Beds 0.984 (0.34) 21,864 (1.36) 3.771*** (2.65) 924** (2.11)
Case mixe 4.913** (2.06) 52,869*** (4.07) 1.176 (1.02)
For profit 3.673** (2.55) 2,003 (0.25) 1.590** (2.28) 81 (0.33)
System 1.389* (1.80) 9,107** (2.14) 1.147*** (3.05) 18 (0.14)
Teach 0.827 (0.82) 2,836 (0.52) 0.408 (1.02) 516*** (3.07)
Competition 2.504 (1.56) 7,487 (0.86) 1.876** (2.42) 169 (0.62)
Wages 7.047** (2.31) 29,216* (1.74) 3.506** (2.35) 2,333*** (4.45)
MCO penetration 4.693 (1.59) 37,314** (2.27) 0.609 (0.42) 827 (1.62)
F 2.862*** 5.382*** 5.553*** 7.371***
Adj. R2 0.088 0.182 0.188 0.232
N 272 277 277 276
a
*p 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided), t-statistics in ( ) below coefficient.
b
DETAIL––the level of detail provided by the system. CLASSIFY––the systemÕs ability to classify costs according to behavior.
FREQUENT––the frequency with which cost information is disseminated throughout the organization. VARIANCE––the type and
number of variances calculated.
c
Smaller values are considered favorable because they indicate better cost control or greater efficiency.
d
Only statistically significant control variables are included in table. Control variables used in the regression are as follows: Size––
total number of beds set up and staffed divided by 1000. Mix––Medicare case-mix index. For profit––an indicator variable that is 1 if
the hospital is a for-profit entity, and zero otherwise. System––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is part of a multi-hospital
system and zero otherwise. Teach––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a teaching hospital and zero otherwise. Compe-
tition––calculated as 1––sum of squared market shares, based upon beds in a county. Wages––Medicare wage index for MSA or state.
MCO penetration––MCO penetration. The number of MCO enrollees in an MSA divided by the areaÕs population. Managed––
percentage of revenue received from managed care. Medicare––percentage of revenue received from Medicare.
e
Expense per admit is adjusted for case-mix; therefore, the case-mix variable is not included as a control.

mance. Unless more highly functional cost systems costs, and distribute information more frequently
provide more relevant and useful data that lead to and broadly can lead to enhanced financial
‘‘better’’ decisions, they should be unrelated to dif- performance. 36
ferences in financial performance. 35 Accordingly, Table 8 contains coefficients from the regression
the tests of managersÕ beliefs about the cost system of actual financial performance measures on the
provide a basis for the expectation that cost sys-
tems that can supply greater detail, better classify
36
In theory, if all hospitals have optimally selected their cost
35
As an alternative to separate regressions, I constructed a systems, there should be no relation between cost-system design
path model of the relation between cost-system functionality, and performance. While hospitals may choose optimally in the
managersÕ beliefs about relevance and usefulness, and actual long run, observers suggest that, in the short run, many
financial performance. The results of the path analysis were hospitals have not yet adjusted their cost systems to accom-
consistent with the causal model linking greater functionality modate the increased information needs created by sweeping
with increased data relevance and use. The total effects of the environmental changes (Hill & Johns, 1994; Orloff et al., 1990;
DETAIL and CLASSIFY constructs on financial performance Young & Pearlman, 1993). For example, a recent survey found
were positive and significant. However, the results of the path that while percent 80% of managers surveyed placed a high
model were not tabulated because the approach mixes the value on obtaining specific cost information, only 33%
relatively subjective relevance and use measures with the more expressed confidence in the quality of their cost data (Serb,
objective cost-system attribute and financial measures. 1997).
198 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

level of cost-system functionality. 37 All four mod- ciated with actual financial performance even
els are significant (p > 0.001) and the adjusted r- though managers find information that is reported
squareds range from 0.088 for operating profit to more frequently to be more relevant and useful.
0.232 for expense per admit. 38 The capability to Interestingly, hospitals that engage extensively in
provide more detail (DETAIL) is positively and variance analysis exhibit significantly lower cash
significantly associated with operating margin flow per bed (p < 0.05, two-sided) and relatively
(p < 0.05, two-sided) and cash flow per bed higher administrative costs (p < 0.01, two-sided).
(p < 0.01, two-sided). 39 DETAIL is negatively As discussed earlier, a potential explanation is that
associated with the administrative expense ratio greater use of variance analysis may lead to inap-
(p < 0.10, two-sided), which indicates that admin- propriate decisions. 40
istrative expenses are lower when a cost system Finally, operating expense per admission, which
can provide greater detail. The significant associa- is driven by clinical resource consumption, is not
tions between DETAIL and measures of both significantly associated with any of the functional-
managersÕ beliefs and financial performance sup- ity measures. This result is consistent with prior re-
port the premise that more highly functional sys- search suggesting that initial efforts to improve
tems provide more relevant and useful cost data, hospital performance typically focus on admin-
which lead to better financial performance. istrative processes and not clinical processes
Neither CLASSIFY nor FREQUENT is signif- (Shortell, Levin, OÕBrien, & Hughes, 1995).
icantly associated with performance in Table 8. Furthermore, as discussed previously, hospital
However, if the highly correlated DETAIL con- managers have little direct control over clinical
struct is removed from this regression, CLASSIFY expenditures because physicians control clinical
is positively and significantly associated with cash decisions. Only if managers present physicians
flow per bed (p < 0.05, two-sided). These results with appropriate cost data can managers poten-
are consistent with prior findings regarding man- tially influence physician behavior (Eldenburg,
agersÕ beliefs in that the ability to better classify 1994; Evans et al., 1995). Even then, the use of
data becomes highly significant only when DE- accounting information in directing physician
TAIL is removed from the regression. Although behavior raises significant concerns (e.g., Aber-
the factor analysis suggested that the ability to nethy & Stoelwinder (1996); Abernethy & Vag-
provide greater detail and the ability to classify noni, 2004; Chua & Degeling, 1991; Evans,
costs according to behavior are separate con- Hwang, & Nagarajan, 2003; Jones & Dewing,
structs, it is difficult to isolate their relations with 1997; Preston, 1992).
managersÕ beliefs about performance and actual In summary, there is some evidence that sys-
cash flow. The variable, FREQUENT, is not asso- tems that are better at supplying detail and classi-
fying costs provide more relevant and useful cost
37
data, which lead to better financial performance.
I also investigated two-way and three-way interactions
among the cost-system design constructs by including multipli-
However, a major concern with cross-sectional
cative terms. However, the high degree of multicolinearity tests is that they do not address causality. Specifi-
between the multiplicative terms and the individual constructs cally, better performing hospitals may have the
precluded a meaningful interpretation of the coefficients. means to invest in cost systems development; thus,
38
White (1980) test indicates no evidence of heteroskedas- strong financial performance could give rise to
ticity. Shapiro and Wilk (1965) tests suggest that only the
residuals of the cash flow regression are distributed normally.
more functional cost systems. Still, if it is the case
However, histograms and normal probability plots indicate the
residuals are close to normal. Elimination of observations with
40
the greatest influence, as measured by the change in a regression To confirm the validity of the VARIANCE construct, I
coefficient when an observation is omitted from the analysis substituted each of the individual questions used to calculate
(DFBETA), had no material impact on the results. the VARIANCE construct in place of VARIANCE in the
39
DETAIL is also positively and significantly associated performance regressions The only notable difference was that
with revenue per bed, investment per bed, and the number of those hospitals using price variances had significantly higher
admissions per bed (p < 0.10, two-tailed), an efficiency measure. expenses per admission.
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 199

