You are on page 1of 11

The International Journal on Media Management, 11: 81–90, 2009

Copyright © Institute for Media and Communications Management


ISSN: 1424-1277 print/1424-1250 online
DOI: 10.1080/14241270902844249
HIJM

Global Paradigm Shift: Strategic Management of New and Digital Media


in New and Digital Economics
Zvezdan Vukanovic
Strategic Management of Media

DG University, Montenegro

Abstract The purpose of this conceptual article is to outline and explain a global paradigm shift in
strategic management of new and digital media in the age of new and digital economics. Accordingly,
this article presents an analysis of the 5 most-successful international media conglomerates (Time
Warner, Walt Disney Co., News Corporation, CBS Corp., and Bertelsmann AG) in regards to their annual
revenue, profit, and stock growth, as well as total debt to equity. The article finds that 4 out of the 5 firms
are American (Time Warner, Walt Disney Co., News Corporation, and CBS Corp.), and 1 is German
(Bertelsmann AG). For the most part, 6 factors are particularly dominant in explaining the profitable
growth of leading international media conglomerates at the macrolevel: cross-media content distribution
leveraging and repurposing, innovation management, vertical integration, vertical expansion, media diver-
sification, and large number of shareholders. To more effectively position and leverage new paradigmatic
models largely influencing volatile media markets, this article proposes the creation and adoption of repur-
posed media content and economies of aggregation (triple- and quadruple-play bundling strategies and
network externalities) for the emerging Internet Protocol TV, Internet TV, and the mobile-TV markets.

The increased importance of the media industry has grown return on invested capital, the media industry (1963–2003),
incessantly over the last 15 years as a result of new digital together with pharmaceuticals, household and personal
convergence. Its increased importance is particularly products, and computer software and services, represents
reflected in economic respects. The global media industry the most profitable global industry (Grant, 2008, p. 70).
encompasses over $1 trillion (Vizjak & Ringlstetter, 2003)
and accounted for about 22% of the total information
industries’ revenue (Compaine & Gomery, 2000, p. 545). In Strategies of the Top Five Media
its annual media forecast, PricewaterhouseCoopers (2008) Conglomerate Firms
projects that global media revenue will grow by an average
of 6.6% per year, reaching $1.29 trillion in 2012. This section presents an overview of the organizational
Furthermore, the importance of strategic management and business strategies of the top five international
of new and digital media in a new and digital economy is media conglomerates. I selected the five most–successful,
particularly important as present and future markets are in international media conglomerates in regards to their
the process of global expansion. The potential for global annual revenue, profit, and stock growth, as well as total
competition will increase by about 300% between 2007 and debt to equity that, in profitable companies, is less than
2037. It is important to notice that in terms of the average 1. The five companies reviewed in this research include
Time Warner, Walt Disney Co., News Corporation, CBS
Dr. Zvezdan Vukanovic is an assistant professor in media manage- Corp., and Bertelsmann AG. All firms are publicly traded
ment and economics at the Faculty of International Business, Econom- companies with the exception of Bertelsmann AG, which
ics and Finance, DG University in Montenegro and a visiting lecturer is privately held (Picard, 2002b, p. 118). These companies
in management, marketing and international business at the School were selected because their divisional structure consists
of Business and Economics, Thompson Rivers University, Canada.
Address correspondence to Zvezdan Vukanovic, UDG - University
of at least two or more media-related divisions, and
of Donja Gorica, Faculty for International Economics, Finance media activities account for at least one half of the com-
and Business, Donja Gorica, 20 000 Podgorica, Montenegro. pany’s asset base. As such, the world’s largest company in
E-mail: zvezdanv@t-com.me terms of revenue, General Electric, is omitted from this

81
82 Vukanovic

Table 1. Global Media Financial Ratios


Revenue Annual Growth Net Income Number of
Company (in $billions) of Media Market Stock (in $billions) Shareholders Employees

Time Warner 47.32 +20% 4.38 25,000 86,400


Walt Disney Co. 37.84 +40% 4.42 658,000 137,000
News Corporation 32.99 +35% 5.4 25,832 64,000
Bertelsmann AG 23.99 NA 0.51 6 102,000
CBS Corp. 14.18 +22% 1.24 113,024 23,650