that hospitals invest in cost systems simply because determined by the hospitalÕs organizational
they have excess funds, it is not clear that manag- context. 42
ers would find information supplied by more func- Following Chenhall and Langfield-Smith
tional systems to be more relevant or more useful. (1998), strategy is characterized along two dimen-
Only when managers believed that a specific sys- sions, product differentiation and cost control.
tem capability (i.e., supplied greater detail, better Product differentiation, denoted lead, is measured
classified costs) provided more relevant and useful by taking the average of three survey questions that
information was financial performance better. ask respondents to rate the importance of estab-
Causality is further examined in the extensions. lishing clinical leadership, technological leadership,
Alternatively, performance and cost-system func- and leadership in business processes. The extent to
tionality may be simultaneously determined. which hospitals follow a low-cost strategy, denoted
Simultaneity is considered in the next section. 41 cost, is quantified with two survey questions that
ask respondents to rate the importance of control-
Alignment with operating environment ling and eliminating unprofitable services. 43
To model cost-system functionality, I regress
The levels tests of the previous section assumed each functionality construct (DETAIL, CLAS-
that the appropriate benchmark for determining if SIFY, FREQUENT, VARIANCE) on measures
a system is ‘‘highly’’ functional is the average level of a hospitalÕs strategy, structure, and environ-
of cost-system functionality for all hospitals in the ment. Hospital structure is characterized by hospi-
sample. However, contingency theory contends the tal size (size), case mix (case mix), teaching status
appropriate benchmark is the expected level of (teaching), system ownership (system), and hospi-
functionality, given the hospitalÕs organizational tal district membership (district). The variable, dis-
context. Accordingly, I investigate associations be- trict, is set equal to 1 if a hospital is a member of a
tween financial performance and the residuals hospital district association, and it is 0 otherwise.
from an empirical model estimating the bench- The remaining variables were defined in the section
mark level of cost-system functionality as a func- on control variables. Environmental factors are
tion of hospital structure, strategy, and also captured by variables defined in the section
environment (Hypotheses 2a and 2b). The estima- on control variables: the level of competition (com-
tion of the benchmark model itself is an operation- petition), the degree of MCO penetration (MCO
alization of the selection approach to measuring fit penetration), and the percentage of managed (man-
between control system design and organizational aged) and Medicare (Medicare) patients in a hospi-
context (Selto et al., 1995, p. 669). The selection talÕs patient mix. As discussed in the section on
approach assumes that context drives organiza- contingency theory, all structural and market vari-
tional design, and therefore, defines fit in terms ables are expected to be positively associated with
of associations between context and control sys- functionality, except district, which is predicted to
tem design. The residuals from the benchmark be negatively associated with functionality.
model are a variant of the systems approach to Results of the benchmark regressions are con-
measuring fit (Selto et al., 1995, p. 670). The resid- tained in Table 9. The model has the greatest
uals measure variations in overall systematic fit as explanatory power for DETAIL (adjusted

42
Others have used the top performing organizations as the
41
HausmanÕs specification error test can potentially identify benchmark in determining systematic fit (Selto et al., 1995).
whether the independent variables are exogenous. However, This approach was not used here because, as discussed in
this test requires an instrumental variables estimate of the footnote 29, it is unlikely that hospital cost system design is in a
regression coefficient on the design construct, and there are no state of equilibrium.
43
obvious choices for instruments. Moreover, a simultaneous Each set of questions loads on a different factor. Cron-
equations approach renders a system of five equations with five bachÕs alphas are 0.56 and 0.52 for lead and cost, respectively.
endogenous variables. and thus would require four instrumen- Each variable is the average of the standardized responses to
tal variables. each set of questions.
200 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

Table 9
Regression of functionality constructs on hypothesized determinants of functional capabilitya,b,c
DETAIL CLASSIFY FREQUENT VARIANCE
INTERCEPT 1.857*** (4.15) 1.597 (3.75) 0.228 (0.48) 1.485*** (3.59)
Cost + 0.115* (1.86) (1.40) 0.243*** (3.69) 0.178*** (3.12)
Lead 0.080 (1.47) 0.040 (0.77) 0.050 (0.85) 0.032 (0.63)
Teach 0.180 (1.45) 0.079 (0.67) 0.028 (0.22) 0.156 (1.36)
Size +(1.33) 0.487 0.023 (0.07) 0.104 (0.27) 0.079 (0.23)
Case mix + 0.591** (1.99) 0.651** (2.31) 0.336 (1.06) 0.689** (2.52)
For profit + 0.188 (1.05) 0.165 (0.97) 0.298 (1.56) 0.329*** (1.99)
System + 0.204** (2.13) 0.142 (1.56) 0.224*** (2.20) 0.162* (1.84)
Competition + 0.194 (1.01) 0.284 (1.56) 0.241 (1.18) 0.111 (0.63)
MCO penetration + 0.226 (0.65) 0.396 (1.20) 0.109 (0.29) 0.106 (0.33)
Managed + 0.005 (1.08) 0.002 (0.57) 0.001 (0.32) 0.002 (0.46)
Medicare + 0.010** (2.49) 0.006 (1.64) 0.005 (1.12) 0.005 (1.35)
District 0.540*** (2.65) 0.601*** (3.11) 0.163 (0.75) 0.064 (0.34)
F 7.95*** 6.35*** 2.53*** 3.94***
Adj. R2 0.232 0.188 0.063 0.113
N 277 277 277 277
a
*p < 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided), t-statistics in ( ).
b
DETAIL––the level of detail provided by the system. CLASSIFY––the systemÕs ability to classify costs according to behavior.
FREQUENT––the frequency with which cost information is disseminated throughout the organization. VARIANCE––the type and
number of variances calculated.
c
Cost––the extent to which the hospital follows a cost-focused strategy. Lead––the extent to which the hospital follows a leadership
strategy. Size––total number of beds set up and staffed divided by 1000. Mix––Medicare case-mix index. For profit––an indicator
variable that is 1 if the hospital is a for-profit entity, and zero otherwise. System––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is part of
a multi-hospital system and zero otherwise. Teach––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a teaching hospital and zero
otherwise. Competition––calculated as 1––sum of squared market shares, based upon beds in a county. Wages––Medicare wage index
for MSA or state. MCO penetration––MCO penetration. The number of MCO enrollees in an MSA divided by the areaÕs population.
Managed––percentage of revenue received from managed care. Medicare––percentage of revenue received from Medicare. District––an
indicator variable that equals 1 if the hospital is a member of a hospital district association.