analysis because the company’s media holdings are limited dominant reasons: It increases the number of media
to a single division that consists of NBC and its branded distribution platforms and services, and it diversifies
cable networks (CNBC, MSNBC; Picard, 2002b, p. 103). Like- firms’ corporate portfolios while reducing financial risk
wise, Sony and Vivendi were also rejected because their in highly volatile global markets.
media holdings are limited, with most of the company’s Globalization and convergence have created addi-
revenues obtained through their consumer electronics and tional possibilities and incentives to repackage or to
telecommunications divisions and the sale of music records repurpose media content into as many different formats
and compact discs (CDs; Picard, 2002b, p. 118). In addition, as is technically and commercially feasible (books, maga-
Viacom was rejected due to its high total debt to equity zine serializations, television programs and formats, vid-
(1.10), which is below the profitably expected level (1.0). eos, etc.) and to sell those products through as many
Four out of the five firms are American (Time Warner, distribution channels, outlets, or windows in as many
Walt Disney Co., News Corporation, and CBS Corp.), and geographic markets and to as many paying consumers as
one is German (Bertelsmann AG). Table 1 presents the possible (Doyle, 2002, p. 22). Accordingly, repurposing rep-
basic description of global media financial ratios in resents the joint emphasis of media firms on both the
regards to revenue, annual growth of media market stock, content and distribution.
net income, number of shareholders, and employees. It was recently estimated by Mark Selby, Vice President
The market position of the five most-successful media of Nokia Multimedia, that the mixing up of media con-
conglomerates reveals that the total revenue of the “Big tent will increase a multimedia content by 25% by 2012.
Five” media conglomerates is $156.32 billions. It repre- The concept of cross-media content will integrate both
sents nearly 15% of the global media revenue in 2007. For the hypermedia and multimedia models. Cross-media
the most part, six factors are particularly dominant in and on-demand content offer the enormous content base
explaining the profitable growth of leading international (linear and nonlinear) as a part of TV program schedules
media conglomerates at the macrolevel: cross-media con- (Bakos & Brynjolfsson, 2000). In addition, on-demand TV
tent distribution leveraging and repurposing, innovation services are able to promote premium, niche, and user-
management, vertical integration, vertical expansion, generated content. As such, innovative services are based
media diversification, and large number of shareholders. on convergent technological architecture (Bakos &
Brynjolfsson, 2000). Due to the faster product life cycles,
volatile markets, and increased competition, future cross-
media services will be more interactive, dynamic,
Stragetic Management of Cross-Media enhanced, and flexible. This enhanced technological and
Content Distribution, Leveraging, content integration will more efficiently stimulate the
and Repurposing economies of aggregation that, in turn, will bring value-
added services to the media business and industry. It is
In a rapidly changing media industry with firms advisable to point out that identical content must be able
continuously facing competition from new entrants, glo- to be called up via an array of media in the future to
bal strategic management is important for maintenance achieve the broadest possible marketing effect.
of sustainable competitive advantage. The media indus- Repurposing and leveraging content can help media
try is in the midst of radical transformation driven by companies reach a larger and a brand new audience. It is
technological change. In the future, only media compa- profitable and beneficial because audiences will demand
nies focusing on selling content and services in maxi- different experiences based on the different media. Digi-
mum quantities will manage to maintain a profitable talization of media production and distribution,
position in this highly volatile market (Vizjak & Ringl- together with increases in cable and Internet bandwidth,
stetter, 2003, p. 17). The term cross-media stands for con- as well as increases in size and screen resolution of con-
tent repurposing. The strategic management of cross- ventional TV sets, will positively influence increases in
media content and platform is important because of two the delivery of repurposing content.
Strategic Management of Media 83

The Role of the Economies of Aggregation bundling is dominantly seen as an optimal marketing
in Innovation Management and management strategy for a multiservice firm with
access to a client. This strategy profits from cost synergies
During the last 2 decades, user-generated content, mass that include (a) value-adding services and content and (b)
customization, and personalization have replaced mass price discounts.
production in the media business. Accordingly, econo- A quadruple- and triple-play bundling strategy implies
mies of scale have been substituted largely by economies the utilization of multiple services, devices, and techno-
of scope. Meanwhile, global hyper-competition has frag- logical domains (TV, broadband, telephony, and mobile
mented niche markets and stimulated media corporations telephony), but one network, one vendor, and one bill.
to search for more original and innovative services. To be Broadband has emerged as the central hub of the bun-
profitable, innovative services in the media industry and dling trend. There are two main reasons for this: (a)
business have to be diffused and distributed efficiently Broadband subscriptions comprise the fastest-growing
and effectively via various cross-media platforms (broad- sector of the global telecoms market with broadband,
band, multicast, and convergent digital models). Ideally, and (b) it is possible to deliver all the fixed-line elements
the economies of aggregation can be based on two crucial of a service bundle over the same access technology.
strategic and managerial concepts: triple- and quadruple- These benefits enhance profit; ensure customer loyalty
play bundling strategies and network externalities. It is (thereby decreasing customer churn); and increase con-
important to point out that both concepts are fundamental sumer choices, market shares, and average revenues per
in terms of increasing the diffusion of innovation. user while helping to reduce churn and protect against
Bundling is the strategy of adopting, competing, and incursions from new competitors. Competitive pressures
differentiating corporate portfolios in volatile media and changing consumption habits are encouraging
markets. Bundling strategies add value to different ser- media firms to market bundles of services that include
vices by inventing economical packages that are conve- television, telephony, and Internet access (Baranes, 2006).
nient to use. As such, bundling can create economies of Studies initiated by Whinston (1990) have shown that the
aggregation for information goods if their marginal costs profitability of bundling results from economies of scale
are very low, even in the absence of network externali- in the tied market. Other studies (Carbajo, de Meza, &
ties, economies of scale, or economies of scope. Bundling Seidmann, 1990; Chen, 1997; Seidmann, 1991) have
stimulates multi-product media firms to innovate. shown that bundling may mitigate competition by
To be profitable and effectively applied by consumers, inducing more differentiation.
the innovation has to be efficiently diffused. This notion The triple-play bundling strategy is most successful
implies that innovation is of little value unless it dif- when there are economies of scale in production and
fuses. Effective diffusion of innovations increases econo- economies of scope in distribution, marginal costs of
mies of scale effects and captures profits before bundling are low, production set-up costs are high, cus-
competitors. The diffusion of innovation is particularly tomer acquisition costs are high, and consumers appreci-
important in media industry, as the global competition ate the resulting simplification of the purchase decision
tends to be fierce, whereas the market is becoming and benefit from the joint performance of the combined
increasingly volatile. Generally speaking, companies product. Research by Bakos and Brynjolfsson (2000)
should accelerate the diffusion of innovations because found that bundling was particularly effective for digital
early movers tend to achieve higher market shares. “information goods” with close to zero marginal cost,
and could enable a bundler with an inferior collection of
products to drive even superior quality goods out of the
market place.
Triple- and Quadruple-Play
Bundling Strategies
The Role of Network Externalities
The bundling of services is defined as marketing two or in the Media Industry and Business
more components of the same service together as a pack-
age at a special price (Shaw, 2006). A triple-play bundling Network externalities were originally introduced in the
strategy is the optimum method for leveraging financial communications network literature. Before the inven-
gain from the content. This strategy is very common in tion of telecommunications, Internet, and digital media,
the software business (e.g., bundle a word processor, a the effect of network externalities was less visible and
spreadsheet, and a database into a single office suite) and dominant. Initially, these externalities were referred to
in the cable television industry (e.g., basic cable in the as consumption externalities in which demand is mod-
United States and the European Union (EU) generally eled as being interdependent. A market exhibits network
offers many channels at 1 price). Today, the concept of effects (or network externalities) when the value to a
84 Vukanovic