R2 = 0.23) and the least explanatory power for variables equal the absolute value of the residual
FREQUENT (adjusted R2 = 0.06). All statistically if it is negative, and zero otherwise. For example,
significant associations have the predicted sign. a large value of less FREQUENT indicates that
Low-cost strategic orientation, case mix, system the system reports cost information less frequently
ownership, and district membership have the than expected, given its operating environment.
strongest associations with cost-system functional- The relation between performance and cost-sys-
ity. Residuals from the benchmark model measure tem alignment is investigated by regressing perfor-
the extent to which the functionality of a hospitalÕs mance measures on the positive and negative
cost system differs from that expected, given the residuals and the control variables described in
hospitalÕs operating environment. Positive residu- prior tests. In addition to addressing hypotheses
als measure the degree to which a system is more 2a and 2b, this approach has two advantages.
functional than expected; they are denoted with First, it does not constrain the coefficients on the
the variables more DETAIL, more CLASSIFY, functionality measures to be the same regardless
more FREQUENT, and more VARIANCE. These of whether a system has relatively ‘‘too much’’ or
variables equal the residual if the residual is posi- ‘‘too little’’ functional capability. Second, the ap-
tive, and zero otherwise. Similarly, negative devia- proach provides a partial control for endogeneity
tions from expected indicate that the system has by modeling cost-system functionality as a func-
relatively little functionality, and they are denoted tion of a number of exogenous variables (e.g.,
with the variables less DETAIL, less CLASSIFY, competition, MCO penetration, etc.), as well as
less FREQUENT, and less VARIANCE. These three additional instrumental variables (cost, lead,
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 201

Table 10 mation to be significantly less relevant (p < 0.01,


Regression of managersÕ beliefs about relevance and usefulness two-sided) when it comes from systems that provide
on positive and negative residuals from benchmark
regressionsa,b
relatively less detail than expected (less DETAIL).
Residuals from the CLASSIFY benchmark model
Relevant Use
are significant only if the highly correlated residuals
Intercept 2.220*** ( 2.02) 1.508** (2.47) from the DETAIL benchmark model are re-
More DETAIL 0.297** (2.01) 0.561*** (2.75)
Less DETAIL 0.744*** ( 6.08) 0.043 (0.25)
moved. 45 In this case, more CLASSIFY is posi-
More CLASSIFY 0.034 (0.22) 0.077 (0.37) tively associated with relevant (p < 0.05, two-sided)
Less CLASSIFY 0.159 (1.36) 0.034 (0.21) and use (p < 0.10, two-sided), and less CLASSIFY
More FREQUENT 0.046 (0.36) 0.120 (0.67) is negatively associated with relevant (p < 0.01,
Less FREQUENT 0.115 (1.00) 0.090 (0.57) two-sided). Residuals from the FREQUENT and
More VARIANCE 0.013 (0.91) 0.096 (0.49)
Less VARIANCE 0.047 (0.35) 0.240 (1.26)
VARIANCE benchmark models are not signifi-
F 12.223*** 4.393*** cantly associated with managersÕ beliefs about the
Adj. R2 0.409 0.181 relevance and usefulness of cost data at all.
N 277 277 Table 11 contains regressions of financial per-
a
**p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided), t-statistics in ( ). formance on the measures of cost-system align-
b
Control variables are not included in table. Control vari- ment. With respect to the DETAIL construct,
ables used in the regression are as follows: Size––total number hospitals that have relatively greater functional
of beds set up and staffed divided by 1000. Mix––Medicare
case-mix index. For profit––an indicator variable that is 1 if the
capability than hospitals in similar operating envi-
hospital is a for-profit entity, and zero otherwise. System––an ronments have significantly higher operating mar-
indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is part of a multi- gins (p < 0.05, two-sided) and cash flow per bed
hospital system and zero otherwise. Teach––an indicator vari- (p < 0.05, two-sided). Hospitals with cost systems
able that is 1 if the hospital is a teaching hospital and zero that provide less detail than expected have lower
otherwise. Competition––calculated as 1––sum of squared
market shares, based upon beds in a county. Wages––Medicare
cash flow per bed (p < 0.10, two-sided) and incur
wage index for MSA or state. MCO penetration––MCO pene- proportionally higher administrative expenses
tration. The number of MCO enrollees in an MSA divided by (p < 0.10, two-sided). As in prior tests, residuals
the areaÕs population. Managed––percentage of revenue from the CLASSIFY benchmark model are signif-
received from managed care. Medicare––percentage of revenue icant only if the DETAIL residuals are removed.
received from Medicare.
In this case, less CLASSIFY is negatively associ-
ated with cash flow per bed (p < 0.05, two-sided),
and district) that are not included in the perfor-
suggesting that hospitals that do a relatively poor
mance regressions. 44
job of classifying costs have significantly lower
Table 10 contains regressions of managersÕ beliefs
cash flows. The relative frequency with which costs
about the relevance and usefulness of cost informa-
are reported is not associated with performance.
tion on the measures of cost-system alignment. Man-
Finally, hospitals that conduct relatively more var-
agers find cost information to be significantly more
iance analysis have significantly lower operating
relevant (p < 0.05, two-sided) and useful (p < 0.01,
margins (p < 0.05, two-sided). Overall, the results
two-sided) when it is supplied by systems that pro-
from residuals regressions are consistent with
vide relatively more detail than expected (more
those of the levels tests. This suggests that cost sys-
DETAIL). Correspondingly, managers find infor-
tems that have greater detail and classification
capabilities, relative to all hospitals and relative
44
Obviously, the strategy variables are also choice variables to their peers, achieve better performance. More-
for the hospital. I assume that these choices precede the choice over, there is nothing to indicate that the levels
of cost-system design, and are therefore exogenous to the choice tests have been confounded by endogeneity.
of cost-system attributes. Additional untabulated tests indicate
that these three variables are generally correlated with func-
45
tional capabilities and uncorrelated with the performance More DETAIL and more CLASSIFY have a correlation
measures, supporting their use as instruments in the function- of 0.53 (p < 0.01, two-sided); less DETAIL and less DETAIL
ality regressions and omission in the performance regressions. have correlation of 0.51 (p < 0.01, two-sided).
202 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