buyer of an extra unit is higher when more units are in recent years (Gupta, Jain, & Sawhney, 1999) as they
sold, everything else being equal. In other words, the have been driven by a continuous growth of the digital
utility a consumer drives from joining a communications media, Internet and media globalization, a quest for
service increases as others join the network. Theoretically, improved efficiency, and cost reduction. These paradigm
network externalities are described as a mechanism changes that occur in the field of management economy
whereby a firm’s marginal product of an input is posi- influence value chains to be increasingly reorganized in
tively affected by other firms’ use of the same input value networks. In addition to that, this reorganization
(Ongardanunkul, 2003). Network effects arise because of in value networks provides a balance between specializa-
complementarities. In a traditional network, network tion and flexibility (Peck & Juttner, 2000). The network
externalities arise because a typical subscriber can reach thus involves corporations, customers, and stakeholders
more subscribers in a larger network. In addition, it is (Lisboa, 2007). At the same time, customers are taking
advisable to point out that by increasing the size of the part in global social networks that shape their percep-
network, the value of authorized users is increased. At tions and inform their decisions. This is facilitated by
this point, we witness the creation of positive network increased Internet and mobile communications access.
effects, which raise the value received by consumers as The result of these different types of associations is called
markets get larger. As such, the network of competitors network economy—an economy in which the relation-
with larger market shares will have an advantage over ships among its members is a product of the information
smaller competitors. they exchange (Evans & Wurster, 1997).
The existence of network externalities is the key When large international media companies work in a
reason for the importance, growth, and profitability of networked economy, they observe lower complexity, bet-
global media industry in the new, digital, and network ter internal communication, flexibility, tailored resource
economy. Unlike in many other businesses, in the media allocation, and high potential for innovation (Johnston &
services industry the benefit from consuming increases Lawrence, 1988). The basic concept of the network econ-
with the number of other people consuming (Hoskins, omy is that the value of being a part of a network
McFadyen & Finn, 2004, p. 72). An extra subscriber to the increases as the network size increases (Lisboa, 2007).
media network brings additional benefits to current sub- Metcalfe’s rule states that the value of a network
scribers. Similarly, the loss of a subscriber reduces bene- increases proportionally with the square of the number
fits to current subscribers. For example, a telephone is of of its members (Cartwright, 2002; Shapiro & Varian,
little value if no one else is using it, of moderate value if 1998).
only a few of one’s potential contacts use it, and indis- In their fundamental study on the network economy,
pensable if everyone uses it. Obviously, the value of con- Shapiro and Varian described the rules that guide the
suming a certain TV channel by only a few consumers dynamics of networks. They argued that it is necessary to
has increased with the number of other subscribers. achieve a critical mass in the network to grant positive
Economists refer to this phenomenon as network exter- feedback. They also explored the effects that a network is
nalities. Accordingly, a product or service possesses net- subject to, such phenomena as network externalities and
work externalities if the utility one derives from it is a lock in. Network externalities and critical mass are con-
positive function of the number of other people who con- sidered crucial aspects when taking into account the
sume it. Most media and communications technologies whole network with its multiple stakeholders such as
such as satellite and cable TV, cellular TV, and Internet partners, customers, consumers, shareholders, employ-
Protocol (IP) TV are network goods in this sense: They lit- ees, investors, regulatory sectors, governments, and so on
erally constitute a network, and the value of the network (Foss, Kristensen, & Wilke, 2004).
depends on the number of persons (or organizations or However, media management researchers in the
other entities) connected to it. mobile-TV and IP TV industries have been slow to
Historically, indirect network externalities have influ- respond to the growing importance of network econo-
enced the outcome of technology competition in many mies and externalities in new product and service adop-
markets, including AM stereo, color television, videocas- tion. For instance, most new product models in the
sette recorders, CD players, laser disc players, and personal management science literature assume that new products
computers (Ducey & Fratrik, 1989; Farrell & Shapiro, are autonomous and that the adoption of new products is
1992; McGahan, Vadasz, & Yoffie, 1997). More recently, as not affected by the presence or absence of complemen-
analog technologies give way to digital technologies that tary products (Mahajan, Muller, & Bass, 1993). These
require new software, indirect network externalities will assumptions are being called into question in almost
play an important role in the evolution of a wide range every durable product market in the network economy,
of technology markets (Yoffie, 1996). where firms rarely act alone to create new products, and
Therefore, it is advisable to point out that network products rarely function in isolation (Shapiro & Varian,
effects have attracted significant attention from economists 1998).
Strategic Management of Media 85

The network economy is characterized by the fact that member of the hierarchy produces a different product or
businesses increasingly work together with others when service, and the products combine to satisfy a common
producing their products and services and—as the other need. Vertical integration is one method of avoiding the
side of the coin—consumers satisfy their needs by using hold-up problem. Three varieties among vertical integra-
products and services that come from the most diverse tion are backward (upstream) vertical integration, for-
sources. The moving forces behind the developments of ward (downstream) vertical integration, and balanced
the network economy are technologies, which enable the (horizontal) vertical integration. The most effective
fast and cheap transportation of goods and information. integration in internationally volatile media markets is
The stronger and higher the creation of benefit through balanced (horizontal) vertical integration. In balanced
networking with others, the greater one’s own vulnera- vertical integration, the company sets up subsidiaries
bility and dependency (Petrovic, Ksela, Fallenböck, & that both supply them with inputs and distribute their
Kittl, 2003, p. 29). outputs.
Neoliberal globalization will accelerate network (effects) Internal and external gains and benefits due to vertical
externalities. Studies by Barrett and Yang (2001), Econo- integration include lower transaction costs, synchroniza-
mides (1996a, 1996b), Katz and Shapiro (1994), Kikuchi and tion of supply and demand along the chain of products,
Kobayashi (2007), and Shy (2001) demonstrated that the lower uncertainty and higher investment, the ability to
role and impact of network effects is amplified in the monopolize markets throughout the chain by market
globalized world and trade liberalization. Furthermore, foreclosure, and better adaptation to the line of program-
international firms gain from globalization and trade liber- ming of the broadcasting channel. Another advantage
alization due to intensified network effects (Kikuchi & includes more efficient distribution of the media content.
Kobayashi, 2007). To empirically prove the beneficial Vertical integration gives media firms higher control
impact of globalization and network externalities on inter- over their operating environments, and it can help them
national media industry, I present findings related to the avoid losing market access in important upstream or
vertical integration and media diversification effects. downstream phases (Doyle, 2002, p. 23). Another reason
for the creation of vertically integrated and diversified
media conglomerates is that it makes it more difficult for
Vertical Integration them to be taken over by a predator (Doyle, 2002, p. 25).
As such, it provides additional value and more sustain-
All five of the examined media conglomerates are vertically able competitive advantage to media conglomerates. The
integrated. Vertical integration combines a core business following are summaries of arguments made in favor of
with its suppliers along a supply chain. A vertically vertical integration in the media industry: It prevents
integrated firm controls most aspects of the production, double marginalization (Noam, Groebel, & Gerbarg,
distribution, and exhibition of its products (Albarran, 2004, p. 46); it increases investment by internalizing
2002, p. 30). Media companies should be producers of pecuniary externalities (Noam et al., 2004, p. 47); it may
content and providers of distribution. It is very expensive improve investment coordination (Noam, Groebel, &
to be only the producer of content or a provider of distri- Gerbarg, 2004, p. 48); it restricts the entry of competitors
bution. A successful example of vertical integration is to media markets and businesses; it provides the ability
Rupert Murdoch’s Fox News. Vertical integration is a to secure supplies and future orders and assurance of the
path for reducing transaction costs. Firms with vertically pricing, quality, and availability of supplies and opera-
integrated structures are considerably larger, on average, tional efficiencies gained from coordinating production
than other firms—even those that operate in multiple of supplies with their consumption.
(but not vertically linked) industries. In summary, vertical integration is a successful strat-
To maintain a high level of productivity and delivery egy for media conglomerates, as it is very efficient for
of programs, TV companies will have to vertically them to control both content production and distribu-
integrate their business activities. This implies that TV tion because the greater the distribution of their output,
companies will own rights over their content and distri- the lower their per-unit production costs will be (Doyle,
bution to aggressively seek out new relationships to 2002, p. 34).
accommodate the shift toward digital convergence.
Furthermore, companies will need to test new business
models to address increased fragmentation and intellec- Vertical Expansion and Acquisition
tual property in a digital era.
Vertical integration is the degree to which a firm Vertical expansion, in economics, is the growth of a busi-
owns its upstream suppliers and its downstream buyers. ness enterprise through the acquisition of companies
Vertically integrated companies are united through a that produce the intermediate goods needed by the
hierarchy and share a common owner. Usually, each business or help market and distribute its final goods.
86 Vukanovic