Table 11
Regression of profitability and cost measures on positive and negative residuals from benchmark regressionsa,b
Operating profit Cash flow Administrative expensec Expense per admitc
INTERCEP 8.196* (1.72) 4,877 (0.19) 8.923*** (3.89) 1,645** (2.51)
More DETAIL 2.862** (2.27) 14,788** (2.11) 0.187 (0.30) 271 (1.24)
Less DETAIL 0.124 (0.12) 10,138* (1.75) 0.873* (1.70) 4 (0.02)
More CLASSIFY 1.190 (0.92) 7,714 (1.07) 0.697 (1.10) 61 (0.27)
Less CLASSIFY 0.912 (0.91) 6,231 (1.13) 0.054 (0.11) 22 (0.13)
More FREQUENT 1.152 (1.04) 516 (0.08) 0.435 (0.80) 71 (0.37)
Less FREQUENT 0.198 (0.20) 77 (0.01) 0.557 (1.16) 74 (0.44)
More VARIANCE 2.539** (2.01) 10,690 (1.57) 0.826 (1.37) 88 (0.41)
Less VARIANCE 0.739 (0.63) 3,508 (0.54) 0.859 (1.49) 68 (0.33)
F 2.510*** 4.203*** 4.420*** 5.671***
Adj. R2 0.091 0.173 0.182 0.225
N 277 277 277 277
a
*p < 0.10 (2-sided), **p < 0.05 (2-sided), ***p < 0.01 (2-sided), t-statistics in ( ).
b
Control variables are not included in table. Control variables used in the regression are as follows: Size––total number of beds set
up and staffed divided by 1000. Mix––Medicare case-mix index. For profit––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a for-profit
entity, and zero otherwise. System––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is part of a multi-hospital system and zero otherwise.
Teach––an indicator variable that is 1 if the hospital is a teaching hospital and zero otherwise. Competition––calculated as 1––sum of
squared market shares, based upon beds in a county. Wages––Medicare wage index for MSA or state. MCO penetration––MCO
penetration. The number of MCO enrollees in an MSA divided by the areaÕs population. Managed––percentage of revenue received
from managed care. Medicare––percentage of revenue received from Medicare.
c
Smaller values are considered favorable because they indicate better cost control or greater efficiency. Control measures were
included in regression, but they are not shown in the table.

Extensions––robustness of results ines whether above (below) average past perfor-


mance is associated with the decision to change
Because causality is a major concern in cross- the cost system. A positive association between
sectional tests such as these, I examine the research past performance and major cost-system change
question using alternative specifications that can is consistent with the premise that better-perform-
potentially detect evidence of causality and omit- ing hospitals invest in cost-system upgrades and,
ted variables. consequently, have more functional systems. A
negative association may indicate that poor per-
System changes formers attempt to improve performance by
upgrading cost systems. However, I find that the
To examine causality, I estimate the likelihood decision to change the cost system is not signifi-
that the cost system is currently changing or has cantly associated with past performance at all.
undergone a significant change within the past Therefore, the results do not support the premise
two years as a function of past performance and that strong financial performance drives invest-
the control variables. 46 This specification exam- ments in cost-system functionality.

46
The timing of cost-system changes is determined by the
following questions: When was the last major change to your
Performance changes
organizationÕs cost accounting system completed? (Major
changes include the installation of new software, integration To test for omitted variables bias, I regress
of the cost accounting system with other control systems, changes in performance over a one-year period
adoption of a new overhead allocation scheme, etc.) 36% on cost-system functionality, past performance,
responded that the system was currently changing, 28%
completed last major change within the past two years, 18%
and the control variables. Hospitals that have
within last three-to-five years, 18% more than five years since undergone major cost-system changes within the
last major change. past two years are removed from the sample in this
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 203

specification so that the functionality measures de- sistent with previous research that suggests cost
scribe systems that have been in place for at least containment efforts have been directed at adminis-
three years. This test again controls for past per- trative processes and not clinical process (Shortell
formance. It also helps control for omitted vari- et al., 1995). Ultimately, the ability to significantly
ables that may be related to both current levels reduce healthcare expenditures lies in containment
of cost-system functionality and financial perfor- of the direct costs of patient care, and not in sim-
mance, such as managerial skill. Finally, simulta- ply improving administrative efficiency.
neity is less of a concern in this specification There is also some evidence that better clas-
because the functionality constructs describe a cost sification of costs, in general and relative to a
system that has been in place for at least three homogeneous peer group, is associated with higher
years prior to measuring the improvement in per- managerial evaluations of data relevance and use,
formance. Thus, the system was selected prior to as well as actual financial performance. However,
many of the actions taken to affect the current it was not possible, with this data, to isolate the ef-
change in performance. fects of systems that better classify costs from
Regressions using the change specification show those that provide greater detail. Increased report-
that the ability to provide detailed information is ing frequency was favorably associated with
significantly and positively associated with in- managersÕ beliefs about data relevance and time-
creases in cash flow per bed, and negatively associ- lines, but it was not associated with financial
ated with reductions in the administrative expense performance.
ratio. In contrast, hospitals that engaged more I found no relation between the extent to
extensively in variance analysis also experienced which systems calculate variances and managersÕ
greater increases in administrative expenses. These evaluations of the relevance and usefulness of cost
results are consistent with the findings from the information. Interestingly, hospitals with systems
levels specification, and therefore, provide no evi- that calculate more variances had significantly
dence that omitted variables or simultaneity con- lower profits and relatively higher administrative
founded the levels tests. expenses. These results could indicate reverse cau-
sality, as poorly performing hospitals may engage
in variance analysis to identify and correct prob-
Conclusion lems. However, poor performance in the past
was not associated with decisions to change the
This study examines relations among cost-sys- cost system. Alternatively, these findings support
tem functionality, managersÕ beliefs about the rel- claims that variance analysis can be problematic,
evance and usefulness of cost data, and actual especially in the hospital setting. Consistent with
financial performance in US hospitals. The results this explanation, tests that control for prior per-
indicate that managers believe that systems that formance and the timing of cost-system changes
supply greater cost detail, on average and relative find increases in administrative expenses among
to hospitals in similar organizational contexts, those hospitals that performed more variance
provide more relevant and useful data. Hospitals analysis.
with such systems are significantly more profitable, The similarity of the findings regarding the level
generate greater cash flows, and have proportion- of functionality on average and relative to contex-
ately lower administrative expenses. These findings tually similar peers is consistent with claims from
support the premise that more functional cost sys- the practitioner literature that hospitals have not
tems supply managers with more relevant data, yet adjusted their cost systems to accommodate
which they use to make performance-enhancing the increased information needs created by sweep-
decisions. Interestingly, there was no relation be- ing environmental changes (e.g., Hill & Johns,
tween the detail capability and expense per admis- 1994; Orloff et al., 1990; Serb, 1997; Young &
sion, which is largely driven by physiciansÕ clinical Pearlman, 1993). Specifically, more detail capabil-
decisions and not managersÕ decisions. This is con- ity relative to all hospitals and relative to similar
204 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