The result of the vertical expansion is a more efficient they arise when the same media content is repackaged or
business with lower costs and more profits. Vertical repurposed into different media products (i.e., econo-
expansion gives secure access to essential inputs or essen- mies of scope). The prevalence of economies of scope in
tial distribution outlets for output. This is a key advan- the media explains the widespread tendency toward
tage in the media because firms depend on getting access expansion and the high number of multiproduct firms
both to content and to avenues for distribution of con- (Doyle, 2002, p. 28). Thus, the term economies of multi-
tent (Doyle, 2002, p. 35). formity embraces all benefits that come about through
Vertical expansion is also known as a vertical acquisi- diagonal cross-ownership in the media and communica-
tion. Vertical expansions or acquisitions can also be used tions industries (Doyle, 2002, p. 31).
to increase scales and to gain market power, as well as to The systematic finding of the study on the relation
set up competitive barriers. The acquisition of DirecTV® between corporate diversification strategy and perfor-
by News Corporation is an example of vertical expansion mance clearly indicates that media conglomerates with
or acquisition. DirecTV is a satellite TV company through high diversity (Time Warner and Bertelsmann AG), as
which News Corporation can distribute more of its well as low diversity (News Corporation and CBS Corp.),
media content: news, movies, and television shows. perform equally well in terms of net income, annual
revenue, annual growth of media market stock, and total
debt to equity. However, in terms of international diver-
Media Diversification sification, the same study found that a media firm
improved its performance (as measured by revenue and
Convergence, globalization, and a massive market dereg- net income) as it diversified into international markets
ulation in the United States and Europe between 1980 (News Corporation and Bertelsmann AG). This conclusion
and 1996 have strengthened trends toward concentrated confirms Jung and Chan-Olmsted’s (see Chan-Olmsted,
media and cross-media ownership, with the growth of 2006, p. 191) findings of their longitudinal investigation
integrated conglomerates (e.g., Time Warner, Bertelsmann of the relation between diversification and performance of
AG, Walt Disney Co.) whose activities span several areas the top 25 media companies over a 12-year (1991–2002)
of the industry (broadcasting, multichannel video pro- period.
gramming distribution [MVPD], Internet, publishing). However, with the exception of News Corporation and
According to a report by Screen Digest (2000), only in this Bertelsmann AG, other media conglomerates with domi-
decade did Europe see national or regional channels nantly more unrelated diversified businesses, such as
jump from 100 to 1,000 (Sánchez-Tabernero, 2004), Vivendi and Viacom, are relatively less profitable in
whereas in the United States the number of TV stations regard to the Big Five, as evident in their high debt to
between 1980 and 2000 increased by about 700 equity ratio. Media firms with related diversified busi-
(Vukanovic, 2004, p. 55). This implies that during the nesses are more profitable than undiversified firms with
1990s, 100 new commercial channels were created in unrelated businesses (Chan-Olmsted, 2006, p. 192). In
Europe every year (Sánchez-Tabernero, 2004). other words, managerial efficiency and profitability, as
The reason for the adoption of media diversification measured by return ratios, decrease with unrelated
strategies in regard to large and vertically integrated product diversification, reflecting the fact that market
media conglomerates seem well suited, as they are able investors devalue overly diversified media conglomer-
to exploit common resources and spread production ates with non-synergistic asset holdings (Chan-Olmsted,
costs across wider product and geographic markets and 2006, p. 192). It is advisable to point out that in review-
benefit from natural economies of scale and scope in the ing the histories of all five of these firms, one can easily
media. Diversified media enterprises are better able to see that these companies became more diversified over
reap the economies of scale and scope that are naturally the years through a series of mergers and acquisitions
present in the industry and that, due to globalization (Picard, 2002b, p. 117)
and convergence, have become even more pronounced Related diversification enables a firm to benefit from
(Doyle, 2002, p. 23). synergy—the added value created by business units work-
Another motivation underlying strategies of cross-media ing together and economies of scope and scale through
expansion is the desire to exploit anticipated synergies the leveraging of core competencies and sharing of activ-
and “economies of multiformity” between different ities and information. Related diversification also offers a
media sectors (newspaper publishing and television firm the advantages of pooled negotiation power and
broadcasting), which may develop over the long term access to, as well as control over, production materials and
(Doyle, 2002, p. 33). Economies of multiformity refers to product flows through vertical integration (Chan-Olmsted,
any and all advantages that firms derive from cross- 2006, p. 41). In addition, a diversifier can also generate
owning activities in more than one sector of the media cash from its core, successful business unit to invest in
or communications industry (Doyle, 2002, p. 31). Also, other ventures of additional profits (Chan-Olmsted,
Strategic Management of Media 87

2006, p. 39). Corporate diversification may be a desirable Large Number of Shareholders


alternative to reduce a media company’s business risk
(Picard, 2005, p. 27), as well as shift to value chain areas Four out of the five companies have at least 25,000 or
with a higher added value (Pagani, 2003, pp. 22–25). more shareholders. Only Bertelsmann AG has 6 major
Moreover, diversification is an efficient and effective shareholders. The analysis suggests that the most profit-
strategy used by media firms to smooth sales and profit able media conglomerates whose annual growth of
fluctuations, stimulate growth faster than if they concen- media market stock was +40%, such as Walt Disney Co.,
trated on a single product or service, and ensure that per- have the largest number of shareholders (658,000). This
formance is not dependent on the economic cycles of one can be explained by the fact that media market stocks
location or industry (Picard, 2002a, p. 197). have greater tendency to be sold and bought by different
In conclusion, there is little doubt that media diversi- market investors if there are more shareholders within a
fication is an important strategy of many media con- specific company. Frequent buying and selling of market
glomerates. Given the trends in globalization and stocks positively influence the price of media stocks. It
convergence of media and communication industries, also testifies that market investors are interested in
the competition between traditional media companies, investing in a media company if they anticipate that its
but also between companies from emerging media and flexible market and organizational structure will provide
information markets, will increase (Picard, 2005, p. 37). A them with more profitable outcomes.
well-defined diversification strategy may help these com-
panies to create or sustain their competitive advantage.
In summary, it is advisable to point out that the five
Advantages of Network Externalities on Media
most-successful global media conglomerates predomi-
nantly focused their core business activities in media
Markets (IP TV and Cellular–Mobile TV)
diversification and vertical integration over the U.S. and
Information, media, and communications products and
EU media markets. The reason is that these two global
services tend to predominantly define network indus-
markets are economically and technologically most
tries. Accordingly, network economies will necessarily
advanced and consist of higher numbers of media con-
govern the ways that we build and exchange products
sumers. Furthermore, both the U.S. and EU economies
and services in the information, media, and communica-
account for more than 40% of the global gross domestic
tions sectors (business and industry). Unlike with tradi-
product in 2008.
tional cable and satellite TV, the global media market is
not saturated with products and services relating to IP TV
and cellular–mobile TV. As such, these two types of
The Top Five Media Conglomerates
media are more effectively positioned to utilize the bene-
and Their Holdings
fits of network externalities.
In addition, the main advantage of IP TV, Internet, and
Bertelsmann AG centers its holdings in the broadcast,
cellular–mobile TV over other media such as newspapers,
TV and film production, and print sectors. Time
radio, and TV is that they are not one-way, but rather
Warner has the most presence in the MVPD market.
two-way, mediums of communication. Their content can
Walt Disney Co. has strong broadcast properties, MVPD
be efficiently accessed, distributed, as well as customized
brands, and successful production resources. News Cor-
and repurposed to suit individual consumers’ needs and
poration is very competitive in both broadcast and
preferences. Because of the fact that it can be efficiently
MVPD markets, in both branded television and film
accessed, Internet takes advantage of “locational monop-
and print content, as well as in the creation and distri-
olies,” which represents the monopoly from being physi-
bution of online programming. CBS Corp. has strong
cally close to the customers (Jansen, 2006, p. 146).
Web properties and television production, as well as
print content. The “richest” media conglomerates in
terms of content include Walt Disney Co., Time
Warner, and News Corporation. In terms of distribu- Global Market Potential
tion, Time Warner distributes content via broadcast- and Positioning of IP TV
ing, cable, the Internet, and print. Walt Disney Co.
concentrates on broadcasting, cable, and the Internet. There are several advantages to IP TV including interactiv-
News Corporation is the leading distributor of content ity, video-on-demand, better compression technologies,
via satellite, but also offers distribution via broadcast- and triple-play efficiencies. Other advantages include bet-
ing, cable, and publishing. CBS Corp.’s distribution ter program guides. Therefore, it is not surprising that
effort primarily focuses on TV and radio broadcasting, strategy analytics predicted in 2007 that the number of
billboards, and publishing. broadband subscribers would grow to 530 million by
88 Vukanovic

2011, up from 210 million in 2005. Presently, telecom- Europe will lead with a 42.5% share of global revenues, fol-
munication companies offering IP TV services in the lowed by the United States at 40.5%, and Asia accounting
United States are Verizon, AT&T, BellSouth, and for the remaining 17%. According to the latest IDC
Surewest; in Canada they are Manitoba Telecom Services research, the number of U.S. mobile-phone subscribers
and Sasktel; in Europe they are France Telecom, Belgacom, paying for some form of television or video content on
BT, Telecom Italia, Neuf, Telefonica, Various, Magnet, their devices is set to rise by 240% between 2007 and 2010.
Free, Fastweb, DT, Telia/Sonera, Cyprus Telecom Authority,
VNL, Versatel, and Video Networks; in Asia they are
PCCW, Softbank, KDDI, and Chungwa Telecom. Future Research Directions in Global
Furthermore, IP TV is set to achieve significant sub- Media Management
scriber growth over the next year, according to a recent
report by the Open IP TV Forum in November 2007, To more effectively position and leverage new paradig-
which expects the global market for such services to matic models largely influencing volatile media markets,
reach 39 million by the end of 2009, up from 16 million I propose further diversification of repurposed media
in 2007. This prediction is supported by additional stud- contents, products, and services for the emerging IP TV,
ies of the Multimedia Research Group Inc and MRG, Inc. Internet TV, and mobile-TV markets. Accordingly, the
On the other hand, global IP TV services’ revenues have untapped market of IP TV and the mobile-TV market, and
achieved an annual growth rate of 290% over the period of its growing number of subscribers, provide a profitable
2003 to 2006. IP TV will reach nearly 10% of the European base for the expansion and adoption of these technologies
pay-TV market by 2009. by international media conglomerates.
Furthermore, looking from a macroeconomic view-
point, I suggest that large international media con-
Global Market Potential and Positioning glomerates have to analytically observe transitional
of Cellular–Mobile TV trends from old economies to new and digital econo-
mies (Tables 2 & 3). Only after profound and analytical
Mobile television is set to achieve massive subscriber examination of these managerial, economic, technolog-
growth over the next 5 years, according to a report by the ical, and marketing parameters will it be possible to
analysis firm, Datamonitor, which expects the global conceptualize an effective and sustainable competitive
market for such services to reach 155.6 million by the advantage strategy, as well as to more efficiently locate
end of 2012, up from 15.3 million today. It suggests a the future of a paradigmatic shift in the global media
significant growth of 66.2% year over year. Asia Pacific market.
markets will be the most accepting of mobile TV, Data- It is evident that trends toward global conglomeration
monitor predicts, accounting for 76.3 million subscribers will continue because global media conglomerates are in
by December 2012. Europe, meanwhile, is expected to see a more competitive position compared to non-diversified
year-on-year growth of 102%, for a market size of 42.7 media firms (Chan-Olmsted, 2006, p. 199). Global media
million in the same year, whereas North America will conglomerates often have the resources to exploit con-
account for 34.6 million users. Datamonitor media and tent products via the repurposing process for distribu-
broadcasting analysis predicts that Europe’s mobile tion in multiple platforms under different ad or fee
broadcasting sector will experience especially “strong structures, to perform cross-platform marketing with
growth” between 2009 and 2012, as terrestrial television complementary distribution systems, and to be well-
signals are moved from analogue to digital airwaves and positioned to deliver products in the developing
a new spectrum is freed-up for wireless TV technologies broadband spectrum with their diverse holdings and
like Digital Video Broadcasting–Handheld and MediaFLO. partnerships (Chan-Olmsted, 2006, p. 199).
Screen Digest’s latest report entitled, “Mobile TV: Busi- As the field of media management and economics
ness Models and Opportunities,” predicts significant becomes a more mature area of study, it is essential for
growth in subscriber numbers globally, with 140 million scholars to enhance the rigor of the discipline by devel-
subscribers and revenues of €4.4 billion by 2011 oping an analytical framework of strategic paradigms
(Sánchez-Tabernero, 2004). North America will experi- that draw on new or modified paradigms from these
ence the biggest increase, growing its subscriber base academic fields (Albarran, Chan-Olmsted, & Wirth,
twentyfold to 28.8 million and revenues as much as fifty- 2006, p. 176). The fluidity of media industries, because
fold to €1.8 billion by 2011. However, subscriber num- of the continuous changes in communication technol-
bers do not equate to revenue; despite its large ogy, creative development, and audience preferences,
subscriber numbers and longevity of mobile TV services, requires media management and economics scholars to
Screen Digest believes that by 2011, the Asian market will constantly introduce, incorporate, and test new para-
generate less revenue than Europe and the United States. digms (Albarran et al., 2006, p. 177 ).
Strategic Management of Media 89