hospitals is positively associated with perfor- functionality has not yet been successfully intro-
mance, while less, in absolute and relative terms, duced into the management of clinical expendi-
is negatively associated with performance. How- tures. Until this takes place, the usefulness of
ever, while healthcare management literature lar- cost-system design in containing hospital costs is
gely supports cost-system refinement along limited.
several dimensions, this study indicates that only
the detail capability, and possibly the classification
capability, warrant investment. Moreover, even
Acknowledgements
improved detail capability has not helped manag-
ers to reduce clinical costs.
I thank Christopher Ittner, David Larcker,
The findings are subject to a number of limita-
Rick Lambert, John Core, Keith Weigelt, and
tions. Cross-sectional studies such as this can
workshop participants at the University of Penn-
establish associations, but not causality. Future
sylvania, Emory University, Rice University, the
studies using panel data would enable researchers
University of Washington, Stanford University,
to investigate performance changes arising from
HarvardÕs Kennedy School of Government, the
decisions made using cost system data. Similarly,
University of Texas at Dallas, the University of
endogeneity is also an obvious concern with this
VirginiaÕs Darden School, and the 2000 AAA
test design. Although alternative specifications re-
Managerial Accounting Conference for their
veal no evidence of reverse causality or endogene-
comments. This paper has benefited greatly from
ity with regard to the detail and classify
the comments of two anonymous referees. I also
constructs, these potentially confounding factors
thank Taylor Randall and Steve Walston, who
cannot be eliminated. Another factor that may
were instrumental in collecting the data used in
affect these results is the noisiness of the mea-
this study. The financial support of the Deloitte
sures. A mail survey prevents an assessment of
and Touche Foundation is gratefully acknowl-
the survey respondentÕs actual knowledge of the
edged.
cost-accounting system, although the surveys
were mailed to chief financial officers. A mail sur-
vey also prevents the respondent from effectively
clarifying his or her understanding of the ques- Appendix. Number of responses, mean response,
tions. Moreover, the single-industry sample limits and coding method for survey questions
the ability to generalize these results to other
industries. Finally, the hypotheses were primarily Cost-system design constructs
based upon economic theories of organization,
and some argue that such theories do not ade- Detail––level of detail provided
quately capture the complex interplay between To what extent does the cost accounting system
various internal and external organizational ac- provide data that allow you to analyze costs at the
tors in hospitals (e.g., Abernethy & Vagnoni, following levels? 1 = not at all, 7 = completely
2004; Chua & Degeling, 1991; Covaleski & Dir-
smith, 1986; Jones & Dewing, 1997). Despite
these limitations, this study has important impli- N Mean Median St. Dev.
cations for research in both accounting and
healthcare financial management. The results pro- Payer level 324 5.1 6 2.0
vide the first empirical evidence of a relation be- (e.g. Medicare)
tween cost-system functionality and actual Contract level 321 4.5 5 2.2
financial performance and thereby help justify Physician level 323 4.9 6 2.0
claims regarding the need for greater investment Procedure level 324 4.9 6 2.1
in certain dimensions of hospital cost systems. Per Diem level 320 4.3 5 2.2
However, the results also suggest that cost-system Patient level 324 5.0 6 2.1
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 205

The cost accounting function can easily custom- Frequent––frequency and breadth of cost-report
ize reports to the specification of users. 1 = strongly distribution
agree, 7 = strongly disagree, N = 320, mean = 4.2. How often does the cost accounting system re-
port information to each of the following groups?

N Not Daily Weekly Monthly Quarterly Semi-annually Annually


reported
Response codinga 1 7 6 5 4 3 2
Sr. Managers 309 40 10 12 159 40 18 30
(CEO, CFO)
Middle Managers 307 59 5 8 168 27 14 26
(Dept. Heads)
Clinical Managers 307 107 5 7 115 43 11 18
(Phys. Mgrs.)
Nursing Staff 307 133 0 6 107 27 10 21
Medical Staff 307 136 2 1 64 64 17 20
a
Method of coding responses. Higher numbers were assigned to more frequent reporting.

Classify––Classification of costs according to Variance––number and type of variances are


behavior calculated
Does your cost system have a formalized meth- Which of the following variances does your orga-
od of distinguishing between the following costs? nization calculate? (Check all that apply.) 48%: effi-
1 = not at all, 7 = completely ciency, 53%: case mix, 58%: price, (N = 317) (coded
as 0, 1).
N Mean Median St. Dev.
Direct and indirect 321 5.1 6 1.9 Perceptual performance measures
Fixed and variable 318 4.7 5 2.1
Controllable and 317 3.7 4 2.0 Relevant––This measure was based upon the
non-controllable two sets of questions below (1 and 2). Responses
to the second set of questions (2. Actual infor-
mation supplied) were subtracted from the corre-
If your hospital tracks fixed and variable costs, sponding responses to the first set of questions
how are they separated? (Check one, N = 317) (1. User Needs). The average of these differences
captures the extent to which a system meets the
22% N/A, hospital does not track fixed userÕs needs. The smaller the difference, the bet-
and variable costs (1)a ter the system meets the userÕs needs. To calcu-
34% Account analysis (3) late the variable relevant, the average difference
40% Subjective/managerial experience (2) for each hospital was subtracted from the
4% Statistical regression techniques (4) maximum difference so that larger values indi-
a
Number indicates how responses were coded; 4 = most cate that a system is better at meeting a userÕs
advanced, 1 = least advanced. need.
1. User Needs: Rate the importance of cost
To what extent does the cost accounting function accounting information in performing each of
use the ratio of cost to charge (RCC) to estimate the the following activities. You may not actually have
cost of individual services and procedures? 1 = use the information necessary to perform the activities
only RCC, 7 = do not use RCC at all: N = 318, listed below; however, in responding, please indi-
mean = 4.1, median = 4, St. Dev. = 2.1. cate whether you would consider cost information
206 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

of value in performing these activities. 1 = not at N Mean Median St.


all important, 7 = very important Dev.
Budget 323 4.9 5 1.6
Control costs 323 4.9 5 1.6
N Mean Median St. Price hospital 324 4.9 5 1.7
Dev. services
Benchmark your 321 4.3 5 1.8
Evaluate individual 322 4.4 5 1.6 hospitalÕs
performance costs against
Evaluate group 324 5.6 6 1.3 industry
(e.g., departmental) Evaluate 322 4.2 4 1.8
performance acquisitions
of new
Negotiate contracts 323 6.2 7 1.1 technology/
with payers equipment
Budget 324 5.8 6 1.2 Evaluate strategic 321 4.1 4 1.8
Control costs 324 6.2 6 1.0 alternatives
Price hospital services 323 5.7 6 1.3 Negotiate contracts 321 4.0 4 1.8
with suppliers
Benchmark your 323 5.6 6 1.2 (e.g. Pharm. Co.)
hospitalÕs costs
against industry
Evaluate acquisitions 324 5.2 5 1.3 Use––Use in decision-making: Rate agreement
of new technology/ with the following statements: 1 = strongly agree,
equipment 7 = strongly disagree. Users rely on cost account-
Evaluate strategic 324 5.3 6 1.4 ing data to make decisions. N = 324, mean = 4.5,
alternatives median = 5, St. Dev. = 1.5.
Negotiate contracts 324 5.1 5 1.4
with suppliers
(e.g. Pharm. Co.) Construct validity measures––(Table 4)

Differs from Medicare: To what extent is your


2. Actual information supplied by system: Can organizationÕs cost accounting system different
the cost accounting system provide your organiza- from the Medicare cost-reporting system? 1 = ex-
tion with information for the following activities. actly the same, 7 = completely different. N =319,
1 = not at all, 7 = completely. mean = 4.35, median = 4, St. Dev. = 2.1.
Allocation bases: In allocating costs in revenue
departments to a specific procedure, how many
N Mean Median St. separate bases does your hospital use? (Circle
Dev. one; circle N/A if your organization does not allo-
cate costs at the procedure level.)
Evaluate 322 3.2 3 2.0
individual
performance No. of responses N/A 1 2–3 4–6 >6
Evaluate group 324 4.8 5 1.7 309 114 27 60 47 61
(e.g., depart-
mental) Accurate: Rate agreement with the following
performance statements: 1 = strongly agree, 7 = strongly dis-
Negotiate 324 4.9 6 1.8 agree. The cost accounting system provides accu-
contracts rate data. N = 321, mean = 3.5, median = 4, St.
with payers Dev. = 1.4.
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 207

Timely: Users receive information from the N Mean Median St. Dev.
cost accounting function in a timely manner.
1 = strongly agree, 7 = strongly disagree. N = 316, Business 321 4.1 4 1.6
mean = 3.9, median = 4, St. Dev. = 1.6. process
innovation
Control variable––(Table 6) (e.g., new
billing system)
Managed: Percentage of revenues derived from Patient-care 323 4.3 4 1.7
managed care––(control variable): Indicate your technology
approximate payer mix by assigning the percent- (e.g., advanced
age of total inpatient revenue that is received from operating room)
the following: N = 316.

46% Medicare; 19% Managed care References


13% Medicaid; 7% Self-pay/bad debt/charity
Abernethy, M. A., & Chua, W. F. (1996). A field study of
12% Indemnity; 4% Other control system ‘‘redesign’’: The impact of institutional
process on strategic choice. Contemporary Accounting
Strategy constructs––used to model cost-system Research, 13, 596–606.
functionality (Table 9) Abernethy, M. A., & Stoelwinder, J. Y. (1996). The role of
professional control in the management of complex
Cost––Extent to which the hospital follows a organizations. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 20,
1–17.
cost-focused strategy: Rate the importance of the
Abernethy, M. A., & Vagnoni, E. (2004). Power, organization
following objectives in achieving your hospitalÕs design and managerial behaviour. Accounting, Organiza-
mission: 1 = not at all important, 7 = very important. tions and Society, 29, 207–225.
Babad, Y. M., & Balachandran, B. V. (1993). Cost driver
optimization in activity-based costing. The Accounting
N Mean Median St.
Review, 68, 563–575.
Dev. Bastable, C. W., & Bao, D. H. (1988). The fiction of sales-mix
Control or reduce 321 6.4 7 0.9 and sales-quantity variances. Accounting Horizons, 2, 10–17.
Banker, R. D., & Potter, G. (1993). Economic implications of
the costs of existing
single cost driver systems. Journal of Management Account-
services ing Research, 5, 15–31.
Identify and eliminate 320 4.9 5 1.4 Beal, E., & Little, R. (1975). Missing values in multivariate
unprofitable services analysis. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B,
129–145.
Brickley, J. A., & Van Horne, R. L. (2002). Managerial
Lead––Extent to which hospital follows a prod- incentives in nonprofit organizations: Evidence from hospi-
uct differentiation strategy: Rate the importance tals. Journal of Law and Economics, 45, 227–249.
of the following objectives in achieving your hospi- Bromwich, M., & Hong, D. (1999). Activity-based costing
systems and incremental costs. Management Accounting
talÕs mission: 1 = not at all important, 7 = very Research, 10, 39–60.
important. Burda, D. (2002). Déjà vu all over again? Joint CommissionÕs
history casts doubt on the sincerity of its newest makeover.
N Mean Median St. Dev. Modern Healthcare, 32, 22.
Callahan, C. M., & Gabriel, E. A. (1999). The differential
Establish 322 5.8 6 1.3 impact of accurate product cost information in imperfectly
clinical competitive markets: A theoretical and empirical investiga-
leadership tion. Contemporary Accounting Research, 15, 419–455.
Cheatham, C. B., & Cheatham, L. R. (1996). Redesigning cost
systems: Is standard costing obsolete?. Accounting Horizons,
Is your organization a leader or follower with 10, 23–31.
respect to the time of adoption of the following: Chenhall,R.K.(2003).Management controlsystemsdesign within
1 = leader, 7 = follower. its organizational context: Findings from contingency-based
208 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