Table 2. Marketing and Technological Distribution and The future of global management and new and digital
Production Shifts From Old to New Paradigms economies will be profoundly influenced by emerging
economic, technological, managerial, and marketing
Old Production and paradigms. Therefore, it is necessary for large media con-
Distribution Models New Production and Distribution Models
glomerates to systematically and effectively monitor and
Analogue and old Digital and new media, multimedia, analyze present and future market and business trends
media hypermedia, and cross-media influencing traditionally volatile media markets. In the
Terrestrial, satellite, Internet TV, Internet Protocol TV, and age of a new economy, it is evident that vertical integra-
and cable TV mobile–cellular TV
Linear viewing of TV Nonlinear (interactive and enhanced)
tion, cross-media contents and platforms, economies of
program viewing of TV program aggregation (triple- and quadruple-play bundling strate-
Broadcasting Narrowcasting (Webcasting) gies and network externalities), vertical expansion, and
Macrocasting Microcasting–repurposing of content media diversification will play important role. As such,
and cross-media content management more intensive global competition will inevitably influ-
Mass production Mass customization–IT management
ence product and service life cycles to be shorter, more
Product Product and services differentiation
differentiation innovative, and distributed efficiently to the end users.
9 a.m. to 5 p.m. 7/24 (“7×24”) or 24/7
Corporate business Internet time-based market
time market References
Mass market–mass Micromarket–niche marketing
marketing
Push strategy (short Pull strategy (long distribution channel)
Albarran, A. B. (2002). Management of electronic media. Belmont,
distribution On-demand marketing strategy CA: Wadsworth.
channel) User-generated content Albarran, A., Chan-Olmsted, S. & Wirth, M. (2006). Handbook of
Product centered— Customer and service centered— media management and economics. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence
brand marketing relationship marketing Erlbaum Associates.
and management Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2000). Bundling and competition of
Economies of scale Economies of scope information goods on the Internet. Marketing Science, 19, 63–82.
Market diversification Baranes, E. (2006). Bundling and collusion in communications markets
Bundling and servitization–network (Working Paper No. 06–17). New York: NET Institute.
externalities
Barrett, C. B., & Yang, Y. N. (2001). Rational incompatibility with
Complementary distribution systems
international product standards. Journal of International
Economics, 54, 171–191.
Carbajo, J., de Meza, D., & Seidmann, D. J. (1990). A strategic
motivation for commodity bundling. Journal of Industrial
Economics, 38, 283–298.
Cartwright, P. A. (2002). Only converge: Networks and connec-
tivity in the information economy. Business Strategy Review,
Table 3. Strategic Management, Market, and Business Shifts 13(2), 59.
From Old to New Paradigms Chan-Olmsted, S. M. (2006). Competitive strategy for media firms.
Old Strategic Management, New Strategic Management, Market, Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc.
Market, and Business Models and Business Models Chen, Y. (1997). Equilibrium product bundling. Journal of Business,
70(1), 85–103.
Shareholder value Shareholder–stakeholder value Compaine, B., & Gomery, D. (2000). Who owns the media? Mahwah,
Tangible management Integration of tangible management NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc.
and intangible management (human Doyle, G. (2002). Understanding media economics. London: Sage.
capital and content creation and
Ducey, R. V., & Fratrik, M. R. (1989). Broadcasting industry
distribution) through “balanced
response to new technologies. Journal of Media Economics, 2,
scorecard” strategy and “just in
time” management and distribution 67–86.
Strategic competition Strategic alliance–strategic cooperation Economides, N. (1996a). The economics of networks. Interna-
A value business network–business tional Journal of Industrial Organization, 14, 673–699.
chain Economides, N. (1996b). Network externalities, complementari-
Horizontal integration Vertical integration ties, and invitations to enter. European Journal of Political Economy,
Cost-reduction strategy Investment in growth and content or 12, 211–233.
product innovations Evans, P. B., & Wurster, T. S. (1997). Strategy and the new eco-
Long life cycle of Short life cycle of products and services nomics of information. Harvard Business Review, 75(5), 70–82.
products and services
Farrell, J., & Shapiro, C. (1992). Standard setting in high-definition
Strategic management Strategic management, innovation
television. In M. N. Baily & C. Winston (Eds.), Brookings papers
management, diffusion of
innovation, and entrepreneurship on economic activity (pp. 1–93). Washington, DC: Brookings
Institute.
90 Vukanovic

Foss, N. J., Kristensen, T., & Wilke, R. (2004). Corporate commu- Pagani, M. (2003). Multimedia and interactive digital TV: Managing
nication in the emerging network economy: A provider of the opportunities created by digital convergence. Hershey, PA: IRM
common knowledge. Corporate Communications: An International Press.
Journal, 9, 43–49. Peck, H., & Juttner, U. (2000). Strategy and relationships: Defin-
Grant, R. G. (2008). Contemporary strategy analysis. Oxford, England: ing the interface in supply chain contexts. International Journal
Blackwell. of Logistics Management, 11(2), 33.
Gupta, S., Jain, D. C., & Sawhney, M. S. (1999). Modeling the evo- Petrovic, O., Ksela, M., Fallenbock, M., & Kittl, C. (2003). Trust in
lution of markets with indirect network externalities: An network economy. New York: Springer.
application to digital television. Marketing Science, 18, 396–416. Picard, R. (2002a). The economics and financing of media companies.
Hoskins, C., McFadyen, S., & Finn, A. (2004). Media economics: New York: Fordham University Press.
Applying economics to new and traditional media. Beverly Hills: Picard, R. (2002b). Media firms: Structures, operations, and perfor-
Sage. mance. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc.
Jansen, D. W. (2006). The new economy and beyond. Cheltenham, Picard, R. (2005). Media product portfolios. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence
England: Edward Elgar Publishing. Erlbaum Associates, Inc.
Johnston, R., & Lawrence, P. R. (1988). Beyond vertical integration— PricewaterhouseCoopers. (2008). Global media forecast for 2008–2012,
The rise of the value adding partnership. Harvard Business 9th Ed. United Kingdom.
Review, 66(4), 94–101. Sánchez-Tabernero, A. (2004, May). Competition between public ser-
Katz, M. L., & Shapiro, C. (1994). Systems competition and vice and commercial television broadcasting in the European market.
network effects. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(2), 93–115. Paper presented at 6th World Media Economics Conference
Kikuchi, T., & Kobayashi, C. (2007). Network effects and the Centre, HEC Montreal, Canada.
impact of trade liberalization. Economics Bulletin, 6(4), 1–7. Seidmann D. J. (1991). Bundling as a facilitating device: A rein-
Lisboa, J. (2007). Network marketing. Unpublished doctoral thesis, terpretation of leverage theory. Economica, 58, 491–499.
Cranfield School of Management, Bedford, Bedfordshire, Shapiro, C., & Varian, H. R. (1998). Information rules: A strategic
United Kingdom. guide to the network economy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business
Mahajan, V., Muller, E., & Bass, F. M. (1993). New-product School Press Books.
diffusion models. In J. Eliashberg & G. L. Lilien (Eds.), Shaw, M. (2006). Commerce and the digital economy. Armonk, NY:
Handbooks in OR and MS (Vol. 5, pp. 349–408). Amsterdam: Sharpe.
North-Holland. Shy, O. (2001). The economics of network industries. New York:
McGahan, A., Vadasz, L. L., & Yoffie, D. B. (1997). Creating value Cambridge University Press.
and setting standards: The lessons of consumer electronics Vizjak, A., & Ringlstetter, M. (2003). Media management: Leveraging
for personal digital assistants. In D. B. Yoffie (Ed.), Competing in content for profitable growth. New York: Springer.
the age of digital convergence (pp. 227–264). Boston: HBS Press. Vukanovic, Z. (2004). The influence of media globalization and organi-
Noam, E., Groebel, J., & Gerbarg, D. (2004). Internet television. zational culture on strategic management of CNN. Podgorica,
Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates, Inc. Montenegro: Oktoih.
Ongardanunkul, P. (2003). Essays on network externalities: Theoreti- Whinston, M. D. (1990). Tying, foreclosure and exclusion. American
cal and empirical analyses. Unpublished doctoral dissertation, Economic Review, 80, 837–859.
Graduate School of Arts and Sciences, Department of Yoffie, D. B. (1996). Competing in the age of digital convergence.
Economics, Boston College. California Management Review, 38(4), 31–53.

You might also like