research and directions for the future. Accounting, Organi- Duggan, M. (2002). Hospital market structure and the behavior
zations and Society, 28, 127–168. of not-for-profit hospitals, specification and measurement
Chenhall, R. H., & Langfield-Smith, K. (1998). The relation- errors in product costing. Rand Journal of Economics, 33,
ship between strategic priorities, management techniques 433–446.
and management accounting: An empirical investigation Early, L., & Cleverly, W. (1995). CFO compensation increas-
using a systems approach. Accounting, Organizations and ingly linked to performance. Healthcare Financial Manage-
Society, 23, 243–264. ment, 49, 44–49.
Chenhall, R. H., & Morris, D. (1986). The impact of structure, Eldenburg, L. (1994). The use of information in total cost
environment, and interdependence on the perceived useful- management. The Accounting Review, 69, 96–121.
ness of management accounting systems. The Accounting Eldenburg, L., Hermalin, B. E., Weisbach, M. S., & Wosinska,
Review, 61, 16–35. M. (2004). Governance, performance objectives, and orga-
Chilingerian, J., & Sherman, H. (1990). Managing physician nizational form: Evidence from hospitals. Journal of Cor-
efficiency and effectiveness in providing hospital services. porate Finance, 10, 527–548.
Health Services Management Research, 3, 3–15. Eldenburg, L., & Kallapur, S. (1997). Changes in hospital
Christensen, J., & Demski, J. S. (1997). Product costing in the service mix and cost allocations in response to changes in
presence of endogenous subcost functions. Review of Medicare reimbursement schemes. Journal of Accounting
Accounting Studies, 2, 65–87. and Economics, 23, 31–50.
Chua, W. F., & Degeling, P. (1991). Information technology Evans, J. H., III., Hwang, Y., & Nagarajan, N. J. (1995).
and accounting in the accomplishment of public policy a PhysicianÕs response to length-of-stay profiling. Medical
cautionary tale. Accounting, Management, and Information Care, 33, 1106–1119.
Technology, 1, 109–137. Evans, J. H., III., Hwang, Y., & Nagarajan, N. J. (1997). Cost
Comerford, S. E., & Abernethy, M. A. (1999). Budgeting and reduction and process reengineering in hospitals. Journal of
the management of role conflict in hospitals. Behavioral Cost Management, 11, 10–27.
Research in Accounting, 11, 1–17. Evans, J. H., III., Hwang, Y., & Nagarajan, N. J. (2003).
Coombs, R. W. (1987). Accounting for the control of doctors: Management conrol and hospital cost reduction: Additional
Management information systems in hospitals. Accounting, evidence. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy, 20, 73–88.
Organizations, and Society, 12, 389–404. Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983a). Separation of ownership
Cooper, D., Hayes, D., & Wolf, F. (1981). Accounting in and control. Journal of Law and Economics, 26, 301–325.
organized anarchies. Accounting, Organizations, and Soci- Fama, E. F., & Jensen, M. C. (1983b). Agency problems and
ety, 6, 175–191. residual claimants. Journal of Law and Economics, 26,
Cooper, R., & Kaplan, R. (1991). The design of cost manage- 327–349.
ment systems: Text, cases, and readings. Englewood Cliffs, Feinglass, J., Martin, G., & Sen, A. (1991). The financial effect
NJ: Prentice Hall. of physician practice style on hospital resource use. Health
Cooper, R., & Kaplan, R. (1992). Activity-based systems: Services Research, 26, 183–205.
Measuring the costs of resource usage. Accounting Horizons, Feltham, G. A. (1977). Cost aggregation: An information
6, 1–13. economic analysis. Journal of Accounting Research, 15,
Cooper, J., & Suver, J. (1994). Variance analysis refines overhead 42–70.
cost control. Healthcare Financial Management, 48, 40–52. Feltham, G. A., & Xie, J. (1994). Performance measure
Counte, M., & Glandon, G. (1988). Managerial innovation in congruity and diversity in multi-task principal/agent rela-
the hospital: An analysis of the diffusion of hospital cost- tions. The Accounting Review, 69, 429–453.
accounting systems. Hospital and Health Services Adminis- Foster, G. F., & Swenson, D. (1997). Measuring the success of
tration, 42, 371–384. activity-based cost management and its determinants. Jour-
Covaleski, M. A., Dirsmith, M. W., & Michelman, J. E. (1993). nal of Managerial Accounting Research, 9, 109–141.
An institutional theory perspective on the DRG Frame- Fralicx, R. D., & Liccione, W. J. (1997). What Are You
work: Case-mix accounting systems health-care organiza- Worth?. Hospital and Health Networks, 69(17), 8.
tions. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 18, 65–80. Gal-Or, E. (1987). First mover disadvantages with private
Covaleski, M. A., & Dirsmith, M. W. (1986). The budgetary information. The Review of Economic Studies, 54, 279–292.
process of power and politics. Accounting, Organizations Gal-Or, E. (1998). The advantages of imprecise information.
and Society, 11, 193–214. Rand Journal of Economics, 19, 266–275.
Datar, S., & Gupta, M. (1994). Aggregation, specification and Gal-Or, E. (1993). Strategic cost allocation. Journal of Indus-
measurement errors in product costing. The Accounting trial Economics, 41, 387–402.
Review, 69, 567–591. Gaynor, M., & Gertler, P. (1995). Moral hazard and risk
DeBrock, L., & Arnould, R. J. (1992). Utilization controls in spreading in partnerships. RAND Journal of Economics, 26,
HMOs. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance, 32, 591–613.
31–53. Gaynor, M., & Pauly, M. V. (1990). Competition and produc-
Dopuch, N. (1993). A perspective on cost drivers. The tive efficiency in partnerships: Evidence from Medical Group
Accounting Review, 68, 615–620. Practice. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 544–573.
M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210 209

Gordon, L. A., & Narayanan, V. K. (1984). Management Lee, R. H. (1990). Monitoring physicians: a bargaining model
accounting systems, perceived environmental uncertainty of medical group practice. Journal of Health Economics, 9,
and organization structure: An empirical investigation. 463–481.
Accounting, Organizations, and Society, 9, 37–47. Lawrence, C. H. (1990). The effect of ownership structure and
HCIA, Inc. (1997). Financial and clinical benchmarking: The accounting system type on hospital costs. Research in
strategic use of data. Baltimore. Governmental and Nonprofit Accounting, 6, 35–60.
Hill, N. T. (2001). Adoption of costing systems in U.S. Langfield-Smith, K. (1997). Management control systems and
hospitals: An event history analysis 1980-1990. Journal of strategy: a critical review. Accounting, Organizations and
Accounting and Public Policy, 19, 41–71. Society, 22, 207–232.
Hill, N. T., & Johns, E. (1994). Adoption of costing systems by Leone, A. J., & Van Horne, R. L. (1999). Earnings management
U.S. hospitals. Hospital and Health Services Administration, in not-for-profit institutions: Evidence from hospitals.
39, 521–537. Working Paper. Simon School, University of Rochester.
Hilton, R. (1979). The determinants of cost information value: Luft, J., & Shields, M. J. (2003). Mapping management
An illustrative analysis. Journal of Accounting Research, 17, accounting: Graphics and guidelines for theory-consistent
411–435. empirical research. Accounting, Organizations and Society,
Ittner, C. D., Lanen, W. N., & Larcker, D. F. (2002). The 28, 169–250.
association between activity-based costing and manufactur- Mak, Y., & Roush, M. J. (1996). Managing Activity Costs with
ing performance. Journal of Accounting Research, 40, Flexible Budgeting and Variance Analysis. Accounting
711–725. Horizons, 10, 141–146.
Ittner, C. D., Larcker, D. F., & Pizzini, M. J. (2004). McGown, A. S. (1998). Perceived benefits of ABCM imple-
Compensation contracts in professional service firms. mentation. Accounting Horizons, 12, 31–50.
Working Paper. Wharton School, University of Meeting, D. T., & Harvey, R. O. (1998). Strategic cost
Pennsylvania. accounting helps create a competitive edge. Healthcare
Johnson, H. (1992). ItÕs time to stop overselling activity-based Financial Management, 52, 42–51.
concepts. Management Accounting, 74, 26–35. Merchant, K. A., & Shields, M. D. (1993). When and why to
Johnson, H., & Kaplan, R. (1987). The rise and fall of measure costs less accurately to improve decision-making.
management accounting. Boston MA: Harvard Business Accounting Horizons, 7, 76–81.
School Press Books. Molinari, C., Hendryx, M., & Goodstein, J. (1997). The effect
Jones, C. S., & Dewing, I. P. (1997). The attitudes of NHS of CEO-board relations on hospital performance. Health
clinicians and medical managers towards changes in Care Management Review, 22, 7–15.
accounting controls. Financial Accountability and Manage- Nelson, E. G., Rust, R. T., Zahorik, A., & Rose, R. L. (1992).
ment, 13, 261–280. Do patient perceptions of quality relate to hospital finan-
Kaplan, R. S., & Norton, D. P. (1992). The balanced cial performance?. Journal of Health Care Marketing, 12,
scorecard––measures that drive performance. Harvard Busi- 6–13.
ness Review, 70, 71–79. Newhouse, J. P. (1970). Toward a theory of nonprofit institu-
Karmarkar, U. S., Lederer, P. J., & Zimmerman, J. L. (1990). tions: An economic model of a hospital. The American
Choosing manufacturing production control and cost Economic Review, 60, 64–74.
accounting systems. In R. Kaplan (Ed.), Measures for Noreen, E. (1991). Conditions under which activity-based cost
manufacturing excellence. Boston, MA: Harvard Business systems provide relevant costs. Journal of Management
School Press. Accounting Research, 3, 159–168.
Khandwalla, P. (1972). The effect of different types of compe- Norton, E. C., & Staiger, D. O. (1994). How hospital ownership
tition on the use of management controls. Journal of affects access to care for the uninsured. Journal of Health
Accounting Research, 10, 275–285. Economics, 7, 259–284.
Krumwiede, K. R. (1998). The implementataion stages of Orloff, T., Littell, C., Clune, C., Klingman, D., & Preston, B.
activity-based costing and the impact of contextual organi- (1990). Hospital cost accounting: WhoÕs doing what and
zational factors. Journal of Management Accounting why. Health Care Management Review, 15, 73–78.
Research, 10, 239–277. Ouchi, W. G. (1979). A conceptual framework for the design of
Krishnan, R. (2001). Market restructuring and pricing in the organizational control mechanisms. Management Science,
hospital industry. Journal of Health Economics, 20, 213–237. 79, 833–848.
Kurunmäki, L. (1999). Professional vs financial capital in the Pauly, M., & Redisch, M. (1973). The not-for-profit hospital as
field of health care – struggles for the redistribution of a physicianÕs cooperative. The American Economic Review,
power and control. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 63, 87–99.
24, 95–124. Phelps, C. E. (2003). Health economics (3rd ed.). New York:
Lambert, R. A., & Larcker, D. F. (1995). The prospective Addison Wesley.
payment system, hospital efficiency, and compensation Picone, G., Chou, S. Y., & Sloan, F. (2002). Are for-profit
contracts for senior-level hospital administrators. Journal hospital conversions harmful to patients and to medicare?
of Accounting and Public Policy, 14, 1–31. Rand Journal of Economics, 33, 507–523.
210 M.J. Pizzini / Accounting, Organizations and Society 31 (2006) 179–210

Porter, M. E. (1980). Competitive strategy. New York: The Free empty or half full?. Journal of Hospital and Health Services
Press. Administration, 40, 4–24.
Porter, M. E. (1985). Competitive advantage. New York: The Simons, R. (1987). Accounting control system and business
Free Press. strategy: And empirical analysis. Accounting, Organizations,
Preston, A. M. (1992). The birth of clinical accounting: A study and Society, 12, 357–374.
of the emergence and transformations of discourses on costs Swenson, D. (1995). The benefits of activity-based cost man-
and practices of accounting in U.S. hospitals. Accounting, agement to the manufacturing industry. Journal of Man-
Organizations, and Society, 17, 63–100. agement Accounting Research, 7, 167–180.
Prince, T. R. (1998). Strategic management for health care Tselepis, J. (1989). Refined cost accounting produces better
entities: Creative frameworks for financial and operational information. Healthcare Financial Management, 43, 27–34.
analysis. Chicago: American Hospital Publishing Inc. Young, D., & Pearlman, L. (1993). Managing the stages of hos-
Schick, A. G., Gordon, L. A., & Haka, S. (1990). Information pital cost accounting. Healthcare Financial Management, 47,
overload: A temporal approach. Accounting, Organizations, 58–80.
and Society, 5, 199–220. Selto, F. H., Renner, C. J., & Young, S. M. (1995). Assessing
Serb, C. (1997). Data rich, information poor. Hospital and the organizational fit of a just-in-time manufacturing
Health Networks 5 May, 43–44. system: Testing selection, interaction and systems models
Shank, J., & Govindarajan, V. (1993). Strategic cost manage- of contingency theory. Accounting Organizations and Soci-
ment: The new tool for competitive advantage. New York: ety, 20, 665–684.
The Free Press. Wedig, G., Hassan, M., & Sloan, F. (1989). Hospital invest-
Shapiro, S. S., & Wilk, M. B. (1965). An analysis of variance ment decisions and the cost of capital. Journal of Business,
test for normality (complete samples). Biometrica, 52, 62, 517–536.
591–611. West, T. D., & Balas, E. A. (1996). Contrasting RCC, RVU,
Shields, M. D. (1995). An empirical analysis of firmsÕ imple- and ABC for managed care decisions. Healthcare Financial
mentation experience with activity-based costing. Journal of Management, 50, 54–61.
Management Accounting Research, 7, 1–28. White, H. (1980). A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance
Shortell, S. M., Levin, D. Z., OÕBrien, J. L., & Hughes, E. F. X. matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity.
(1995). Assessing the evidence on CQI: Is the glass half Econometrica, 48, 817–838.

You might also like